View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

EMBARGOED UNTIL
8:35 AM U.S. Eastern Time on
Friday, October 13, 2017 – OR UPON DELIVERY

“Making Monetary Policy:
Rules, Benchmarks,
Guidelines, and Discretion”
Eric S. Rosengren
President & Chief Executive Officer
Federal Reserve Bank of Boston
Federal Reserve Bank of Boston’s
61st Economic Conference
Boston, Massachusetts
October 13, 2017

EMBARGOED UNTIL 8:35 AM U.S. Eastern Time on Friday, October 13, 2017 OR UPON DELIVERY

“Making Monetary Policy:
Rules, Benchmarks,
Guidelines, and Discretion”
Eric S. Rosengren
President & Chief Executive Officer
Federal Reserve Bank of Boston
Federal Reserve Bank of Boston’s
61st Economic Conference
Boston, Massachusetts
October 13, 2017

Good morning and welcome to the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston’s 61st Economic
Conference. I am very much looking forward to the presentations and discussions over the
coming days. Before I begin, let me note as I always do that the views I express are my own,
not necessarily those of my colleagues at the Board of Governors or on the Federal Open Market
Committee (FOMC).
Let me also provide a bit of context for the conference. This year, our conference focuses
on a topic currently debated in Congress but longstanding among economists – whether
1

EMBARGOED UNTIL 8:35 AM U.S. Eastern Time on Friday, October 13, 2017 OR UPON DELIVERY

monetary policy should follow a rules-based approach, or focus on outcomes (like maximum
sustainable employment and stable prices) and allow policymakers discretion in determining
how best to achieve them.
This forum continues the Boston Fed’s tradition of examining economic issues and policy
questions in a nonpartisan, data-focused way – with an emphasis on actionable issues that can
impact the economic well-being of all citizens. Certainly, monetary policy impacts all
Americans.
The extraordinary measures taken to combat the financial crisis and Great Recession have
rekindled a longstanding debate: In pursuing the objectives mandated by Congress, is it in the
public’s best interest to allow policymakers discretion in setting interest rates, or – as recent
legislation would suggest – is macroeconomic performance enhanced if policymakers adhere to a
predetermined rule, for example, a “Taylor rule,” named after one of our distinguished
conference presenters, John Taylor.
The resolution of the rules vs. discretion debate will have significant consequences. And
a hallmark of the Boston Fed’s economic conference is an engaged consideration of impactful
policy topics – monetary or otherwise – encouraging frank discussion and debate. In that spirit,
over the next day and a half we will grapple with a range of questions central to the rules vs.
discretion debate – and the way forward. My colleagues and I hope this conference provides a
constructive forum for the vigorous and balanced consideration of these important issues.

2

EMBARGOED UNTIL 8:35 AM U.S. Eastern Time on Friday, October 13, 2017 OR UPON DELIVERY

An Overview of Policy Rules
Policy rules have long been central to discussions of monetary policy. I will cover some
of the positive aspects, as well as some of the drawbacks.
On the positive side, rules can capture the response of monetary policy to various
conditions over a historical period, thus providing an important benchmark and allowing
policymakers to compare potential policies to historical norms. What’s more, if the rules capture
the central bank’s actual behavior, they can make inherently complex policies more
understandable and transparent to the public. This transparency can also aid in communicating
the current and prospective stance of monetary policy – a task that has become more important as
communications operate in real time, around the clock and around the globe, with information
constantly processed by financial markets. Finally, such rules can provide more consistency
through time, even as the membership of the central bank’s policymaking committee changes.
However, in my view, policy rules can also have drawbacks. Let me provide one
example. Thirty-five years ago, when Frank Morris was president of the Federal Reserve Bank
of Boston, there was a raging debate underway about monetary policy rules – but they were
different policy rules than are currently used. At that time, many economists were arguing for
rules tied to simple money aggregates. Frank was one of the leading voices at that time in
arguing that financial innovation had degraded the information content of money aggregates, and
as a consequence, simple money-based rules would be poor guides for monetary policy.
With the benefit of hindsight, I think it is clear that Frank Morris was right: simple
money aggregate rules did not stand the test of time. A review of the recent transcripts of FOMC

3

EMBARGOED UNTIL 8:35 AM U.S. Eastern Time on Friday, October 13, 2017 OR UPON DELIVERY

meetings (released with a five-year lag) – and more recent minutes, public speeches, and
testimony – suggests very little time spent discussing monetary aggregates at the FOMC.
No simple policy rule has been widely adopted to direct policy at central banks around
the world. One reason may be that picking the wrong rule can entail significant costs: an
ineffective or inappropriate rule could produce distinctly sub-optimal results for the economy. It
could also be quite costly to a central bank’s reputation and communication efforts if the rule has
to be abandoned as a consequence.
More modern policy rules, as first described by John Taylor in his 1993 and 1999 papers,
have significant advantages over simple money aggregate rules, as they are firmly tied to the
ultimate goals that Congress has set for the Federal Reserve (the so-called dual mandate of
maximum sustainable employment and price stability) and to which it holds the central bank
accountable. While the U.S. central bank has independence in how best to achieve these goals,
the mandate itself is provided by a democratically-elected government. Thus, a policy rule that
guides actions (interest rate decisions) to reduce misses in the mandate (deviations of inflation
and employment from their targets) makes intuitive sense.
In my remarks today, I will highlight why I view policy rules tied to the central bank’s
mandate as extremely useful benchmarks. I will show, using figures from FOMC briefings five
years ago that are now publicly available, that FOMC participants do indeed regularly refer to
policy rules. However, the key point is that such briefings refer to a variety of policy rules – not
one rule alone – as different policy rules can give very different policy prescriptions. Small
deviations in the rule can lead to dramatically different policy outcomes. Of course, the same
record will show that FOMC participants refer to a number of other non-rule benchmarks as

4

EMBARGOED UNTIL 8:35 AM U.S. Eastern Time on Friday, October 13, 2017 OR UPON DELIVERY

well. 1 My view is that it’s not just rule diversity that’s important, but diversity in the overall
policy approach that builds in robustness.
In sum, I will attempt to document why benchmarking with policy rules is essential – as
well as why legislating the use of simple policy rules would, in fact, be quite counterproductive.

Policy Rules as Helpful Guides
Figure 1 shows the path of inflation over nearly 50 years. The inflation rate certainly
appears to behave quite differently prior to 1990 than after, with the earlier period reflecting
higher average inflation rates and larger cyclical moves, and the latter period showing less
volatility and rates centered around 2 to 3 percent.
Certainly, this change in inflation dynamics in part reflects central banks’ efforts to fulfill
their key role of ensuring price stability, which has been interpreted by many central banks as
having an inflation target around 2 percent. As central banks have consistently worked to attain
a 2 percent inflation target, inflation expectations have become “well-anchored” around that 2
percent goal. In fact, one of the major advantages of simple policy rules is that they can
reinforce the expectations of firms and households that inflation is likely to return to 2 percent in
the future.
Figure 2 shows the unemployment rate over nearly 50 years. Unlike the inflation chart,
the broad dynamics of the unemployment rate movements are more consistent over time. One
regularity of note is that unemployment always falls below its natural rate as the recovery
matures, and shortly thereafter rises noticeably above it. While the Federal Reserve’s dual

5

EMBARGOED UNTIL 8:35 AM U.S. Eastern Time on Friday, October 13, 2017 OR UPON DELIVERY

mandate involves achieving a low but sustainable unemployment rate, the chart suggests that
maintaining a low but sustainable unemployment rate has been quite difficult.
Because policy rules that encourage monetary policymakers to move interest rates to
achieve low sustainable unemployment and price stability are well-aligned with the Federal
Reserve’s dual mandate, it is, in fact, quite common for members of the FOMC to use such
policy rules as benchmarks. Figure 3 shows the set of policy rules provided during FOMC
briefings from 2011, the most recent period for which memos and transcripts are now publicly
available. 2 Note that there are several policy rules shown, including John Taylor’s rules from his
1993 and 1999 papers, as well as other variants commonly used in the literature. The variants of
the rules all have the dual mandate embedded in their specifications – that is, deviations from
potential output (roughly equivalent to full employment) and the inflation target generate a
prescribed federal funds rate.
While the rules share many common attributes, their modest differences can generate
very different interest rate “solutions,” as is shown in the table presented in Figure 4. Note that
the interest rate recommended by this set of rules for the second quarter of 2012 ranged from
negative 2.15 to positive 0.59. This wide dispersion in policy prescriptions highlights how
sensitive these models can be to relatively modest modeling differences. A second important
feature to note is that all but one rule resulted in a prescription for negative interest rates, with
the rule based on John Taylor’s 1999 paper implying an interest rate of -2.15 percent – a rate that
might not be feasible in practice, given the powerful incentive it would create for holding cash.

6

EMBARGOED UNTIL 8:35 AM U.S. Eastern Time on Friday, October 13, 2017 OR UPON DELIVERY

Why a Legislated Rule Would Be Problematic
Since the Federal Reserve regularly refers to monetary policy rules in its monetary policy
deliberations, why not require the Fed to follow a prescribed rule or a rule that it selects? While
using rules to capture how the Fed has historically reacted to misses in the mandate is quite
useful, as a benchmark, I would argue that rigid adherence to a rule would result in a host of
problems.
First, simple interest rate rules do not capture the full range of policy instruments
available to the central bank. While some might view this as a positive feature of rules rather
than a design flaw, I do not. Since the financial crisis, the Federal Reserve has – necessarily, and
with positive results – expanded its balance sheet, changed the composition of the balance sheet,
and changed the duration of the balance sheet.
Figure 5 shows the size of the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet over the past 25 years.
While the balance sheet was not used as a policy tool until the Great Recession and its aftermath,
in my view, the Fed is very likely to need it again in the future, 3 a consequence of living in a
low-inflation and low nominal interest rate environment. Policy rules can, and – as seen in
Figure 4 – actually did, imply negative short-term interest rates. While modestly negative policy
rates have been used by some central banks, the existence of zero-return cash still makes the use
of significantly negative policy rates problematic under current institutional arrangements. As a
result, rather than adopt negative rates, the Federal Reserve, like many other central banks,
expanded its balance sheet when additional accommodation was needed. And – as Figure 6
shows – the Fed also changed the composition of its balance sheet, increasing the fraction of
longer-maturity Treasury securities, and adding government-guaranteed mortgage-backed
securities.
7

EMBARGOED UNTIL 8:35 AM U.S. Eastern Time on Friday, October 13, 2017 OR UPON DELIVERY

Once short-term interest rates had reached the effective lower bound, these actions were
undertaken to lower longer-term interest rates so as to provide additional macroeconomic
stimulus, consistent with the negative-rate signals being sent by many simple policy rules. These
actions seem to have flattened the Treasury yield curve and reduced interest rates relative to the
Treasury yield curve.
Unfortunately, as I have noted in the past, low productivity, low population growth, and
low inflation targets imply low equilibrium nominal interest rates. As a result, it is quite likely in
my view that short-term interest rates may again hit the effective lower bound in future
recessions – again necessitating policy tools not currently captured in most simple policy rules.
A second problem I see is that parameters often specified as constants in simple policy
rules have proven to be quite variable. For example, in many formulations of simple policy
rules, the equilibrium real interest rate is set as a constant. However, Figure 7 shows that the
FOMC members have been reducing their estimates of the equilibrium real federal funds rate
quite significantly. (This reflects changes in policymakers’ views of the rate that would be
consistent with no change in inflation and unemployment.) Instead of being constant, their
estimates have moved – and moved enough to significantly alter the expected number of quarterpoint increases required to reach the “normal” or equilibrium rate.
Another parameter that is often viewed as a constant in simple policy rules is the estimate
of full employment or potential output. Figure 8 shows that FOMC participants have moved
their estimates of full employment quite significantly. While I have argued elsewhere that these
estimates may move too much, even more modest changes would imply significant deviations
from a policy rule that assumed the natural unemployment rate was a constant.

8

EMBARGOED UNTIL 8:35 AM U.S. Eastern Time on Friday, October 13, 2017 OR UPON DELIVERY

Proposed legislation covering monetary policy rules requires explanations, which can be
audited, for any deviations in the proposed rule – or deviations from the prescriptions of the rule.
However, Figure 7 and Figure 8 illustrate why such explanations might be needed at many
FOMC meetings, given the changing views of economic relationships as we get more
information about how the economy is actually responding. And because such explanations
would involve estimates of inherently unobservable concepts that are subject to significant
uncertainty, one can imagine that discussion around these explanations could become quite
complicated.
Figure 9 shows how the actual interest rate prescription emanating from a particular rule
would change given variation in key values – specifically, if one used values for full employment
(the non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment, or NAIRU) and the equilibrium real rate of
interest that reflect the variation over the past five years in FOMC participants’ median estimates
in the Fed’s Summary of Economic Projections, or SEP. The first line examines the past five
years using John Taylor’s 1993 rule with an estimate of a real interest rate of 2.25 percent and a
NAIRU of 5.45 percent, similar to the assumptions in the January 2012 SEP. The second line
uses a 1993 Taylor rule with a 0.75 percent estimate of the equilibrium real rate of interest and a
NAIRU of 4.6 percent, similar to the estimates from the September 2017 SEP. 4 The two lines
are quite different, using the same rule but different estimates of the real equilibrium interest rate
and NAIRU – reflecting the actual estimates of FOMC participants over the past five years.
Note that the differences in the two lines are material, in the context of monetary policy
decisions.

9

EMBARGOED UNTIL 8:35 AM U.S. Eastern Time on Friday, October 13, 2017 OR UPON DELIVERY

Do Simple Policy Rules Capture Actual Policy Reaction?
Figure 10 shows errors in estimating the 1993 Taylor rule, with recession shading and
lines tied to various periods of financial instability. The chart shows that the simple 1993 Taylor
rule does not do a particularly good job of tracking how the FOMC actually moved the federal
funds rate, particularly during periods of financial instability. In a paper I wrote with Joe Peek
and Geoff Tootell, 5 we analyzed how policy reacts not only to inflation and unemployment, but
to financial stability concerns, as reflected in mentions of financial stability in the FOMC
transcripts. 6 The paper more rigorously shows that concerns about financial stability, which are
not modeled in the Taylor rule, are reflected in FOMC actions.
This reflects differences in how FOMC participants think about variables that the rules,
and rules legislation, treat as constants or are not included at all. It also possibly reflects the use
of different weights on inflation and unemployment rate misses, and the use of forecasts rather
than outcomes. But it also reflects the fact that, in practice, the Federal Reserve reacts to
financial stability shocks.
The leading example for this point is the last financial crisis. In 2007, the actual federal
funds rate decreased much sooner than would have been implied by the 1993 Taylor rule. In the
case of 2007, a much slower reaction to the impending financial problems would have
exacerbated what was already a very serious economic downturn.
The failure to incorporate financial stability, or anything that reflects “tail risks” rather
than expected outcomes, will not fully capture how policymakers react in real time. During
recessions and financial crises, this can be a significant omission.

10

EMBARGOED UNTIL 8:35 AM U.S. Eastern Time on Friday, October 13, 2017 OR UPON DELIVERY

Concluding Observations
Simple policy rules are useful for many reasons, not least of which is in capturing how
monetary policy has reacted historically. This makes these rules very useful benchmarks,
providing useful guidance on how current policymakers are acting relative to how earlier FOMC
participants reacted to misses on inflation and full employment.
However, a legislated policy rule that is rigid could lead to large policy mistakes, as key
inputs to policy rules that can change over time are estimated with substantial error. From my
perspective, policy effectiveness will be better served, instead, by a more robust formulation of
monetary policy that draws on a diverse set of guidelines and benchmarks – which is the exercise
Fed policymakers conduct every six weeks for actual FOMC meetings.
Thank you, and again I extend a warm welcome to all of you participating in the
conference.

1

Such as: a variety of optimal policy simulations, equilibrium real rate comparisons, and alternative scenarios.

2

For more information on the historical use of monetary policy rules, see:
https://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/files/20170707_mprfullreport.pdf .

3

For additional perspective on use of the Federal Reserve balance sheet as a monetary policy tool, see April 2017
remarks by Eric S. Rosengren, The Federal Reserve Balance Sheet and Monetary Policy.
4

To specify the rule in terms of the Fed’s mandate, the output gap has been replaced by the gap between the longerrun and actual rates of unemployment, using Okun’s Law. Calculation uses the PCE inflation rate. Additional
information may be found here.
5

Peek, Rosengren, and Tootell. (2016) “Does Fed Policy Reveal a Ternary Mandate?” Federal Reserve Bank of
Boston Working Paper 16-11.

6

In this paper, we also allow for interest rate smoothing (including a lag of the federal funds rate), and estimate the
response to inflation and unemployment, rather than calibrating them as the original 1993 Taylor paper does. And
we estimate responses of the funds rate to forecasts, rather than data realizations.

11