View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

EMBARGOED UNTIL WEDNEDSAY, JUNE 27, 2018 AT 12:30 P.M.; OR UPON DELIVERY

Ethics and Economics: Making
Cyclical Downturns Less Severe
Eric S. Rosengren
President & CEO
Federal Reserve Bank of Boston
June 27, 2018
Fourth Annual O. John Olcay Lecture on
Ethics and Economics at the Peterson Institute for
International Economics
Washington, D.C.
bostonfed.org

John Olcay and Ethics and Economics
▶ John Olcay was an astute student of financial
markets
▶ I had the pleasure of getting to know John
through periodic trips he made to Boston
during the financial crisis
▶ He was concerned about the implications of
serious economic downturns – my topic today
▶ Ethics is not a prevalent part of the curriculum
of economics

2

More Attention to Distributional
Implications of Policy
▶ My view – negative outcomes in the economy,
and subsequently their costs, are distributed
disproportionately, which has ethical
dimensions
▶ Policymakers can make policy choices that
mitigate the impact of economic downturns –
which would help those who can least afford
the costs
▶ Today will focus on state and local government
spending, bank regulatory policy, and monetary
policy – though there are many other examples

3

Figure 1: Inflation Rate: Change in Core Personal
Consumption Expenditures (PCE) Price Index
1960:Q1 - 2018:Q1
12

Percent Change from Year Earlier

8

4

0
1960:Q1

1970:Q1

1980:Q1

1990:Q1

2000:Q1

2010:Q1

Recession

Note: Core PCE excludes food and energy.

Source: BEA, NBER, Haver Analytics

4

Figure 2: Unemployment Rate
1960:Q1 - 2018:Q1

12

Percent

10

8

6

4

2
1960:Q1

1970:Q1

1980:Q1

1990:Q1

2000:Q1

2010:Q1

Recession

Source: BLS, NBER, Haver Analytics

5

What are the Consequences of Not
Mitigating Downturns?
▶ Parts of our population are disproportionately
hurt in economic downturns
▶ Those with less education are more likely to
experience unemployment
▶ Dependents of the unemployed are severely
impacted

6

Figure 3: Unemployment Rate by Race and Ethnicity
1972:Q1 - 2018:Q1

25

Percent
Black or African American

Hispanic or Latino Ethnicity
20

Overall

15

10

5

0
1972:Q1

1982:Q1

1992:Q1

2002:Q1

2012:Q1

Recession

Note: Based on labor force age 16 and older. Persons whose ethnicity is identified as Hispanic or Latino may be of any race.
Source: BLS, NBER, Haver Analytics

7

Figure 4: Unemployment Rate by Educational
Attainment
1992:Q1 - 2018:Q1

20

Percent
Less than High School Diploma
High School Diploma, No College
Some College or Associate's Degree

15

Overall, Age 25 and Older

Bachelor's Degree or Higher

10

5

0
1992:Q1

1997:Q1

2002:Q1

2007:Q1

2012:Q1

2017:Q1

Recession

Note: Based on labor force age 25 and older.
Source: BLS, NBER, Haver Analytics

8

Figure 5: Poverty Rate of Children Under Age
18 and the Unemployment Rate
1960 - 2016
Percent

Percent
12

30

10

25

8

20

6

15

4

10

2

5

Unemployment Rate (Left Scale)
Poverty Rate of Children (Right Scale)

0

0
1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

2010

Recession

Note: The poverty rate is annual, the unemployment rate is quarterly. The most recent poverty rate is for 2016.
Source: U.S. Census Bureau, BLS, NBER, Haver Analytics

9

State and Local Government Spending
▶ Current policies are procyclical – aggravate a
downturn or add additional fuel to an already
humming economy
▶ Balanced budget requirements result in
government spending declines at times when
spending is most needed
▶ Focus on federal fiscal policy but state and local
government spending is large
▷ State and local government spending accounts for
11 percent of U.S. GDP
▷ Residential investment is 4 percent and federal
government spending is 7 percent

10

Figure 6: Growth in Real State and Local
Government Spending and the Unemployment Rate
1960:Q1 - 2018:Q1
12

Percent Change from Year Earlier

Percent

Unemployment Rate (Left Scale)
State and Local Government Spending (Right Scale)

12

9

6

6

0

3
1960:Q1

-6
1970:Q1

1980:Q1

1990:Q1

2000:Q1

2010:Q1

Recession

Source: BEA, BLS, NBER, Haver Analytics

11

Figure 7: Changes in S&P State Credit Ratings
June 1, 2013 - June 1, 2018

Number of States
by Number of Changes

Number of

Number of

Changes

Changes

States

1 Change

Downgrades

24

14

7

4

9

8

7

1

Upgrades

No Change

2 Changes 3 Changes

3

29

Note: While 29 states saw no change, one state saw both an upgrade and a subsequent downgrade. As a result,
the states add to 51. In some instances an Issuer Credit Rating is used instead of a general obligation debt rating.
Source: S&P Capital IQ

12

Structure of State and Local Government
Spending
▶ Little focus on macroeconomic consequences
▶ Tax code can be highly cyclical
▶ Spending cut in economic downturns
▶ Small rainy day funds and lingering pension
problems

▶ My view – now is the time, when the economy
is robust, to make changes that will mitigate
the next downturn
▶ While hard, given competing goals, states
should reassess their revenue structure and
fiscal approach with an eye on cyclical
downturns

13

Bank Regulation
▶ Focus on safety and soundness – viability of
financial institutions is important
▶ Structure currently encourages banks to shrink
during economic downturns to maintain
minimum capital-to-assets ratios
▶ A bank can choose to either raise capital or
shrink assets to restore the ratio
▶ Raising capital is costly during economic
downturns and generally opposed by existing
shareholders
▶ Banks most often shrink assets (loans are key
assets) which results in less lending at just the
time the economy may need stimulus
14

Figure 8: Nonperforming Loans at U.S. Banks
and the Unemployment Rate
1989:Q1 - 2018:Q1
12

Percent of Loan Balance

Percent

6

Unemployment Rate (Left Scale)
10

Nonperforming Loans (Right Scale)

5

8

4

6

3

4

2

2

1

0
1989:Q1

0
1994:Q1

1999:Q1

2004:Q1

2009:Q1

2014:Q1

Recession
Note: Nonperforming loans are loans 90 or more days past due plus loans in nonaccrual status. U.S. banks include
commercial and savings banks throughout the period and the former OTS-regulated thrifts beginning in 2012.
Source: Quarterly Bank Call Reports, BLS, NBER, Haver Analytics

15

Figure 9: Stylized Depiction of the Impact of the
Countercyclical Capital Buffer (CCyB)

Impact of a 3% Loss on Capital [with CCyB]
Impact of a 3% Loss on Capital [without CCyB]
Mgmt Excess
Buffer (2.0%)
Required Buffer 1
(2.5%)
Required Buffer 2
(2.5%)
Minimum Capital
Requirement
(4.5%)
Pre-Loss Capital Position

Losses (3.0%)

Minimum
Capital
+
Required
Buffers

Post-Loss Capital Position

Mgmt Excess
Buffer (2.0%)

Losses (3.0%)

CCyB (2.5%)
Required Buffer 1
(2.5%)
Required Buffer 2
(2.5%)
Minimum Capital
Requirement
(4.5%)
Pre-Loss Capital Position

Minimum
Capital
+
Required
Buffers
Post-Loss Capital Position

Minimum Capital Requirement + Capital Conservation Buffer, Buffer for Systemically Important Financial Institutions, and CCyB

Note: Required Buffer 1 is the Global Systemically Important Bank (GSIB) surcharge, which is the additional capital held by the
largest, most systemically important banks. The 2.5 percent level is an average calculated using FR Y-15 data as of December
2017. Required Buffer 2 is the Capital Conservation Buffer, which is set at 2.5 percent and applies to all supervised financial
institutions. The 2 percent Management Excess Buffer is computed as the median buffer for the largest, most systemically important
banks in the U.S., as of March 2018.
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of Boston

16

Bank Regulation Could Reduce
Procyclicality
▶ Countercyclical Capital Buffer – a regulatory
tool that can be used to build buffers in good
times, when there are relatively rich asset
valuations
▶ Countercyclical Capital Buffer currently used in
many European countries and Hong Kong
▶ Would enable more flexibility in the next
downturn to avoid pullback in lending

17

Figure 10: The Federal Funds Rate and the
Unemployment Rate
1960:Q1 - 2018:Q1

12

Percent

Percent

20

Unemployment Rate
(Left Scale)
Federal Funds Rate
(Right Scale)

9

15

6

10

3

5

0
1960:Q1

0
1970:Q1

1980:Q1

1990:Q1

2000:Q1

2010:Q1

Recession

Source: Federal Reserve Board, BLS, NBER, Haver Analytics

18

Figure 11: Forecasts for the Longer-Run Federal
Funds Rate from the Summary of Economic Projections
January 2012 - June 2018
5

Percent

4

3
Central Tendency
Median Federal Funds Target Rate
2
Jan-2012 Dec-2012 Dec-2013 Dec-2014 Dec-2015 Dec-2016 Dec-2017
Date of Forecast

Note: The central tendency excludes the three highest and three lowest observations.
Source: FOMC, Summary of Economic Projections (SEP)

19

Avoid Hitting Zero with Short-Term
Interest Rates
▶ Monetary policy cannot change productivity or
demographics – so a federal funds rate of zero
is a real possibility in future downturns
▶ Have tools, such as the balance sheet, but
these alternative tools may be less effective
and are certainly less well understood
▶ Proposals that provide more flexibility with the
inflation target – possibly with more focus on
an inflation range – lower the risk of short-term
rates hitting zero in the future

20

Figure 12: The Unemployment Rate and the
Natural Rate of Unemployment
1960:Q1 - 2018:Q1

12

Percent
Above the Natural Rate
Below the Natural Rate

10

Unemployment Rate
Natural Rate of
Unemployment

8

6

4

2
1960:Q1

1970:Q1

1980:Q1

1990:Q1

2000:Q1

2010:Q1

Note: The vertical lines mark the beginnings and ends of recessions.

Source: BLS, CBO, NBER, Haver Analytics

21

Current Policy
▶ When the economy runs significantly above
capacity, a recession normally ensues
▶ Correcting imbalances – higher wages and
prices or higher asset prices – can be quite
difficult
▶ Focus on getting a long recession-free period
rather than pushing the economy too hard
▶ In my view, the policy path that will increase
the probability of a longer recession-free
period is the path where the economy does
not run above capacity and thus fall far below
the sustainable unemployment rate
22

Concluding Observations
▶ The costs of economic downturns – and the
uneven distribution of their impact – are in fact
ethical issues

▶ In my view, policy can significantly mitigate
downturns
▶ More active discussion of possible alternative
policies, such as I have highlighted for fiscal,
supervisory, and monetary policymakers, are
needed
▶ Take precautions during the good times for the
inevitable future downturns
▶ Policymakers could continue and perhaps expand
their efforts to make cyclical downturns less
severe
23