View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Speech
Governor Frederic S. Mishkin

At the Forecaster’s Club of New York, New York, New York
January 17, 2007

Enterprise Risk Management and Mortgage Lending
Over the past ten years, we have seen extraordinary run-ups in house prices. From 1996 to the
present, nominal house prices in the United States have doubled, rising at a 7-1/4 percent annual
rate.1 Over the past five years, the rise even accelerated to an annual average increase of 8-3/4
percent. This phenomenon has not been restricted to the United States but has occurred around the
world. For example, Australia, Denmark, France, Ireland, New Zealand, Spain, Sweden, and the
United Kingdom have had even higher rates of house price appreciation in recent years.
Although increases in house price have recently moderated in some countries, they still are very
high relative to rents. Furthermore, with the exception of Germany and Japan, the ratios of house
prices to disposable income in many countries are greater than what would have been predicted on
the basis of their trends. Because prices of homes, like other asset prices, are inherently forward
looking, it is extremely hard to say whether they are above their fundamental value. Nevertheless,
when asset prices increase explosively, concern always arises that a bubble may be developing and
that its bursting might lead to a sharp fall in prices that could severely damage the economy.
This concern has led to an active debate among monetary policy makers around the world on the
appropriate reaction to the run-ups in house prices that we have recently seen in many markets:
Should central banks raise interest rates? And how should they prepare themselves to react if
housing prices decline? These are the issues that I will address today. The views I will express are
my own and not necessarily those of my colleagues on the Federal Open Market Committee.
Home prices, like other asset prices, have important effects on output and inflation. Home prices
affect the economy in two primary ways. First, when they begin rising, the expectation of further
appreciation tends to become built into the market. That expectation boosts demand for homes,
which stimulates new construction and aggregate demand. Of course, the sustained rise in prices can
simultaneously sow the seeds of a market correction by making houses progressively less affordable
relative to income, thereby limiting the demand for them and restraining additional construction.
Second, higher home prices increase household wealth, thus stimulating consumer spending,
another component of aggregate demand.
Because central banks are in the business of managing total demand in the economy so as to
produce desirable outcomes on inflation and employment, monetary policy should accordingly
respond to home prices to the extent that these prices are influencing aggregate demand and
resource utilization. The issue of how central banks should respond to house price movements is
therefore not whether they should respond at all. Rather, the issue is whether they should respond
over and above the response called for in terms of objectives to stabilize inflation and employment
over the usual policy time horizon. The issue here is the same one that applies to how central banks
should respond to potential bubbles in asset prices in general: Because subsequent collapses of these
asset prices might be highly damaging to the economy, as they were in Japan in the 1990s, should
the monetary authority try to prick, or at least slow the growth of, developing bubbles?
I view the answer as no.

I will outline some conventional arguments for and against reacting to asset prices over and above
their direct and foreseeable effects on inflation and employment. I will also discuss some additional
reasons why central banks should not overly emphasize house prices in particular. Although I come
down squarely on the side of those who oppose giving a special role to house prices in the conduct
of monetary policy, I do think that central banks can take steps to ensure that sharp movements in
the prices of homes or other assets do not have serious negative consequences for the economy.
There is no question that asset price bubbles have potential negative effects on the economy. The
departure of asset prices from fundamentals can lead to inappropriate investments that decrease the
efficiency of the economy. For example, if home prices rise above what the fundamentals would
justify, too many houses will be built. Moreover, at some point, bubbles burst and asset prices then
return to their fundamental values. When this happens, the sharp downward correction of asset
prices can lead to a sharp contraction in the economy, both directly, through effects on investment,
and indirectly, through the effects of reduced household wealth on consumer spending.
Despite the clear dangers from asset price bubbles, the question remains as to whether central banks
should do anything about them. Some economists have argued that central banks should at times
"lean against the wind" by raising interest rates to stop bubbles from getting out of hand. They argue
that if a bubble has been identified, then raising interest rates will produce better outcomes. For
instance, William White, of the Bank for International Settlements, has said that "monetary policy
might rather be used in a highly discretionary way to respond to growing imbalances that were
judged by policymakers to threaten financial instability."2 Although central banks have generally
not argued that interest rates should be raised aggressively to burst asset price bubbles, statements
suggest some central bankers believe some leaning against the wind might be warranted. For
example, in the second half of 2003 and the first half of 2004, a minority of members of the
Monetary Policy Committee of the Bank of England argued for raising interest rates more than
could be justified in terms of the Bank of England's objectives for inflation over its normal policy
horizon. They said that such a move would help lower the probability of house prices rising further
and make it less likely that a house price collapse would occur later. Mervyn King, the Governor of
the Bank of England, did not advocate leaning against the wind but did suggest that, to prevent a
buildup of financial imbalances, a central bank might extend the horizon over which inflation is
brought back to target. Statements from officials at the European Central Bank also have suggested
that the possibility of an asset boom or bust might require longer than the usual one to two years in
assessing whether the price stability goal was being met.
The recent case of the Sveriges Riksbank, the Swedish central bank, is particularly interesting. I
studied the Riksbank in a report on monetary policy written with Francesco Giavazzi for the
Swedish parliament before I came to the Federal Reserve Board.3 We found that communications by
the Riksbank suggested to market participants that it was actually adjusting monetary policy to lean
against the wind of rapid increases in home prices. On February 23, 2006, the Executive Board of
the Riksbank voted to raise the repo rate 25 basis points (0.25 percentage points). This monetary
policy action was accompanied by a statement acknowledging that the inflation forecast was revised
downward. In fact the Inflation Report published on the same day also showed that inflation
forecasts had been revised downward and were below the 2 percent target at every horizon. The
Executive Board's statement pointed out that "there is also reason to observe that household
indebtedness and house prices are continuing to rise rapidly."4 It then said: "Given this, the
Executive Board decided to raise the repo rate by 0.25 percentage points at yesterday's meeting."
Not surprisingly, market participants took this statement to mean that the Riksbank was setting the
policy instrument not only to control inflation but also to restrain house prices. A similar reference
to house prices in explaining the decision to raise rates was made in the press release of January 20,
2006.
The above statements suggest that some central bankers advocate that asset prices, and in particular,
house prices, should have a special role in the conduct of monetary policy over and above their
foreseeable effect on inflation and employment. There are several objections to this view.
A special role for asset prices in the conduct of monetary policy requires three key assumptions.

First, one must assume that a central bank can identify a bubble in progress. I find this assumption
highly dubious because it is hard to believe that the central bank has such an informational
advantage over private markets. Indeed, the view that government officials know better than the
markets has been proved wrong over and over again. If the central bank has no informational
advantage, and if it knows that a bubble has developed, the market will know this too, and the
bubble will burst. Thus, any bubble that could be identified with certainty by the central bank would
be unlikely ever to develop much further.
A second assumption needed to justify a special role for asset prices is that monetary policy cannot
appropriately deal with the consequences of a burst bubble, and so preemptive actions against a
bubble are needed. Asset price crashes can sometimes lead to severe episodes of financial
instability, with the most recent notable example among industrial countries being that of Japan. In
principal, in the event of such a crash, monetary policy might become less effective in restoring the
economy's health. Yet there are several reasons to believe that this concern about burst bubbles may
be overstated.
To begin with, the bursting of asset price bubbles often does not lead to financial instability. In
research that I conducted with Eugene White on fifteen stock market crashes in the twentieth
century, we found that most of the crashes were not associated with any evidence of distress in
financial institutions or the widening of credit spreads that would indicate heightened concerns
about default.5 The bursting of the recent stock market bubble in the United States provides one
example. The stock market drop in 2000-01 did not substantially damage the balance sheets of
financial institutions, which were quite healthy before the crash, nor did it lead to wider credit
spreads. At least partly as a result, the recession that followed the stock market drop was very mild
despite some severely negative shocks to the U.S. economy, including the September 11, 2001,
terrorist attacks and the corporate accounting scandals in Enron and other U.S. companies; the
scandals raised doubts about the quality of information in financial markets and ultimately did
indeed widen credit spreads.
There are even stronger reasons to believe that a bursting of a bubble in house prices is unlikely to
produce financial instability. House prices are far less volatile than stock prices, outright declines
after a run-up are not the norm, and declines that do occur are typically relatively small. The loanto-value ratio for residential mortgages is usually substantially below 1, both because the initial loan
is less than the value of the house and because, in conventional mortgages, loan-to-value ratios
decline over the life of the loan. Hence, declines in home prices are far less likely to cause losses to
financial institutions, default rates on residential mortgages typically are low, and recovery rates on
foreclosures are high. Not surprisingly, declines in home prices generally have not led to financial
instability. The financial instability that many countries experienced in the 1990s, including Japan,
was caused by bad loans that resulted from declines in commercial property prices and not declines
in home prices. In the absence of financial instability, monetary policy should be effective in
countering the effects of a burst bubble.
Many have learned the wrong lesson from the Japanese experience. The problem in Japan was not
so much the bursting of the bubble but rather the policies that followed. The problems in Japan's
banking sector were not resolved, so they continued to get worse well after the bubble had burst. In
addition, with the benefit of hindsight, it seems clear that the Bank of Japan did not ease monetary
policy sufficiently or rapidly enough in the aftermath of the crisis.
A lesson that I draw from Japan's experience is that the serious mistake for a central bank that is
confronting a bubble is not failing to stop it but rather failing to respond fast enough after it has
burst. Deflation in Japan might never have set in had the Bank of Japan responded more rapidly
after the asset price crash, which was substantially weakening demand in the economy. If deflation
had not gotten started, Japan would not have experienced what has been referred to by economist
Irving Fisher as debt deflation, in which the deflation increased the real indebtedness of business
firms, which in turn further weakened the balance sheets of the financial sector.
Another lesson from Japan is that if a burst bubble harms the balance sheets of the financial sector,

the government needs to take immediate steps to restore the health of the financial system. This
should involve structural improvements in the way banks operate, not bailing out insolvent
institutions. The prolonged problems in the banking sector are a key reason that the Japanese
economy did so poorly after the bubble burst.
A third assumption needed to justify a special focus on asset prices in the conduct of monetary
policy is that a central bank actually knows the appropriate monetary policy to deflate a bubble. The
effect of interest rates on asset price bubbles is highly uncertain. Although some theoretical models
suggest that raising interest rates can diminish the acceleration of asset prices, others suggest that
raising interest rates may cause a bubble to burst more severely, thus doing even more damage to the
economy. An illustration of the difficulty of knowing the appropriate response to a possible bubble
was provided when the Federal Reserve tightened monetary policy before the October 1929 stock
market crash because of its concerns about a possible stock market bubble. With hindsight,
economists have viewed this monetary policy tightening as a mistake.
Given the uncertainty about the effect of interest rates on bubbles, raising rates to deflate a bubble
may do more harm than good. Furthermore, altering the trajectory of interest rates from the path
predicted to have the most desirable outcomes for inflation and employment over the foreseeable
horizon has the obvious cost of producing deviations from these desirable outcomes.
Because I doubt that any of the three assumptions needed to justify a special monetary policy focus
on asset prices holds up, I am in the camp of those who argue that monetary policy makers should
restrict their efforts to achieving their dual mandate of stabilizing inflation and employment and
should not alter policy to have preemptive effects on asset prices.
However, there is a further reason why I believe that a central bank should not put too much focus
on asset prices. Such a focus can weaken its public support, making it harder for it to successfully
conduct monetary policy to stabilize inflation and employment.
A central bank that focuses intently on asset prices looks as if it is trying to control too many
elements of the economy. Part of the recent successes of central banks throughout the world has
been that they have narrowed their focus and have more actively communicated what they can and
cannot do. Specifically, central banks have argued that they are less capable of controlling real
economic trends in the long run and should therefore focus more on price stability and damping
short-term economic fluctuations. By narrowing their focus, central banks in recent years have been
able to increase public support for their independence. A central bank that expanded its focus to
asset prices could potentially weaken its public support and may even cause the public to worry that
it is too powerful and has undue influence over all aspects of the economy.
Too much focus on asset prices might also weaken support for a central bank by leading to public
confusion about its objectives. When my co-author and I conducted our evaluation of monetary
policy in Sweden, I directly observed this problem. I heard over and over again in interviews with
participants from different sectors of Swedish society that the statements about house prices by the
Riksbank confused the public about what it was trying to achieve.
My discussion so far indicates that central banks should not put a special emphasis on prices of
houses or other assets in the conduct of monetary policy. This does not mean that central banks
should stand by idly when such prices climb steeply. Rather my analysis suggests that central banks
can take steps to make it less likely that sharp movements in asset prices will have serious negative
consequences for the economy.
Instead of trying to preemptively deal with the bubble--which I have argued is almost impossible to
do--a central bank can minimize financial instability by being ready to react quickly to an asset price
collapse if it occurs. One way a central bank can prepare itself to react quickly is to explore different
scenarios to assess how it should respond to an asset price collapse. This is something that we do at
the Federal Reserve.

Indeed, examinations of different scenarios can be thought of as stress tests similar to the ones that
commercial financial institutions and banking supervisors conduct all the time. They see how
financial institutions will be affected by particular scenarios and then propose plans to ensure that
the banks can withstand the negative effects. By conducting similar exercises, in this case for
monetary policy, a central bank can minimize the damage from a collapse of an asset price bubble
without having to judge that a bubble is in progress or predict that it will burst in the near future.
Another way that a central bank with bank supervisory authority can respond to possible bubbles is
through prudential supervision of the financial system. If elevated asset prices might be leading to
excessive risk-taking on the part of financial institutions, the central bank, as in the case of the
United States, can ask financial institutions if they have the appropriate practices to ensure that they
are not taking on too much risk. Working through supervisory channels has the advantage not only
of helping make financial institutions better able to cope with possible asset price declines but
possibly also of indirectly restraining extreme asset prices if they have been stimulated by excessive
bank financing. Also, reminding institutions to maintain risk-management practices appropriate to
the economic and financial environment could potentially help lessen a buildup of excessive asset
prices in the first place.
Even if the central bank is not involved in the prudential supervision directly, it can still play a role
through public communication, particularly if it has a vehicle like the financial stability reports that
some central banks publish. In these reports, central banks can evaluate whether rises in asset prices
might be leading to excessive risk-taking on the part of financial institutions or whether distortions
from inappropriate tax or regulatory policy may be stimulating excessive valuations of assets. If this
appears to be happening, the central bank's discussion might encourage policy adjustment to remove
the distortions or encourage prudential regulators and supervisors to more closely monitor the
financial institutions they supervise.
Large run-ups in prices of assets such as houses present serious challenges to central bankers. I have
argued that central banks should not give a special role to house prices in the conduct of monetary
policy but should respond to them only to the extent that they have foreseeable effects on inflation
and employment. Nevertheless, central banks can take measures to prepare for possible sharp
reversals in the prices of homes or other assets to ensure that they will not do serious harm to the
economy.

Footnotes
1. House prices are measured with the repeat-transaction price index of the Office of Federal
Housing Enterprise Oversight. Return to text
2. William R. White (2004), "Making Macroprudential Concerns Operational," speech delivered at
the Financial Stability Symposium sponsored by the Netherlands Bank, Amsterdam, October 25-26
(www.bis.org/speeches/sp041026.htm). Return to text
3. Francesco Giavazzi and Frederic S. Mishkin (2006), "An Evaluation of Swedish Monetary Policy
between 1995 and 2005" report published by the Riksdag (Swedish parliament) Committee on
Finance; refer to Sveriges Riksbank (2006), "Assessment of Monetary Policy," press release,
November 28, www.riksbank.com/templates/Page.aspx?id=23320. Return to text
4. Sveriges Riksbank (2006). "Repo Rate Raised by 0.25 Percentage Points," press release, February
23, www.riksbank.com/templates/Page.aspx?id=20502. Return to text
5. Frederic S. Mishkin and Eugene N. White (2002), "U.S. Stock Market Crashes and Their
Aftermath: Implications for Monetary Policy," NBER Working Paper Series 8992. Cambridge,
Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research, June; also in William Curt Hunter, George G.
Kaufman, and Michael Pomerleano, eds., Asset Price Bubbles: The Implications for Monetary,

Regulatory, and International Policies. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, pp. 53-80. Return to text
Return to top