View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Speech
Governor Frederic S. Mishkin

At the Annual Macro Conference, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, San Francisco,
California
March 23, 2007

Inflation Dynamics
Under its dual mandate, the Federal Reserve seeks to promote both price stability and maximum
sustainable employment.1 For this reason, we at the Federal Reserve are acutely interested in the
inflation process, both to better understand the past and--given the inherent lags with which
monetary policy affects the economy--to try to forecast the future. We economists have made some
important strides in our understanding of inflation dynamics in recent years. To be sure, substantial
gaps in our knowledge remain, and forecasting is still a famously imprecise task, but our increased
understanding offers the hope that central banks will be able to continue and perhaps even improve
upon their successful performance of recent years.
Today, I will outline what I see as the key stylized facts that research has in recent years uncovered
about changes in the dynamics of inflation and will present my view of how to interpret these
findings. The interpretation has important implications for how we should think about the conduct
of monetary policy and what we think might happen to inflation over the next couple of years. I will
address these two issues in the final part of the talk. Before I continue, however, I should stress that
the views I will express here are my own and are not necessarily those of my colleagues on the
Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC).
The Empirical Evidence on Changes in Inflation Dynamics
To see what research has discovered about the evolution of inflation dynamics in recent years, let’s
explore the following questions: (1) What is the available evidence on changes in inflation
persistence in recent years? (2) What is the available evidence on changes in the slope of the Phillips
curve? (3) What role do other variables play in the inflation process?
Inflation Persistence
To answer the first question, we need to measure how long the effects of a shock to inflation will
last. Specifically, we need to know whether inflation tends to revert quickly to its initial level, or
whether the effects of the shock persist--that is, lead to a changed level of inflation for an extended
period. The most obvious way of measuring inflation persistence is to regress inflation on several of
its own lags and then calculate the sum of the coefficients on lagged inflation. If the sum of the
coefficients is close to 1.0, then shocks to inflation have long-lived effects on inflation. In other
words, inflation behaves like a random walk, so that when inflation goes up, it stays up. If the sum
of the coefficients drops well below 1.0, then a shock to inflation has only a temporary effect on
inflation, and inflation soon reverts back to its trend level.
The evidence from these so-called autoregressions with U.S. data suggests that inflation may have
grown less persistent over time. In particular, when autoregressions are run using rolling samples
with a fixed width of, say, twelve years, the sum of the lagged coefficients often falls noticeably
below unity as the sample advances to include the most recent data. Figure 1 illustrates this
tendency, with the core personal consumption expenditures (PCE) price index as the measure of
inflation. As you can see, the coefficient sum has declined to about 0.6 or so since the late 1990s,
although the dotted lines indicate that the confidence interval for this estimate is wide and still

includes 1.0. This result appears robust to the addition of other explanatory variables to the
regression, although making such a modification does tend to reduce the extent of the estimated
decline.2 Finally, it’s worth noting that this is not just a U.S. phenomenon, as some studies have
found similar results for a number of other countries.3

(I might proudly note in passing that the staff of the Federal Reserve System is responsible for much
of this research.)
Recent work by Jim Stock and Mark Watson (2007) provides an alternative and, to me, a quite
intuitive way of thinking about inflation persistence. They estimate a model that decomposes
inflation into two components. The first component, which can be thought of as the underlying
trend, follows a random walk, so that shocks to this component persist indefinitely and thus affect
the trend inflation rate going forward. The second component is a serially uncorrelated shock,
meaning that such shocks are temporary and lead to only transitory fluctuations around the trend.
Stock and Watson then allow the volatility of these two kinds of shocks, trend and temporary, to
vary over time.
Stock and Watson find that the importance of the trend shocks relative to that of the temporary
shocks started to rise at the end of the 1960s in the United States, peaked in the mid-1970s, stayed
elevated over the next ten years, and then declined to a historical low (upper panel of figure 2).
When the relative importance of the trend shocks became high, as it did in the 1970s and early
1980s, inflation became highly persistent. Under such conditions, if inflation went up, the trend
component typically rose in tandem so that inflation stayed up. In contrast, when the temporary
shocks were relatively more important, as was true before the 1970s and after the mid-1980s, a
change in inflation tended to reflect a change in the temporary component, not the trend. As a result,
fluctuations in inflation tended to fade away, implying that inflation persistence was much lower. In
the context of the Stock-Watson model, then, when inflation rose to double-digit levels during the

"Great Inflation" period of the 1970s and early 1980s, persistence became very high because the
trend rate of inflation moved around a lot--that is, trend inflation became unanchored.
Although the importance of the trend component has fallen markedly since the 1970s, the estimates
produced by Stock and Watson suggest that it is still large enough to be economically meaningful.
The bottom panel of figure 2 illustrates this point; as you can see, the estimated trend (the solid line)
has drifted up a bit since the mid-1990s. Of course, such estimates are inevitably imprecise to some
degree. For example, Cecchetti et al (2007) employ a slightly modified version of the Stock-Watson
procedure in a recent paper and find that inflation persistence has fallen so low that their estimated
trend for gross domestic product (GDP) price inflation has been almost perfectly flat at about 2.2
percent over the past few years. In contrast, Cogley and Sargent (2005), using a different
modification of the procedure, obtain results more in line with the original Stock and Watson paper.
Finally, follow-up work by staff members at the Federal Reserve Board suggests that the degree of
persistence found with these techniques varies across different measures of inflation. Thus, the
empirical evidence on this question can vary. Nonetheless, I think it fair to say that inflation has
become less persistent over the past two decades but that the underlying trend may not yet be
perfectly stable.

When Cecchetti and his co-authors apply this type of analysis to other countries, the results are
remarkably similar. In particular, in Canada, Italy, and the United Kingdom, the importance of the
trend shocks began to rise in the late 1960s and early 1970s and then declined only in the mid1980s. France followed a similar pattern, although there the rise began a bit earlier, in 1963. In
short, all these countries experienced a similar "Great Inflation," when trend inflation became
unanchored. Germany and Japan had shorter periods of high persistence of inflation, with
persistence beginning to decline around 1969 in Germany and around 1979 in Japan. Cecchetti and
his co-authors conclude that the rise and subsequent decline of inflation persistence has thus been a
worldwide phenomenon.
Slope of the Phillips Curve
In traditional Phillips-curve equations, inflation depends on past values of inflation, an

unemployment gap (the difference between the unemployment rate and an estimate of its natural
rate), and variables such as the relative price of energy and import prices. When researchers estimate
these equations, they typically find that the coefficient on the unemployment gap has declined (in
absolute value) since the 1980s, often by a marked amount.4 In other words, the evidence suggests
that the Phillips curve has flattened.
The finding that inflation is less responsive to the unemployment gap, if taken at face value,
suggests that fluctuations in resource utilization will have smaller implications for inflation than
used to be the case. From the point of view of policymakers, this development is a two-edged
sword: On the plus side, it implies that an overheating economy will tend to generate a smaller
increase in inflation. On the negative side, however, a flatter Phillips curve also implies that a given
increase in inflation will be more costly to wring out of the system. We can quantify this latter
consideration using the so-called sacrifice ratio--the number of years that unemployment has to be
1.0 percentage point greater than its natural rate to reduce the inflation rate 1.0 percentage point.
Averaging estimates obtained from a comprehensive battery of equation specifications suggests that
the sacrifice ratio may be 40 percent larger--that is, it may be 40 percent more costly to reduce
inflation than it was two decades ago. Is this really bad news? I will return to this question later.
Role of Other Variables in the Inflation Process
Empirical evidence suggests that inflation has also become less responsive to other shocks. The two
oil price shocks in the 1970s were associated with large jumps in core inflation, whereas recent
surges in energy prices have not had a similar effect. This reduced sensitivity manifests itself in
traditional Phillips-curve models as a substantial decline in the estimated coefficient on the energy
price term in these equations. Because this term equals the change in relative energy prices
multiplied by the share of energy in aggregate output, energy price effects on inflation appear to
have fallen by more than can be accounted for by the greater energy efficiency of the economy.5
In contrast, unpublished empirical work by the staff at the Federal Reserve Board suggests that,
once we take the rising share of imports into account, the influence of import prices on core inflation
in the United States has not changed much in the context of reduced-form forecasting models.6 At
the same time, the influence of exchange rate movements on import prices--the so-called passthrough effect--may have fallen substantially, at least according to some studies.7 If so, then the
influence of exchange rate fluctuations on domestic inflation may now be less than it once was,
when one controls for changes in the volume of our foreign trade.
What Interpretation Can We Give to Changes in Inflation Dynamics?
In interpreting these stylized facts about changes in inflation dynamics, we must first recognize that
all of them are based on reduced-form relationships, and thus they are about correlations and not
necessarily about true structural relationships. Because the explanatory variables in inflation
regressions are themselves influenced by changes in economic conditions, changes in the underlying
monetary policy regime are likely to be a source of changes in reduced-form inflation dynamics.
This problem is especially acute for structural relationships involving expectations or other factors
that are not directly observable and so cannot be included in reduced-form regressions. In such
cases, we cannot use the reduced-form equations to disentangle the effects of such unobserved
factors--which themselves may be driven by changes in monetary policy--from that of other
influences.
The most important development in monetary economics that I have witnessed over my now-long
career has been the recognition that expectations are central to our understanding of the behavior of
the aggregate economy. Theory tells us that inflation expectations must be a key driving force
behind inflation. This dependence has long been implicit in traditional Phillips-curve analysis, but
expectations--now in explicit form--are also a central feature of the increasingly popular New
Keynesian Phillips curves, in which current-period inflation is a function of expectations of next
period’s inflation and resource utilization. Therefore, a natural first place to look for explanations of
changing inflation dynamics is a possible change in the expectations-formation process.

The first stylized fact discussed earlier is that inflation persistence, which rose in the 1970s during
the Great Inflation, has since declined to a much lower level. An intuitive way of thinking about this
rise and fall in inflation persistence is that it resulted from an un-anchoring of trend inflation during
the period of the Great Inflation, and a re-anchoring in recent years, as the work of Stock and
Watson suggests. When we think about what drives trend inflation, inflation expectations-particularly long-run expectations--come to mind. A de-anchoring of inflation expectations would
surely lead to trend inflation becoming unanchored, whereas an anchoring of inflation expectations
at a particular level would necessarily lead to a stabilization of trend inflation and hence a decline in
inflation persistence.
Do indicators of inflation expectations support this story? They certainly do. Consider the measure
of expected inflation for the coming twelve months reported by the Livingston survey. As illustrated
by the dashed line in figure 3 , this measure of expected short-run inflation--adjusted by a constant
factor to convert it from a CPI basis to a PCE basis--soared during the 1970s and then fell back
markedly during the 1980s and early 1990s. Over the past few years, the short-run series has
fluctuated around 2 percent, with its month-to-month movements correlated with swings in energy
prices, as one might expect. An even more striking story is told by the survey-based measure of
expected long-run inflation used in the FRB/US model, the dotted blue line in figure 3.8 When we
look at this long-run series (which should be more closely related to expectations about policy
objectives than the short-run measure), we see that the public’s expectations stood at a high level of
7-3/4 percent at the start of the 1980s, when this information first began to be collected. From that
point on, however, expectations fell steadily over the 1980s and most of the 1990s as the process of
re-anchoring continued. By 1998, this process was apparently completed, and since that time the
public’s expectations--at least according to this particular measure--have been steady as a rock.
Estimates of inflation compensation derived from indexed Treasury yields have also been
remarkably stable in recent years. Figure 3 also reproduces the estimate of trend inflation produced
by the Stock-Watson procedure (the solid line). As you can see, this series more or less tracks the
survey-based measures of long-run expectations, suggesting that the anchoring of long-run inflation
expectations in recent years may explain the finding of a marked decline in inflation persistence.
Anchoring of inflation expectations is not a deus ex machina. It must come from somewhere, and
since Milton Friedman’s adage that “[i]nflation is always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon”
is still true, monetary policy must be the source of the change in the evolution of long-run inflation
expectations. During the 1960s and 1970s, the Federal Reserve and a number of other central banks
maintained a policy stance that, inadvertently or not, was too easy on average and that allowed both
actual and expected inflation to drift up markedly over many years. Since the late 1970s, however,
the Federal Reserve and many other central banks have increased their commitment to price
stability, in both words and actions. The Fed pursued preemptive strikes against rises in inflation in
1994-95, 1999-00, and in 2004-06, as well as preemptive strikes against potentially deflationary
forces in the fall of 1998 and in 2001-04. The result has been not only low and stable inflation but
also, as we have seen, a strong anchoring of long-run inflation expectations.

The pursuit of more-aggressive monetary policy to control inflation and the achievement of
anchored inflation expectations can also help explain the other stylized facts about inflation
dynamics. With expectations of inflation anchored, any given shock to inflation--whether it is from
aggregate demand, energy prices, or the foreign exchange rate--will have a smaller effect on
expected inflation and hence on trend inflation. These shocks will then have a much less persistent
effect on actual inflation. The recent experience with surging oil prices seems consistent with this
story. The price of West Texas intermediate crude oil rose from about $30 per barrel in late 2003 to
a peak of almost $75 per barrel in July of last year. During this episode, inflation appears to have
been boosted only temporarily and by a strikingly small amount, in contrast to the 1970s when oil
price shocks led to large, persistent increases in inflation.
Interestingly, monetary policy could have worked to flatten the estimated Phillips curve even
without these favorable expectational effects, simply by moving more aggressively to stabilize both
inflation and output. A theorem from the literature on optimal control states that implementing a
policy of adjusting some instrument to stabilize a particular variable has the effect, in the limit, of
driving the correlation between the instrument and the targeted variable to zero. Thus, a monetary
policy that more successfully stabilizes inflation and resource utilization could well lead to a smaller
estimated coefficient on unemployment gaps in a traditional Phillips-curve equation.
Research carried out with quite different models of the macroeconomy by my former colleagues at
Columbia, Jean Boivin and Marc Giannoni (2006), and by John Roberts (2006) at the Federal
Reserve Board, supports these conclusions. In particular, their analyses suggest that changes in the
way the Federal Reserve conducts monetary policy--including changes in both the parameters of
monetary policy reaction functions and the volatility of shocks to those functions--may account for
most of the reduction in the coefficients on resource utilization in traditional Phillips curves.9
What is particularly attractive about highlighting a better anchoring of inflation expectations as
probably the primary factor driving the changes in inflation dynamics is that this one explanation
covers so many of the stylized facts--an application of Occam’s razor. Indeed, I have always
become more confident in a theory if it can explain a number of very different facts.10 This is why I

am so attracted to the view that inflation expectations are a key driving factor in the inflation
process.
Of course, many other factors also influence inflation, and some of these provide other possible
explanations for the recent changes in inflation dynamics. For example, smaller coefficients on
unemployment gaps and energy prices in traditional Phillips curve equations may reflect the
influence of lower and less-variable inflation on the frequency with which firms change their prices.
In the context of a low-inflation environment, firms may have concluded that they can leave their
prices fixed for longer periods at little cost, causing inflation to be less responsive to shocks,
particularly if they are transitory. In this way, monetary policy may have affected the slope of the
Phillips curve without having affected the manner in which expectations are formed. Also, from the
mid-1980s through the first years of this decade, energy price movements were smaller and more
transitory. We see this in futures markets, in which oil prices in far-dated futures contracts moved
much less than spot prices over this period, suggesting that people expected a quick reversal in any
rise in oil prices. Such transitory shocks to energy price would presumably have a smaller effect on
inflation than the more-persistent oil price shocks of the 1970s and early 1980s. Increased
globalization and other sources of increased competition may also have lowered the sensitivity of
domestic inflation to aggregate demand, thereby flattening the Phillips curve. However, the
evidence on this last point is limited and inconclusive.11
Policy Implications
These stylized facts--that inflation has become less persistent and now responds less to aggregate
demand and supply shocks--can lead to inappropriate policy advice. If we take these facts to be
structural and attributable to factors other than monetary policy, we might interpret them as
suggesting that the Federal Reserve could respond less to shocks and yet be confident that inflation
would remain at a low level. In addition, the smaller coefficient on unemployment gaps in
traditional Phillips-curve models, which seems to imply that the sacrifice ratio has gone up, might
lead us to think that reducing inflation is very costly because it requires long periods of high
unemployment. As a result, policymakers might decide that such an attempt would not be
worthwhile and so would be less likely to try to reduce inflation if it were undesirably high. If used
in model simulation exercises, the flatter Phillips curve might also suggest that getting inflation
down to a particular desired level could take an inordinately long time.
However, if we instead attribute the observed changes in inflation dynamics to better monetary
policy and a resultant better anchoring of inflation expectations, then such policy conclusions are
unwarranted. Under this alternative interpretation, the reason that inflation has become less
persistent is that monetary policy, in carrying out its dual mandate of promoting both price stability
and maximum sustainable employment, has been vigilant in maintaining a low rate of inflation on
average. But if the monetary authorities were to become complacent and to think that they could get
away with not reacting to shocks that, in their mistaken view, no longer have the potential to cause
inflation to rise persistently, then inflation expectations would surely become unhinged again. In
short, complacency that might arise from the current low inflation persistence might result in deja vu
all over again and return us to an era like the Great Inflation. These are exactly the concerns
expressed in Tom Sargent’s (2000) book on the rise and fall of U.S. inflation, in which he worries
that a misunderstanding of the inflation process might again lead to a high-inflation equilibrium.
If inflation has indeed become less persistent because better monetary policy has anchored inflation
expectations more solidly, the monetary authorities may find that they have less need to induce large
swings in economic activity to control inflation. This is a key benefit of establishing a strong
nominal anchor. Because the public has become confident that the Fed will do the right thing,
expectations now behave in a manner that makes the economy more stable to begin with. If this
hypothesis is correct, cyclical movements in interest rates need not be as great as was necessary
when expectations were unanchored. However, these favorable circumstances will persist only so
long as the monetary authorities continue to ratify the public’s expectations. Consistent with its dual
mandate, the Fed must therefore continue to respond aggressively to shocks that have potentially
persistent adverse effects on both inflation and real activity. Because long-run inflation expectations
are a key driver of trend inflation, the monetary authorities need to monitor long-run inflation

expectations closely. If they find that they are losing credibility with the markets, so that inflation
expectations begin to drift and rise above (or fall below) a desired level, they must take actions to
restore their credibility.
At the Federal Reserve, we understand the importance to the health of the economy of anchoring
inflation expectations. This is why Federal Reserve officials continually reiterate our commitment to
maximum sustainable employment and price stability, why we have been willing to make
preemptive strikes against both inflationary and deflationary pressures, and why we remain vigilant
about developments in the economy that could lead to persistent departures of inflation from levels
that are consistent with price stability.
My view--that recent changes in inflation dynamics result primarily from better-anchored inflation
expectations and not from structural change or simply the achievement of a persistent low rate of
inflation--implies some very good news: Potentially inflationary shocks, like a sharp rise in energy
prices, are less likely to spill over into expected and actual core inflation. Therefore, the Fed does
not have to respond as aggressively as would be necessary if inflation expectations were
unanchored, as they were during the Great Inflation era. Indeed, this can help explain why the recent
sharp rises in energy prices have had a much more benign effect on the real economy than they did
in the 1970s--a point that then-Governor Ben Bernanke made three years ago.
Although solidly anchored inflation expectations are indeed highly desirable, they could pose a bit
of a problem for monetary policy if they were at a level somewhat above or below the rate preferred
by policymakers. Under such circumstances, the central bank would likely be interested in shifting
the public’s expectations in a more favorable direction. Whether such adjustment would be easy or
difficult is, unfortunately, quite uncertain because we do not understand the expectations-formation
process very well. In some early models that used the rational expectations assumption, changing
inflation expectations was relatively easy and thus implied sacrifice ratios that were extremely low,
suggesting that the monetary authorities could shift inflation at little cost. However, the historical
record suggests that permanently lowering inflation expectations may require keeping monetary
policy tight for a substantial period, resulting in considerable output and employment losses for a
time.
On the other hand, as Christy and David Romer (2002) have pointed out, the Federal Reserve in the
1970s overestimated the cost of reducing inflation because estimates of sacrifice ratios by Arthur
Okun and other economists at that time proved to be too high.12 As a historical note, this provides
one explanation for the Federal Reserve’s tolerance of such high inflation at the time. The
disinflation after October 1979, carried out by the Federal Reserve under the leadership of Paul
Volcker using words, procedures, and actions that were a sharp break from the past, produced a
much lower cost of disinflation than policymakers had anticipated during the 1970s.
I think these considerations leave us with fairly wide bounds on what the costs might be of
permanently shifting long-run inflation expectations that are already anchored. On the one hand, the
historical record gives us little reason to think the costs would be as minimal as the simplest models
with rational expectations might suggest. On the other hand, overly pessimistic estimates have
proved to be wrong in the past.
Implications for Inflation Forecasts
I have argued here that the most attractive explanation for recent changes in inflation dynamics is
that expectations have become better anchored. Inflation is now less persistent and more likely to
gravitate to a trend level that is determined by where long-run inflation expectations have settled.
What implication does this have for forecasts of future inflation? In this framework, the first priority
is to determine where inflation expectations may be anchored. This task is somewhat tricky.
According to the latest reading from the Survey of Professional Forecasters (SPF), long-term
inflation expectations are currently around 2 percent, as measured by the PCE price index that the
FOMC has emphasized. The private forecasters appear to have held this view for many years, given
that long-run expectations for CPI inflation in the SPF have been running at around 2-1/2 percent
since the late 1990s, and that the average historical wedge between the CPI measure and the PCE

measure of inflation has been about 50 basis points.13
Of course, the views of professional forecasters may not be representative of what the average
person or firm is thinking.If we turn to the financial markets, we find that inflation expectations
extracted from a comparison of the yields between Treasury inflation-protected securities (TIPS)
and standard Treasury securities seem consistent with an anchor at or perhaps a little above 2
percent in terms of PCE inflation.14 I say “seem consistent,” because we cannot be sure about at
least one of the items used in the extraction, the premium paid to investors to compensate them for
inflation risk. In the case of households, long-term inflation expectations from the Reuters/Michigan
survey have been running much higher for a number of years, at around 3 percent. However, this
figure seems overstated in light of the persistent bias found in the short-term inflation expectations
reported by this survey. Correcting for the bias, these survey results are probably more in line with
PCE inflation closer to 2 percent.15 As for firms, we unfortunately have no good data on their
inflation expectations. More information on this score would be particularly welcome, but
expectations in general is an area worthy of further study.
Taken together, the data suggest to me that long-run inflation expectations are currently around 2
percent. That said, I think it should be clear that the evidence points to a range of estimates;
moreover, this range is itself uncertain because of the assumptions needed to tease point estimates
from the available data. So, although I think that 2 percent is a reasonable estimate of current longrun expectations, I don’t want to overstate the precision of this figure. We still face some uncertainty
in this regard, and policymakers must be cautious about placing too much confidence in any one
estimate.
If long-run expectations are in fact about 2 percent, where is actual inflation likely to be headed in
the next year or two? While recognizing how embarrassingly wrong such prognostications often
turn out to be, I think that we can be reasonably optimistic that core PCE inflation will gradually
drift down from its latest twelve-month reading of 2-1/4 percent. This process may take a while in
light of the recent rebound in prices for gasoline and other petroleum products. These price increases
have boosted the cost of producing many non-energy goods and services, and as firms gradually
pass on these higher costs to their customers, monthly readings on the change in core prices are
likely to be higher than they otherwise would be. Once this process is completed, however, we
might expect consumer price inflation to move into better alignment with long-run expectations and
thus settle in around 2 percent. Of course, our understanding of the empirical links between our
measures of expected inflation and actual inflation is sufficiently poor that things could well go
awry with this forecast. Moreover, many things could happen in the coming months to alter the
outlook, as the recent fluctuations in energy markets and swings in GDP growth illustrate.
Looking to the medium term, I am less optimistic about the prospects for core PCE inflation to
move much below 2 percent in the absence of a determined effort by monetary policy. For the most
part, this assessment--which I should stress is subject to considerable uncertainty--flows from my
view that long-term expectations appear to be well anchored at a level not very far below the current
rate of inflation. If so, a substantial further decline in inflation would require a shift in expectations,
and such a shift could be difficult and time consuming to bring about, as I noted earlier.
As I mentioned at the start, central bankers are acutely interested in the inflation process. This is
why I have thought about the topic a lot and chosen to talk about it today. I hope you have found my
musings on this subject useful.

References
Bernanke, Ben (2004). "The Great Moderation," speech delivered at the meeting of the Eastern
Economic Association, Washington, D.C., February 20.

Boivin, Jean, and Marc Giannoni (forthcoming) "Has Monetary Policy Become More Effective?"
Review of Economics and Statistics.
Borio, Claudio, and Andrew Filardo (2006). "Globalisation and Inflation: New Cross-Country
Evidence on the Global Determinants of Domestic Inflation," unpublished paper, Bank for
International Settlements, Basel, Switzerland (March).
Cecchetti, Stephen G., Peter Hooper, Bruce C. Kasman, Kermit L. Schoenholtz, and Mark W.
Watson (2007). "Understanding the Evolving Inflation Process," presentation at the U.S. Monetary
Policy Forum, Washington, D.C., March 9.
Clarida, Richard, Jordi Gali, and Mark Gertler (2000). "Monetary Policy Rules and Macroeconomic
Stability: Evidence and Some Theory," Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 115 (February), pp.
147-80.
Cogley, Timothy, and Thomas Sargent (2005). "Drifts and Volatilities: Monetary Policies and
Outcomes in the Post WWII U.S.," Review of Economic Dynamics, vol. 8 (April), pp. 262-302.
Friedman, Milton (1957). Theory of the Consumption Function. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton
University Press.
Hanson, Bruce (1999). "The Grid Bootstrap and the Autoregressive Model." Review of Economics
and Statistics, vol. 81 (November), 594-607.
Hellerstein, Rebecca, Deirdre Daly, and Christina Marsh (2006). "Have U.S. Import Prices Become
Less Responsive to Changes in the Dollar?" Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Current Issues in
Economics and Finance, vol. 12 (September), pp. 1-7.
Hooker, Mark A. (2002). "Are Oil Shocks Inflationary? Asymmetric and Nonlinear Specifications
versus Changes in Regime," Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, vol. 34 (May), pp. 540-61.
Ihrig, Jane, Steven Kamin, Deborah Lindner, and Jaime Marquez (forthcoming). “Some Simple
Tests of the Globalization and Inflation Hypothesis,” International Finance Discussion Papers.
Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Levin, Andrew T., and Jeremy M. Piger (2004). "Is Inflation Persistence Intrinsic in Industrial
Economies?" (1.0 MB PDF) ECB Working Paper Series 334. Frankfurt, Germany: European
Central Bank, April.
Marazzi, Mario, Nathan Sheets, Robert J. Vigfusson, Jon Faust, Joseph E. Gagnon, Jaime Marquez,
Robert F. Martin, Trevor A. Reeve, and John H. Rogers (2005). "Exchange Rate Pass-Through to
U.S. Import Prices: Some New Evidence," International Finance Discussion Papers 833.
Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, April.
Nason, James M. (2006). "Instability in U.S. Inflation: 1967-2005," Federal Reserve Bank of
Atlanta, Economic Review, vol. 91 (Second Quarter), pp. 39-59.
Okun, Arthur M. (1978). "Efficient Disinflationary Policies," American Economic Review, vol. 68
(May), pp. 348-52.
O’Reilly, Gerard, and Karl Whelan (2005). "Has Euro-Area Inflation Persistence Changed over
Time?" Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 87 (November), pp. 709-20.
Roberts, John M. (2006). "Monetary Policy and Inflation Dynamics," International Journal of
Central Banking, vol. 2 (September), pp. 193-230.
Romer, Christina D., and David H. Romer (2002). "The Evolution of Economic Understanding and

Postwar Stabilization Policy," in Rethinking Stabilization Policy, proceedings of a symposium
sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Jackson Hole, Wyoming, August 29-31, pp.
11-78.
Rudebusch, Glenn D. (2005). "Assessing the Lucas Critique in Monetary Policy Models," Journal
of Money, Credit, and Banking, vol. 37(April), pp. 247-72.
Sargent, Thomas J. (2000). The Conquest of American Inflation. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton
University Press.
Sekine, Toshitaka (2006). "Time-Varying Exchange Rate Pass-Through: Experiences of Some
Industrial Countries," BIS Working Paper 202. Basel, Switzerland: Bank for International
Settlements, March.
Stock, James, and Mark Watson (2007). "Why Has U.S. Inflation Become Harder to Forecast?"
Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, vol. 39 (February), pp. 3-34.
Williams, John C. (2006). "The Phillips Curve in an Era of Well-Anchored Inflation Expectations,"
unpublished working paper, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, September.

Footnotes
1. I want to thank Michael Kiley, Jean-Philippe Laforte, Deborah Lindner, David Reifschneider,
John Roberts, and Jeremy Rudd for their extremely helpful comments and assistance on this speech.
Return to text
2. Two recent studies that report a marked decline in inflation persistence in the United States are
Nason (2006) and Williams (2006). Their findings should be treated carefully, however, as analysis
by the staff of the Federal Reserve Board suggests that modest changes in methodology, such as
lengthening the sample period, correcting for small-sample bias, or changing the particular price
index used in the analysis, can alter both the magnitude and the statistical significance of the
estimated decline in persistence. Return to text
3. Levin and Piger (2004) find significant declines in inflation persistence since the 1980s for the
major European economies as well as for Japan, Canada, Australia and New Zealand. However,
O’Reilly and Whelan (2005) find little or no evidence for a recent decline in persistence for the euro
area as a whole. Return to text
4. Studies that present evidence of a marked decline in the sensitivity of U.S. inflation to
unemployment and other measures of resource utilization include Roberts (2006) and Williams
(2006). Unpublished work by staff at the Federal Reserve Board indicates that this result generally
holds across a variety of regression specifications, estimation methods, and data definitions. Other
studies find similar declines in many foreign industrial economies; see, among others, Borio and
Filardo (2006) and Ihrig and others (forthcoming). However, the empirical evidence on this question
is such that the exact magnitude, timing, and statistical significance of these changes remain a
subject of debate. Return to text
5. Hooker (2002) finds that oil price movements during the 1980s and 1990s had little or no effect
on core inflation, in contrast to a substantial influence in previous decades. Recent empirical work
carried out at the Federal Reserve Board confirms Hooker’s findings using data through 2006;
however, some of this work also hints that the surge in energy prices since 2004 may have had a
larger influence on core inflation. Return to text
6. Interestingly, Ihrig and others (forthcoming) find that the sensitivity of inflation to movements in
import prices has fallen in several foreign industrial economies. Return to text

7. For evidence on U.S. exchange rate pass-through effects, see Marazzi and others (2005).
Hellerstein, Daly, and Marsh (2006) also find that pass-through has declined in the United States,
although by a considerably smaller amount. Empirical results for other developed countries are
reported in Sekine (2006). Return to text
8. The FRB/US series splices data from two surveys of expected long-run inflation--the Hoey
survey of financial market participants from 1981 through 1989, and the Survey of Professional
Forecasters from 1990 on. After splicing, a 50-basis-point constant factor is subtracted from the
series to put it on a PCE price index basis, on the assumption that survey respondents reported their
expectation for CPI inflation, not PCE inflation. (The average wedge between CPI inflation and
PCE inflation was about 50 basis points from 1980 through 2006.) I have made a similar adjustment
to the Livingston survey data plotted in figure 3 to put it on a PCE price basis. Return to text
9. Clarida, Gali, and Gertler (2000) make a similar argument, but for a dissenting view, see
Rudebusch (2005). Return to text
10. This is why Milton Friedman’s Theory of the Consumption Function is one of my favorite pieces
of empirical research. What is extraordinary about this book is that it has only a handful of
regressions but nonetheless shows that the basic idea of permanent income has to be right because
the theory explains numerous facts derived from numerous studies. This book is not widely read by
graduate students nowadays, but it should be. Return to text
11. See Borio and Filardo (2006) and Ihrig and others (forthcoming) for opposing views on this
issue. Borio and Filardo provide evidence that global output gaps may be just as important as
conventional domestic output gaps in the determination of inflation; moreover, they argue that these
effects have been rising over time. However, Ihrig and her co-authors find that Borio and Filardo’s
results are sensitive to small changes in specification; they also find little support for an independent
role of global output gaps and no evidence that globalization can account for falling coefficients on
domestic gaps. Return to text
12. Okun (1978) estimated that a 10 percent reduction in real GDP for one year would reduce the
inflation rate only 1.0 percentage point. By the mid-1980s, however, Federal Reserve Board staff
estimates of the sacrifice ratio were roughly half as large. Return to text
13. Recently, the Survey of Professional Forecasters (SPF) has begun to report long-run
expectations for the PCE price index as well as the CPI. Long-run expectations for PCE price
inflation were 2 percent in the latest release, the same rate as indicated by the FRB/US estimate
since the late 1990s. (The FRB/US estimate since 1991 derives from the SPF reading on expected
long-run CPI inflation less an average historical wedge between the CPI measure and the PCE
measure of inflation of about 50 basis points.) Interestingly, long-run expectations for CPI inflation
in the SPF ticked down to 2-1/3 percent in the latest survey, suggesting that private forecasters may
have lowered their estimate of the average CPI-PCE wedge to about 30 basis points. Such a
revision would be in line with current Board staff estimates, which indicate that the wedge has
declined in recent years and now stands at about 30 basis points. Return to text
14. Inflation compensation--the difference between nominal and indexed Treasury yields--has
recently been about 2-1/2 percent. However, two adjustments are necessary to translate inflation
compensation into an estimate of expected long-term inflation on a PCE price basis. First, because
the difference between nominal and indexed yields equals the sum of inflation expectations and an
inflation term premium, we must subtract an estimate of the premium. Given that term premiums on
nominal Treasury yields are extremely low at present, the inflation term premium is probably less
than 25 basis points currently, and could even be zero. Second, because the inflation series used to
index the Treasury securities is the CPI, not the PCE price index, we must subtract an estimate of
the wedge between the two measures of inflation. If we use the same 30 basis points wedge
expected by private forecasters in the latest reading from the SPF, indexed and nominal yields
appear to be consistent with expected long-term PCE inflation of about 2 percent or a little higher.
Return to text

15. According to the Reuters/Michigan survey, long-term inflation expectations of households are
currently around 3 percent, as they have been for the past few years. This survey does not specify a
price index. However, expectations from the companion one-year-ahead expectations have come in
about 75 basis points higher than actual PCE inflation since 1990, suggesting that there may be a
systematic bias in the responses to the Reuters/Michigan survey relative to this measure of inflation.
If this bias also applies to longer-run inflation expectations, then household expectations may be in
line with PCE inflation running in the vicinity of 2-1/4 percent in the long run. Return to text
Return to top