View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

EMBARGOED UNTIL
12:30 P.M. Eastern Time on
Wednesday, June 27, 2018 OR UPON DELIVERY

“Ethics and Economics: Making Cyclical
Downturns Less Severe”
Eric S. Rosengren
President & Chief Executive Officer
Federal Reserve Bank of Boston
Fourth Annual O. John Olcay Lecture on
Ethics and Economics at the
Peterson Institute for International Economics
Washington, D.C.
June 27, 2018

EMBARGOED UNTIL 12:30 P.M. Eastern Time on Wednesday, June 27, 2018 OR UPON DELIVERY

“Ethics and Economics: Making Cyclical
Downturns Less Severe”
Eric S. Rosengren
President & Chief Executive Officer
Federal Reserve Bank of Boston
Fourth Annual O. John Olcay Lecture on
Ethics and Economics at the
Peterson Institute for International Economics
Washington, D.C.
June 27, 2018

Good afternoon. I want to thank the Peterson Institute for International Economics for
inviting me to join you today. I am truly honored to be asked to give a talk in memory of John
Olcay, whom I met through his connection to Harvard University professor Benjamin Friedman.
I would see John on his periodic trips to Boston; our first meeting occurred in 2007, just as
financial markets were starting to show stress. John and I shared rising concerns during this
period and, unfortunately, through what turned into the global financial crisis and “Great
Recession.”
In those days, John was troubled by the condition of financial markets, and also had a
deep concern about the human implications of serious economic downturns – a topic I am going
1

EMBARGOED UNTIL 12:30 P.M. Eastern Time on Wednesday, June 27, 2018 OR UPON DELIVERY

to focus on today. Before I do, however, let me note that the views I express are my own, not
necessarily those of my colleagues on the Federal Reserve Board of Governors, or the Federal
Open Market Committee (FOMC).
Given the matters with which John was concerned, it is very fitting that this lecture series
is focused on “Ethics and Economics.” I should note that many academic disciplines incorporate
ethics into required coursework (take medicine, philosophy, or psychology, for example), but I
would argue that ethics is not an especially prevalent part of the curriculum of economics. In
most courses, core economic concepts tend to overwhelm the syllabus and displace the study of
ethical issues. If there is any discussion of ethics in profit- or utility-maximizing frameworks,
my sense is that it might take place in the last week of an introductory economics class. Given
this underweighting in the profession, I think it is wonderful that the Peterson Institute hosts this
series dedicated to ethics and economics.
Today, my remarks will focus on some of the ways in which the impact of negative
outcomes in the economy are distributed – disproportionately, I’ll argue. These distributional
effects have ethical dimensions that should motivate economic policymakers to do more to
reduce the negative outcomes.
Given the Fed’s dual mandate – stable prices and maximum sustainable employment – it
makes sense for us to look at inflation and unemployment as we begin today. First, inflation:
Figure 1 shows that there has been quite a change in the pattern of inflation over the past 50
years, as measured by the change in the core personal consumption expenditures (PCE) price
index. In the United States, as in many advanced economies, the cyclical inflation pattern has
been significantly muted. This moderation beginning around 1980 reflects, by the way, the

2

EMBARGOED UNTIL 12:30 P.M. Eastern Time on Wednesday, June 27, 2018 OR UPON DELIVERY

important role that independent central banks could and did play in dampening the inflation
cycles seen in the past.
However, Figure 2 shows that the economic cycle, as measured by the unemployment
rate, has not been muted and has not steadily moderated like inflation.
To preview my main points, in my view the costs of high unemployment are
disproportionately borne by those who can least afford them, and a variety of actions could be
taken by policymakers to make periods of high unemployment less likely. This brings us to the
ethical dimension of economics. This is not just about thoughts or feelings – I want to talk today
about manifesting those ethical decisions in very tangible policymaking. While there are many
examples of policies that could mitigate periods of high unemployment, today I will address
three specific realms of policy – state and local government spending; bank regulatory policy;
and finally, monetary policy.
First, however, I will touch on the impact of high unemployment and its distribution
across several dimensions of the population.

The Distributional Impact of Periods of High Unemployment
The United States has spent the past nine years recovering from a severe recession. Some
populations in particular suffered disproportionately, and despite the recovery, historic gaps
persist.
Figure 3 provides the unemployment rate by racial and ethnic background from 1972 to
2018. The overall U.S unemployment rate hit 10 percent in the most recent recession – the

3

EMBARGOED UNTIL 12:30 P.M. Eastern Time on Wednesday, June 27, 2018 OR UPON DELIVERY

second such time since 1972 in which the overall unemployment rate reached 10 percent.1
However, it is striking that in every recession over this period, Black or African-American
unemployment rates have exceeded 10 percent. Moreover, in the 1982 recession the Black or
African-American unemployment rate exceeded 20 percent; and in the most recent recession, the
Black or African-American unemployment rate exceeded 15 percent. Similarly, Hispanic
unemployment during recessions is much more elevated than that of the overall population,
although not as elevated as for Black or African-Americans.
Economic recessions also disproportionately impact unemployment for those with less
education, as shown in Figure 4. The figure shows the unemployment rate by educational
attainment (ranging from less than a high school diploma, to a bachelor’s degree or higher) from
1992 to 2018.2 While the unemployment rate for those with a college education reached 5
percent during the most recent recession, the rate exceeded 15 percent for those without a high
school education.
Furthermore, while unemployment significantly impacts individuals, it also affects
families. As Figure 5 shows, the share of U.S. children under age 18 who are below the poverty
line increased significantly in the two recessions where the unemployment rate exceeded 10
percent – with more than 20 percent of children below the poverty level during the Great
Recession. Another sobering observation I take from this chart is that the child poverty rate in
the U.S. has dropped to 15 percent only once in the past nearly 60 years – hovering just above or
just below 15 percent from 1969 to 1973.
In sum, the sad reality is that unemployment disproportionately affects minorities, the
less educated, and children whose families are experiencing unemployment. The costs to both
the entire economy and to parts of our population are significant. In my view, if policies could
4

EMBARGOED UNTIL 12:30 P.M. Eastern Time on Wednesday, June 27, 2018 OR UPON DELIVERY

mitigate the severity of economic slowdowns, some of those costs could be avoided – and taking
actions now, when the economy is strong, could be particularly important to lessening the
severity of a hypothetical future downturn and its impact on individuals.

State and Local Government Spending
Fiscal policy is certainly not in the Fed’s portfolio of mandated responsibilities, but it has
a major impact on the economy so we must take it into account.3 Drawing on the historical
record, I want to suggest some opportunities for fiscal policy to address the issues I have just
highlighted. In my view, state and local government financing should be designed to buffer the
economy during recessions, or at a minimum should not reduce the stimulative effects of
spending when the economy is most troubled.
However, Figure 6 shows that since 1960, state and local government spending tends to
decline when the unemployment rate is high, and increase when the unemployment rate is low.
This pattern likely arises from the fall in state and local tax revenues during economic
downturns, coupled with a desire to spend within one’s means – after all, most state and local
governments face balanced budget requirements. But it tends to aggravate economic downturns
or add additional fuel to an already humming economy (scenarios that would be characterized as
“procyclical” in the parlance of economists). And for context, state and local government
spending is significant in the overall economy, accounting for 11 percent of U.S. GDP, compared
to 4 percent for residential investment (which also tends to fall in economic downturns) and 7
percent for federal government spending.

5

EMBARGOED UNTIL 12:30 P.M. Eastern Time on Wednesday, June 27, 2018 OR UPON DELIVERY

As I have just suggested, state and local governments likely reduce spending in
recessions for good reasons. I would suggest, however, that a number of steps can be taken by
officials that would lessen the problematic impact.
First, the cyclicality of revenue sources for state and local governments can be lessened –
in other words, revenue streams might be redesigned to move less cyclically if other competing
goals allow.4 For example, states that are highly dependent on capital gains taxes are much more
likely to experience funding shortfalls during economic downturns, so if possible, reducing this
dependence could help.5
Second, steps can be taken so that the fiscal health of a state does not drive substantial
cuts during downturns. A number of large states (such as Illinois or New Jersey) have seen
deterioration in their financial conditions over the past several years, as represented by declines
in their credit ratings (Figure 7). This is, in part, the result of chronic underfunding of pension
liabilities in some states. Ideally, a time like now – when the national economy is growing and
employment is robust – would be an opportunity, it seems to me, to prepare for the next
downturn. This would perhaps include shoring up state finances, reducing unfunded pension
liabilities, and significantly increasing “rainy day” funds.6 I am not suggesting it would be easy,
even in these economic times. But progress could be made. A similar argument could be made
for the federal government, given how beneficial it would be to have the capacity to be more
fiscally expansive in a future recession.7
In sum, my view is that in the long run, states should consider how to balance the various
competing goals of their fiscal approach – for example the goal of having stable revenue streams
and of achieving progressivity. But to return to my main point, state and local governments

6

EMBARGOED UNTIL 12:30 P.M. Eastern Time on Wednesday, June 27, 2018 OR UPON DELIVERY

should reassess their revenue structure and fiscal approach with an eye on cyclical downturns
and the potential to lessen their impact on people, through policy.

Bank Regulation
While it may seem somewhat counterintuitive, banking regulation can also amplify the
business cycle, and policymakers can look for ways to lessen these effects. For example,
lenders’ losses on loans tend to increase significantly during economic downturns, reflecting
rising unemployment and the difficulty that many households and firms have in meeting debt
obligations during hard economic times. Figure 8 shows that nonperforming loans at U.S. banks
tend to rise during periods of high unemployment and fall during periods of low unemployment.8
Certain aspects of bank regulation can actually exacerbate the consequences of this trend.
For example, capital regulations set a threshold on how low a bank’s capital – that is, its total
assets (e.g. loans) less its total liabilities (e.g. deposits) – can fall. While this is well-intended –
and designed to ensure that banks can meet all their obligations – certain aspects of capital
regulations can actually cause banks to act in a manner that essentially extends their problems to
their customers in a downturn.
When their capital-to-assets ratio gets too low, banks can choose to either raise their
capital level, or shrink assets, to restore the ratio. Raising additional capital is especially costly
during economic downturns, and is generally opposed by existing shareholders who do not want
their ownership stake diluted.
As a consequence, banks most often raise the capital-to-assets ratio by shrinking assets –
and of course, loans are key assets for banks. Thus raising the capital-to-assets ratio can mean
7

EMBARGOED UNTIL 12:30 P.M. Eastern Time on Wednesday, June 27, 2018 OR UPON DELIVERY

less lending at just the time the economy may need stimulus. And banks may try to reduce
downturn-related losses by raising interest rates or tightening lending standards – both of which
can hurt otherwise credit-worthy borrowers.
In light of all this, I would suggest that – just as state and local governments need to
shore up their finances and build their rainy day funds during a boom – it is incumbent on a bank
to raise more capital during good economic times so that it can deplete that fund during a
recession, rather than shrink loans when the economy most needs them. An important regulatory
tool that can be used to ensure that a bank builds up this so-called rainy day fund during good
times is known as the Countercyclical Capital Buffer (CCyB).9
Figure 9 shows two different ways to implement capital regulations – one using a static
capital requirement and one using a variable capital requirement. We see a hypothetical scenario
in which an economic downturn leads to a loss of 300 basis points (or 3 percentage points) on
capital. On the left, this causes the bank to fall below its capital requirement, given that the bank
was holding 200 basis points of excess capital. As just described, banks often react by shrinking
their assets to try to satisfy their capital requirement, reducing lending when borrowers most
need it.
On the right side of Figure 9, we see an alternate scenario in which the bank has
accumulated a CCyB of 250 basis points during the good economic times that precede the
downturn, as required by regulation upon the activation of the CCyB. If the CCyB is deactivated
when the economic downturn occurs and losses are realized, the bank has an additional capital
buffer of 450 basis points. As a result of the bank’s losses stemming from the economic
downturn, the buffer is consumed and reduced to zero. But the 300 basis point loss does not
push the capital ratio below what is required, and thus the incentive to reduce lending is lessened.
8

EMBARGOED UNTIL 12:30 P.M. Eastern Time on Wednesday, June 27, 2018 OR UPON DELIVERY

While this type of CCyB is currently being used in many European countries and in Hong
Kong, the CCyB in the United States remains at zero.10 Given the overall health of the economy
and the relatively rich asset valuations now prevailing, it is my view that this would be the ideal
time to build up capital buffers in the U.S. Doing so could help address the incentive that banks
will have to pull back on lending to shrink assets in a future economic downturn.11

Monetary Policy
Monetary policy is primarily conducted by moving short-term interest rates. During
good times, the interest rate is set to keep the economy at maximum sustainable employment and
at the inflation target, which is 2 percent in the United States. However, when a recession occurs
and the unemployment rate rises, policymakers push down interest rates. This has the effect of
lowering payments for households and firms that are borrowing, and ideally mitigates the
severity of the economic cycle. As Figure 10 illustrates, since the Volcker disinflation episode
in the late 1970s and early 1980s, the short-term federal funds rate has been lowered
significantly, particularly during periods of very high unemployment rates.
However, in the last economic cycle the inflation rate was relatively modest, and real
interest rates were low because of slow growth in population and productivity, so the federal
funds rate began the downturn at an already relatively low level. This meant that when the
recession hit, as the funds rate was reduced in response, it fairly quickly hit zero. Because shortterm interest rates started off low, the extent to which they could be reduced to offset high
unemployment rates was limited.

9

EMBARGOED UNTIL 12:30 P.M. Eastern Time on Wednesday, June 27, 2018 OR UPON DELIVERY

As Figure 11 shows, estimates of the equilibrium interest rate12 have been declining.
According to the FOMC’s Summary of Economic Projections (SEP), currently Fed policymakers
anticipate that the median federal funds interest rate in the long run is expected to be only 2.9
percent in nominal terms. Subtracting the Fed’s 2 percent inflation goals, this implies a long-run
real interest rate of just 0.9 percent.
While the central bank has other tools to offset economic downturns, such as expanding
its balance sheet to lower long-term interest rates, many economists view short-term interest
rates as a more effective (and certainly a better-tested and understood) countercyclical tool. The
Federal Reserve can do little to change the equilibrium real interest rate in the long run, since it
is determined more by factors such as productivity and demographics. So it is appropriate to
consider other ways to avoid hitting zero with short-term interest rates. One possibility is to
consider more flexibility with the inflation target, perhaps focusing more on an inflation range
than a specific number.13 One might allow the inflation target to rise within the range during
periods of low real rates, thus providing more room for the funds rate to fall during an economic
downturn.
Such a change in the monetary policy framework is something that should be considered,
along with a careful assessment of the potential costs and benefits. However, if the monetary
policy framework is not changed, policymakers should look at other policy tools that can more
effectively reduce the severity of recessions.
Current policy also has a role in preparing for, or postponing, the next recession. As
Figure 12 shows, over the time period since 1960, whenever the economy significantly exceeded
full employment, a recession ensued. The one counter-example is the 1960s, when fiscal policy
was quite expansionary because of the deficit-financed Vietnam War, even though the economy
10

EMBARGOED UNTIL 12:30 P.M. Eastern Time on Wednesday, June 27, 2018 OR UPON DELIVERY

was already running strong with the unemployment rate below the level associated with full
employment. However, that period was also characterized by rising inflation, which triggered
significant problems in the following decade related to elevated inflation and inflation
expectations.
Whether imbalances appear as higher wages and prices, or higher asset prices, correcting
imbalances in the economy (for example, if unemployment falls below a sustainable rate)
without a recession is a challenge for central banks to accomplish. As a result, I think the policy
path that will increase the probability of a longer recession-free period is the path where the
economy does not run above capacity and thus, fall far below the sustainable unemployment rate.
I put these notions forward as policymakers continue to seek ways to lessen the severity and
impact – particularly the disparate impact – of cyclical economic downturns.

Concluding Observations
In summary and conclusion, while ethics is not generally a central focus of the discipline
of economics, my view is that the costs of economic downturns – and the uneven distribution of
their impact – are, in fact, ethical issues. I suspect our friend John Olcay would concur. Both in
the spirit of ethics and to sharpen policy effectiveness, I believe a more active discussion should
be occurring among fiscal, supervisory, and monetary policymakers. All of them, as I have
suggested today, could continue and perhaps expand their efforts to make cyclical downturns –
and resulting periods of high unemployment – less severe.
Thank you.

11

EMBARGOED UNTIL 12:30 P.M. Eastern Time on Wednesday, June 27, 2018 OR UPON DELIVERY

1

1972 is the first date for which this breakdown is available.

2

1992 is the first date for which this breakdown is available.

For additional perspective, see remarks by Eric S. Rosengren: “Monetary, Fiscal, and Financial Stability Policy
Tools: Are We Equipped for the Next Recession?” delivered on March 23, 2018, in Washington D.C.
3

4

Tax policies have multiple, often competing goals and therefore policymakers face tradeoffs. One important goal is
to reduce income inequality. While income taxes (especially capital gains taxes) are very cyclical, they are often
more progressive (i.e., tax as a share of income is higher for higher-income households) than sales taxes and other
tax vehicles.
5

Capital gains taxes are a large revenue source for many states. Cutting or eliminating capital gains taxes will
automatically require a very large increase in sales taxes and other taxes and fees if we talk about a revenue-neutral
scenario.
6

Linking cyclical revenue sources (such as capital gains taxes) to rainy day funds could be a good compromise
among maintaining high revenue-raising capacity, improving progressivity, and reducing cyclicality. In my view,
the macroeconomic effects have probably been underweighted. For additional discussion on the needed size of state
rainy day funds, see 2014 Working Paper by Boston Fed Senior Economist Bo Zhao: “Saving for a Rainy Day:
Estimating the Appropriate Size of U.S. State Budget Stabilization Funds.”
7

It is worth noting that despite long-run fiscal challenges, lack of support during serious recessions extends the
recession, and thus extends the period of lost tax revenue, and exacerbates underlying woes in the state. In my view,
a short-term investment in a modest increase in indebtedness may pay back over time.
8

Furthermore, the combination of nonperforming loans and lower interest rates during recessions have the effect of
adding pressure to banks’ earnings.
9

For more info on the CCyB, see: https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/bcreg20160908b.htm.
In addition to the CCyB, other bank regulatory tools include the Comprehensive Capital Analysis and Review
(CCAR) and the Dodd-Frank Stress Tests (DFAST). There are countercyclical elements to the stress tests. More
stressful scenarios in good times require banks to build more capital. For more on CCAR and DFAST see
http://www.federalreserve.gov/bankinforeg/stress-tests-capital-planning.htm.
As Federal Reserve Chairman Jerome H. Powell noted in his recent press conference on June 13, 2018, “…the
countercyclical capital buffer gives us the ability to raise capital requirements on the largest institutions when
financial stability vulnerabilities are meaningfully above normal.” I am suggesting a slightly different application
might also be appropriate. (See transcript of the Chairman’s press conference here.)
10

For additional perspective, see remarks by Eric S. Rosengren: “Monetary, Fiscal, and Financial Stability Policy
Tools: Are We Equipped for the Next Recession?” delivered on March 23, 2018, in Washington D.C.
11

12

It is important to note that the equilibrium interest rate isn’t precisely known.

13

For additional perspective, see remarks by Eric S. Rosengren: Considering Alternative Frameworks: an Inflation
Range with an Adjustable Inflation Target, delivered on Jan. 12, 2018 in San Diego, California.

12