View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FRB: BOSTON. ADDRESSES.

The Taxable Bond Option
by

Frank E. Morris, Pres ident
Federal Reserve Bank of Boston

An Address

Before the

Nation~l Tax Association
Symposium on Urban Fiscal Problems

Mayflower Hotel
Washington, D. C.

July 15, 1976

The taxable municipal bond option has been on
the nation's legislative agenda for seven years.
What I propose to do today is to set forth what I, as
a long-time advocate of the taxable bond option, think
it would accomplish and to analyze the reasoning of
those who have thus far succeeded in preventing its
adoption.

In so doing, I will be speaking only for

myself and not for the Federal Reserve System.
The taxable bond option has become associated in
the minds of some with other measures designed to
alleviate the financial problems of our older cities.
This is an improper association.

The taxable bond

option is a tool to improve the efficiency of our
financial markets and, at the same time, to reduce
substantially the element of inequity in our income
tax system which stems from tax exemption.

It will

reduce the interest costs on municipal borrowings,
but the benefits will accrue proportionally as much
to cities with strong credit ratings as to those with
serious financial problems.

The case for the taxable

bond option was just as strong back in 1969, before the
urban financial crisis had manifested itself in its
present proportions, as it is today.

-2-

The taxable bond option would accomplish four things:
(1) The efficiency of the municipal bon<l market
would be improved and the net interest costs
on State and local borrowings would decline.
(2) The element of tax inequity stemming from
tax exempt bonds would be reduced substantially
by widening the spread between taxable and taxexempt yields.
(3) The efficiency of the present subsidy given
thro~gh tax exemption would be improved; i.e.,
more of the benefits of tax exemption would
accrue to State and local governments and
less to the bond holders.
(4) Everything else being equal, equity prices
would rise relative to bond prices, strengthening
our financial system.
The extent of these effects would depend on the level
of the subsidy on taxable bonds.

The process would

be automatic and market determined, as market participants reacted to a new set of conditions.
There are three principal groups of buyers of
tax-exempt municipal bonds:

commercial banks, casualty

insurance companies and well-•to-do individuals.

During

the decade of the 60 1 s the commercial banks were the
backbone of the market, taking 63% of the new issue volume.!/

-3-

The casualty companies typically move in and out of
the market, depending on their need for tax-exempt
income.

Individuals have been the residual buyers,

filling the gap when institutional buying was not
sufficient to clear the market.
As long as institutional buying was substantial,
as it was during most of the 60's, the market performed
t
reasonably efficiently. The need to broaden the market
now through the taxable bond option stems from the
fact that the major institutional buyer of the past,
the commercial banks, has largely withdrawn from the
market.

Nor are the banks likely to return to their

buying habits of the 60's.
In the first quarter of 1976, commercial banks were
acquiri~g financial assets at a $25.8 billion rate,
while business loans were declining in volume.

In

similar periods of the past, commercial banks put a
substantial part of their available funds into municipal bonds.

However, in the first quarter of 1976

they actually liquidated municipals at a $2 billion
annual rate.~/

-4-

In part, this reflects the fact that commercial
banks had a poor earnings experience in the first
quarter of 1976; but, more fundamentally, it reflects
the fact that the banks are loaded up with municipals.
In the preceding 15 years, commercial banks made a
major portfolio shift out of United States Government
securities into municipals.

This was a one-shot deal

which cannot be duplicated in the future.

The commer-

cial banks simply will not have the capacity to support
the municipal bond market in the future to anywhere
near the extent that they did in the 1960 1 s.
When the commercial banks pull out of the market,
the residual to be taken up by individuals rises.

To

clear the market, interest rates on municipals have
to rise relative to rates on Treasury and corporate
securities in order to attract the marginal individual
investor.

When this happens, the high bracket individ-

ual investor receives a windfall and the split of the
benefits of tax exemption is shifted toward the investor
and away from State and local governments.

-5-

In the present market, there is no limit to the
narrowness of the spread between tax-exempt and taxable
yields.

The spread must narrow to that point where

the marginal individual investor can be persuaded to
take up the remaining supply.

With the taxable bond

option, the interest subsidy rate would automatically
limit the narrowing of the spread beyond a specific
point.

With an interest subsidy of 35%, for example,

tax-exempt yields could never exceed 65% of the taxable
equivalent.

Whenever the tax-exempt market could not

absorb the supply at that level, new issues would
spill over into the taxable market.
To use a numerical example, let us assume that
a municipality faced a market in which it could sell longterm bonds for 7-1/2% on a tax-exempt basis and 10%
on a taxable basis.

With a 35% interest subsidy on

taxable bonds, the municipality facing this choice
would choose to sell the bonds on a taxable basis; since
the net interest cost would be 6-1/2%.

Not until the

available supply of tax-exempts had shrunk to the point
where the marginal buyer would be willing to accept a
tax-exempt yield of 6-1/2% would this municipality
again sell its bonds on a tax-exempt basis.

-6-

The first product of the taxable bond option, of course,
is that the municipality saved 1% in interest costs.
The second product is that the supply of tax-exempt
bonds would shrink, driving the yield down to the 6-1/2%
level for this municipality.

The resulting permanent

widening of the · spread between tax-exempt and taxable
yields would reduce the element of inequity introduced
into our income tax system by tax-exemption, since the
size of the windfall to high-bracket investors is
inversely related to the size of the spread between
taxable and tax-exempt yields.
Futhermore, it would improve the efficiency of the
present subsidy given through tax exemption.

The most

recent estimate I have seen is that tax exemption on
municipal bonds cost the Treasury $4.8 billion in foregone tax receipts in fiscal 1976.

Of this total, $3.5

billion was passed on to State and local governments
in the form of lower interest costs and $1.3 billion
3/
. d b y private
.
.
was retaine
investors.-

In other words,

for every $1 of interest costs saved by State and
local governments, the cost to the United States
Treasury is $1.37.

The taxable bond option would,

over the years, work to improve this relationship
substantially.

-7By reducing the level of yields on tax-exempt bonds,
the taxable bond option will also have one other significant product:

it will tend to raise the price of equities

relative to the price of debt instruments.

In a well-

organized capitalist economy, wealthy individuals should
be induced to invest in risk-bearing assets.

Tax

exemption on municipal bonds, to the contrary, provides
extra incentives for the wealthy to invest in relatively
risk-free assets.

The more inefficient the municipal

market, the stronger the incentive.

A 7% municipal bond

yield provides a 14% taxable equivalent yield to someone
in the 50% bracket, more than 14% if the interest is also
exempt from State income taxes.

This is formidable

competition for the stock market where the historic
long-term yield has been 9%.
There is little doubt in my mind that the taxable
bond option, by reducing the level of tax-exempt yields
relative to taxable yields, will drive some funds which
would otherwise have been lodged in municipal bonds
into the stock market.

This would strengthen our financial

system in a most fundamental way.

-8-

The Arguments in Opposition
If the taxable bond option has the potential for
accomplishing all of these things, why has it failed
thus far to pass the Congress?
The principal arguments in opposition are the following:
1.

The fear that the taxable bond option will
inevitably lead to the elimination of the
tax-exempt privilege, leaving State and local
governments even more dependent on the Federal
Government than they are today.

2.

The budget costs of the interest subsidy
to the Treasury.

3.

The notion that it would be difficult for
municipal bonds to compete in the taxable
market.

4.

The contrary notion that so many taxable
municipals would be sold as to drive up
interest costs to the Treasury and corporate
borrowers.

S.

The concern that the taxable bond option will
lead to self-dealing by State and local governments
with their own pension funds.

Of these, only the first argument has much substance.
Over the past four decades, State and local governments
have become more and more dependent upon the Federal

-9-

Government.

One of their most prized vestiges of

sovereignty is their ability to issue tax-exempt
bonds freely without reference to Washington.

It

is the fear that the taxable bond option will turn
out to be a "Trojan horse" rather than a "gift horse"
that has led many State and local officials to oppose
it.
How realistic is this fear?

Since passage of the

income tax amendment to the Constitution in 1913, the
Treasury Department has, more or less continuously,
been seeking to eliminate tax exemption on
municipal bonds.!/
survived.

Nonetheless, tax exemption has

How is this political phenomenon to be

explained?

The answer, I believe, is that state and

local government officials, whenever they are firmly
united on an issue, probably constitute the most powerful lobby in Washington.

The lack of awareness of this

political muscle among State and local officials stems
from the fact that they are seldom firmly united on any
issue.

It is impossible to find a substantial community

of in_Jerest between the officials of large cities and
the administrators of rural countries on such issues as
urban mass transit and welfare reform, or between
northern and southern officials on the price of
heating oil.

-10-

On the issue of municipal bond tax exemption,
however, state and local government officials, from
large cities and rural counties, and from North and
South, have spoken with one clear voice to Congress.
Tax exemption on their bonds is a universally prized
privilege that they are not going to permit Congress
to take away from them.

Their unanimity on the issue

has succeeded for more than SO years in defeating
efforts of tax reformers to eliminate the exemption.
I see no reason to believe that they will be less
successful in the future.
The cost of the direct interest subsidy is
probably the second most influential argument used
against the taxable bond option.

Estimates of the

cost of the subsidy will vary depending on the level
of the subsidy and the set of assumptions used.
things are certain:

Two

regardless of the assumptions

used, any costs will be modest when compared to the
cost of tax exemption and the interest cost savings
to State and local governments will be a multiple of
any costs to the Treasury.~/

This subsidy, when used,

would displace the inefficient subsidy now given
through tax exemption--a subsidy through which the
interest cost savings to State and local governments
are substantially less than the costs to the Treasury.

-11-

That there should be any substantial concern about
the cost of the taxable bond option to the Treasury
is a reflection of the fact that both the Congress
and the Treasury assess direct subsidies much more
carefully than they do tax subsidies.
The notion that the obligation of State and local
governments, which by and large are high grade credits,
somehow cannot compete in a taxable market is absurd.
It is true that the serial form of municipal bonds,
which is the norm today, is not well adapted to the
pension fund and life insurance market.

This is

going to require a shift to more single-maturity
issues with sinking funds.

Since this shift will

also carry with it a better secondary market for
municipals, it will be an independent factor working
toward lower interest costs.
The contrary notion that so many taxable municipals
would be sold as to drive up interest rates sharply
on Treasury and corporate securities is vastly
exaggerated.

In 1975 the total of funds raised through

debt instruments by the non-financial sectors of the
economy was $194.6 billion, of which $15.4 billion
were State and local obligations.

Even if we assume

that half of the State and local obligations were sold
on a taxable basis, this would increase the total
volume of taxable debt instruments by only 4.3%.

A

-12substantial part of this increase in taxable instruments
would be financed by funds which otherwise would have
gone into the displaced tax-exempt bonds.

To the extent

that some of these funds flow instead into the equity
markets, causing an upward revaluation of ~quity prices
relative to the prices of debt instruments, which I
suspect would happen, I would consider that development
a net plus for the financial system.
Finally, the concern that the taxable bond option
might lead to self-dealing by municipalities with their
own pension funds is something that can be dealt with by
legislation.

H.R. 12774, the taxable bond option bill

voted out this year by the House Ways and Means Committee,
attempts to meet this potential problem by requiring that
not less than 25% of the obligations sold must be acquired
by persons who are not related entities.

If this should

prove insufficient to meet the problem, more restrictive
legislation could be imposed.
Tallying up the modest potential costs of the taxable
bond option against its very substantial potential benefits leads me to believe that it will ultimately become
law.

Since I first began writing about the taxable bond

option in 1970, I have always concluded my remarks by
stating that it was "an idea whose time had come."

I

have been a bit premature in this judgment, but with every
passing year the logic of the proposal is gaining more
adherents.

Footnotes

1/
- Federal Reserve Flaw of Funds Accounts.

2/

- Ibid.
3/
- Jahn Petersen, "Changing Conditions in the Market
for State and Local Government Debt", a study prepared for the use of the Joint Economic Committee,
Congress of the United States, April 16, 1976, p. 56.
4/
- James Maxwell, Financing State and Local Governments,
1965, p. 190.

5/
- Peter Fortune, "Impact of Taxable Municipal Bonds :
Policy Simulations with a Large Econometric Model",
Federal Reserve Bank of Boston (1974).
6/
- Federal Reserve Flow of Funds Accounts.