View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

EMBARGOED UNTIL
4:15 P.M. Eastern Time and 1:15 PM Pacific Time on
Friday, January 12, 2018 OR UPON DELIVERY

“Considering Alternative Monetary Policy
Frameworks: an Inflation Range With an
Adjustable Inflation Target”
Eric S. Rosengren
President & Chief Executive Officer
Federal Reserve Bank of Boston
Money, Models, & Digital Innovation Conference
Global Interdependence Center
San Diego, California
January 12, 2018

EMBARGOED UNTIL 4:15 P.M. Eastern Time, and 1:15 P.M. Pacific Time on Friday, January 12, 2018 OR UPON DELIVERY

“Considering Alternative Monetary Policy Frameworks:
an Inflation Range With an Adjustable Inflation Target”
Eric S. Rosengren
President & Chief Executive Officer
Federal Reserve Bank of Boston

Money, Models, & Digital Innovation Conference
Global Interdependence Center
San Diego, California
January 12, 2018

After spending much of the last several weeks in Boston experiencing an arctic blast, I
feel fortunate the Global Interdependence Center’s (GIC) Money, Models, and Digital
Innovation conference was held in a decidedly warmer locale. I also feel very fortunate and
honored to have received the GIC’s Frederick Heldring Award for Global Leadership from my
good friend David Kotok, who has previously led, and long been associated with, the Global
Interdependence Center’s conferences. I thank the GIC for this award, which of course honors a
remarkable individual, Fredrick Heldring, whose life story1 is inspiring. He was courageous in
2

EMBARGOED UNTIL 4:15 P.M. Eastern Time, and 1:15 P.M. Pacific Time on Friday, January 12, 2018 OR UPON DELIVERY

the Dutch Underground in World War II, successful as a banking leader, a passionate advocate
for investment in inner cities, and committed to many civic and philanthropic causes.
Before I begin my remarks today, let me note as I always do that the views I express are
my own, not necessarily those of my colleagues on the Federal Reserve Board or the Federal
Open Market Committee (FOMC).
I would like to start by reflecting on the past year’s economic performance, which was
better than most forecasters were expecting a year ago. U.S. labor markets have continued to
improve; and with the unemployment rate now at 4.1 percent, I think we have clearly left the
period of the Great Recession behind. Real GDP growth in the second and third quarters of 2017
was over 3 percent – well above the level of growth economists call “potential.” By definition, if
above-potential growth continues, as expected by many forecasters, labor markets will tighten
further, likely pushing the unemployment rate well below its sustainable rate.
Inflation has also been subdued, especially considering that it has already been a fairly
long economic recovery by historical standards. Low inflation has enabled the Federal Reserve
to pursue a very gradual exit from the extraordinary monetary policy accommodation undertaken
to address the financial crisis, the Great Recession, and the slow recovery. The Fed’s policy
accommodation, along with a well-recovered economy, have been generally good for asset
prices, including stocks.
While the economic news has remained positive, the extent of the forecast “misses” by
FOMC participants and private sector forecasters – our forecast errors for both inflation and
unemployment – are relevant for the topic of this conference on money and models. On a
quarterly basis, FOMC participants provide their economic forecasts for key economic variables,

3

EMBARGOED UNTIL 4:15 P.M. Eastern Time, and 1:15 P.M. Pacific Time on Friday, January 12, 2018 OR UPON DELIVERY

called the Summary of Economic Projections or SEP. At the December 2016 FOMC meeting,
the median SEP forecast was that 2017 would finish with the unemployment rate at 4.5 percent
and core inflation (measured using the Personal Consumption Expenditures or PCE price index)
at a rate of 1.8 percent. Instead, the unemployment rate ended up 0.4 percent lower than
expected; and core PCE inflation, based on the data through November, was 0.3 percent lower
than expected. While these are not overwhelming forecast errors by historical standards, the
inflation miss, in particular, has received significant attention by some observers – as inflation
has been lower than expected, despite labor markets that are tighter than expected.
My own perspective on this is that the recent misses in the Fed’s inflation forecast have
not been particularly large, taken in the context of the forecast errors made historically in
forecasting inflation. The forecast errors for inflation also have not been particularly consistent
or persistent, which would be expected if the Fed’s inflation models were missing some
fundamental change in the inflation process. As a result, I would argue that it does not seem
justified to assume there have been changes in the underlying inflation process, based on
relatively modest recent misses. Of course, if we continue to experience one-sided forecast
errors for another year or two, the possibility of structural change should be considered more
seriously.
Thus, I do not view the somewhat lower than expected recent inflation rate as particularly
troublesome for near-term monetary policy. But looking to the medium and long run, I do see
low and fixed inflation targets as a potential problem – particularly if we continue to experience
low productivity growth, a low equilibrium interest rate, and the near-certainty of a slowly
growing and aging workforce. In such an environment, with a two percent inflation goal,
nominal interest rates are likely to be low, on average. As a consequence, when a recession
4

EMBARGOED UNTIL 4:15 P.M. Eastern Time, and 1:15 P.M. Pacific Time on Friday, January 12, 2018 OR UPON DELIVERY

eventually does occur, policymakers would likely start with a low policy rate – perhaps 3 percent
or so – leaving little room to lower rates to offset the effects of the recession. The desire to
retain an adequate “policy buffer” – by which I mean the amount of room we have to lower rates
to offset recessions – lies at the heart of my evolving thoughts on the appropriate monetary
policy framework.2
If, as a result, we seek to avoid a prolonged low interest rate environment in the future,
then my view is that policymakers should start studying and discussing alternative frameworks to
make this outcome less likely. While there is little that monetary policy can do to impact
productivity or labor force growth, policymakers can influence the prevailing level of interest
rates by adjusting our medium-term inflation goal.3 One option would be targeting a higher
inflation rate,4 so that nominal interest rates would be higher than otherwise – and there have
been other more technical proposals (for example price-level targeting and nominal GDP
targeting) designed to provide a greater buffer.5
I would also suggest that the optimal inflation rate is not likely to remain constant over
time. An alternative, which would recognize that the inflation target should not necessarily be
constant, is an inflation range with an adjustable inflation target. Within this framework, one
could think of our inflation goal as defined by two components: A range of inflation rates that
policymakers would find acceptable across many economic circumstances, and a medium-term
goal within that range that policymakers would set, perhaps year by year, depending on specific
economic circumstances.
In my view, adopting an inflation range that allows for movement in the effective
medium-run inflation goal might be a helpful addition to the Fed’s monetary policy framework.6
An inflation range that allows some movement in the inflation target, depending on economic
5

EMBARGOED UNTIL 4:15 P.M. Eastern Time, and 1:15 P.M. Pacific Time on Friday, January 12, 2018 OR UPON DELIVERY

fundamentals, would be treating the Fed’s inflation goal more like the natural rate of
unemployment, where we recognize that the natural rate will shift over time with demographic
and other workforce characteristics.
Of course, the advantages of greater inflation target flexibility would likely be partly
offset by some costs. For instance, it is likely that such flexibility would generate more
uncertainty about inflation in the medium to long run, since we cannot know for sure how long
productivity and demographic trends would persist.7 However, if we set the range to – for
example – 1.5 to 3.0 percent, and were successful in keeping inflation mostly in that range, this
would represent a set of inflation outcomes that are similar to those the U.S. has experienced
over the past 20 years.

Perspectives on Recent Forecast Misses
As previously mentioned, once a quarter, FOMC participants provide their economic
forecasts for key economic variables. Among the charts that are included are the so called “fan
charts,” shown in Figure 1 for PCE inflation. The fan chart shows that even at a 70 percent
confidence level, the forecast errors for PCE inflation are quite large. Thus, with the current 2
percent forecast, it would not be at all surprising to have actual inflation turn out to somewhere
between 1 to 3 percent.
The sources of these forecast misses are many: large, unexpected changes in energy,
food, import or other volatile prices can temporarily disrupt overall inflation measures relative
to the forecast; the economy can grow faster or slower than we expect; or our assessment of what
is relatively fast or slow can be off. A good example of an unexpected price change is the
6

EMBARGOED UNTIL 4:15 P.M. Eastern Time, and 1:15 P.M. Pacific Time on Friday, January 12, 2018 OR UPON DELIVERY

modification in wireless service pricing by many U.S. mobile carriers that occurred last spring.
This change is one of the factors that lowered the PCE inflation rate relative to the forecast in
December 2016.
Figure 2 provides some history on SEP8 and private-sector forecast errors, comparing the
median core PCE inflation rate forecast for one-year-ahead to the actual rate, based on both the
SEP and the Survey of Professional Forecasters’ fourth quarter forecasts for each year.9 While
the forecast error (based on the 2016 fourth-quarter forecast for the core inflation rate10 for the
fourth quarter of 2017) was clearly a miss, it certainly was not outsized relative to other oneyear-ahead forecast errors made over the past 10 years. In addition, forecasters made both
positive and negative forecast errors during this period, not persistently missing in one direction.
This forecast record seems inconsistent with concerns of some observers who argue forecasters
are missing some fundamental attribute of inflation dynamics.
Figure 3 provides forecast errors for the unemployment rate forecast, by comparing both
the SEP and the Survey of Professional Forecasters’ median unemployment rate forecast for the
fourth quarter of the next year with the actual rate, for each fourth-quarter forecast. While the
2016 fourth-quarter forecast error for the unemployment rate in the fourth quarter of 2017 is not
particularly large relative to previous years, there do seem to be persistent, consistent forecast
errors in the same direction for the unemployment rate, unlike for the inflation rate. That is,
since 2010, forecasters have regularly anticipated the unemployment rate would fall less than
actually occurred.
From a short-run policy perspective, the inflation forecast errors do not seem to be
particularly noteworthy, and would not seem to indicate serious forecast biases over the past
decade. In contrast, the persistent forecasts that unemployment will not fall as much as has
7

EMBARGOED UNTIL 4:15 P.M. Eastern Time, and 1:15 P.M. Pacific Time on Friday, January 12, 2018 OR UPON DELIVERY

occurred should provide policymakers pause, since at 4.1 percent the unemployment rate is
already well below most estimates of the sustainable long-run unemployment rate. The most
recent median estimate for the natural rate from the Survey of Professional Forecasters is 4.5
percent; the corresponding median longer-run unemployment rate estimate from the December
SEP is 4.6 percent.

Models and the Monetary Policy Framework
Since January 2012, the FOMC has published a statement of longer-run goals and
monetary policy strategy11 that it reaffirms, sometimes with small modifications, at each January
FOMC meeting. The statement provides the FOMC’s tactical approach for meeting the Federal
Reserve’s dual mandate provided by Congress: fostering economic conditions to achieve both
stable prices and maximum sustainable employment.
The statement explicitly defines the inflation goal as being a 2 percent inflation target.12
The employment mandate does not have a numerical target because the natural rate of
unemployment is primarily determined by non-monetary factors, must be inferred from other
economic data, and has moved significantly over time.13 The statement also clarifies that when
there are misses in both elements of the dual mandate, the Committee should follow a balanced
approach, by which we mean that we will give equal policy attention to deviations of
employment from an estimate of full employment, and to deviations of inflation from its 2
percent target.
At the time of adoption of the statement on longer-run goals, the 2 percent inflation target
was quite similar to the target set by most other central banks in developed economies.14 Many
8

EMBARGOED UNTIL 4:15 P.M. Eastern Time, and 1:15 P.M. Pacific Time on Friday, January 12, 2018 OR UPON DELIVERY

academic studies advocated for a 2 percent inflation target as being consistent with price
stability, although many of them were conducted prior to the Great Recession. Most of this
research that attempted to determine how large a policy buffer would be sufficient – and thus
how high a target inflation rate would be best – generally estimated that interest rates were
unlikely to reach the effective lower bound, but if they did, the expected duration at near-zero
interest rates would be measured in quarters, not years.
Unfortunately, the economic history of the past 10 years has shown that many developed
countries in the wake of the Great Recession and financial crisis were forced to hold interest
rates near zero for many years, much longer than the earlier model estimates suggested.15 Such
low interest rate environments make it difficult to conduct counter-cyclical monetary policy, and
can potentially undermine financial stability, as households and firms “reach for yield” in the
face of low interest rates, almost always taking on additional risk as a consequence.
It is not surprising, in my view, that many estimates assumed that a period of prolonged
low interest rates was unlikely. In an economy with rapid increases in productivity and an
expanding labor force, periods of prolonged low interest rates are likely to be avoided in most
recessions. However, the size of the negative shock from the Great Recession, along with
fundamental changes in the economy,16 have made it much more likely that future recessions
could also result in prolonged low interest rates and a need to conduct monetary policy with
nontraditional methods, such as asset purchases on central banks’ balance sheets – rather than
just through movement of short-term interest rates.
Figure 4 shows FOMC participants’ assessments of the longer-run rate that the federal
funds rate will settle to when the Fed has achieved both elements of the dual mandate.

9

EMBARGOED UNTIL 4:15 P.M. Eastern Time, and 1:15 P.M. Pacific Time on Friday, January 12, 2018 OR UPON DELIVERY

Recognizing the effects of slower productivity growth and labor force growth on this so-called
“neutral” rate of interest, SEP submissions have gradually lowered this measure since 2012.
In early 2012, both the median forecast and the central tendency of FOMC participants
was that the federal funds target rate in the longer-run would be at least 4 percent. As of
December 2017, both the median forecast and most of the central tendency expect that the
federal funds target rate will be below 3 percent.17 Since most recessions involve lowering the
federal funds target rate by more than 300 basis points, this makes it seem quite likely that a low
interest rate environment will become a more common occurrence.
Figure 5 illustrates one possible reason for the decline in the expectations of the longerrun or neutral federal funds rate. Productivity growth is much lower now than it has been for
much of the previous 50 years. This lower productivity growth, as long as it persists, implies
that real interest rates are likely to be lower on average.
Figure 6 provides another reason to expect lower real interest rates, which is the
reduction in the growth in the civilian labor force. With slower population growth, fewer
immigrants, and an aging population, the growth in the labor force is expected to be much lower
for quite some time than it has been in previous decades. Again, this implies lower real interest
rates.
One way to avoid periods of prolonged low interest rates would be to alter the inflation
target in response to changes in our estimates of real interest rates – estimates that have been
changing of late. This would make inflation, like the natural unemployment rate, a target that
could vary over time. If, for example, the monetary policy framework set an inflation range of,
say 1.5 to 3.0 percent, the FOMC could vary its medium-term inflation target to be high, low, or

10

EMBARGOED UNTIL 4:15 P.M. Eastern Time, and 1:15 P.M. Pacific Time on Friday, January 12, 2018 OR UPON DELIVERY

in the middle of the range depending on economic factors that the Committee could determine at
the beginning of each year. For example, in the current environment, with low population
growth and low productivity growth, policy could move even more gradually to remove
accommodation, and allow inflation to be somewhat higher in its range. Should the labor force
or productivity grow more quickly, the Committee could seek to gradually reduce the inflation
target within its range.
Using an inflation range would trade off the costs of more effective policy responses to
recessions (and the potential financial stability risk that may attend prolonged low interest rate
periods), with the costs of having somewhat less certainty about what the inflation rate would be
in the long run. But as long as the inflation rate were in a relatively narrow band, such as 1.5 to
3.0 percent, the range would not be a dramatic change from actual experience and would
therefore be less likely to impact inflation expectations. If changes in productivity and labor
force growth occurred very infrequently, the inflation target would be stable – but at a level more
consistent with avoiding prolonged low interest rates.

Concluding Observations
Recent forecast errors of inflation and unemployment have not been particularly large,
and do not pose much challenge to continuing on the current path of gradual increases in the
federal funds rate. Perhaps the bigger risk for short-run policy is the fact that the unemployment
rate continues to fall further below sustainable levels, and will likely continue to do so going
forward, risking the sustainability of the recovery.

11

EMBARGOED UNTIL 4:15 P.M. Eastern Time, and 1:15 P.M. Pacific Time on Friday, January 12, 2018 OR UPON DELIVERY

A more significant longer-run matter, from my perspective, is the opportunity for the
Federal Reserve’s current monetary policy framework to adapt to the recent experience with
prolonged low real interest rates. If the U.S. economy is to avoid a scenario in which the
effective lower bound is reached and the central bank must use its balance sheet for asset
purchases rather than move short-term interest rates for counter-cyclical monetary policy, then
policymakers should consider alternative monetary policy frameworks that would make such
outcomes less likely.
An inflation range with an adjustable medium-run inflation goal is one way to address
such concerns, but there are a variety of alternative frameworks also worth considering.18 In my
view, we are approaching a time when a comprehensive reconsideration of the monetary policy
framework is likely warranted, given the experience of the past 10 years. Any change we make
should be designed to provide policymakers with the flexibility to set monetary policy
appropriately as key features of the economy change, as they have repeatedly over U.S.
economic history.
Thank you.

1

See https://www.interdependence.org/wp-content/uploads/2013/10/HeldringObituary.pdfhttps://www.interdependence.org/wp-content/uploads/2013/10/Heldring-Obituary.pdf.
2

For additional discussion, see Jan. 8, 2018 remarks at the Brookings Institution by Eric S. Rosengren, Reviewing
Monetary Policy Frameworks: https://www.bostonfed.org/news-and-events/speeches/2018/reviewing-monetarypolicy-frameworks.aspx
3

On average, overall or nominal interest rates equal the prevailing real rate of interest plus the average inflation rate
– which should be near our inflation goal – we can move the overall average level of nominal rates one-for-one by
changing our inflation goal.

12

EMBARGOED UNTIL 4:15 P.M. Eastern Time, and 1:15 P.M. Pacific Time on Friday, January 12, 2018 OR UPON DELIVERY

4

When the real interest rate is low.

For more discussion behind the Fed’s current monetary policy framework and alternative monetary policy
frameworks see, https://www.brookings.edu/blog/up-front/2018/01/04/the-hutchins-center-explains-the-frameworkfor-monetary-policy/.
5

6

Additional dimensions of such a framework would be how symmetric the range would be: Is flexibility to be used
only when real rates are low, requiring a higher inflation goal? Or would we expect to adjust the medium-term
inflation goal down when real rates are unusually high? And what status does the center of the range hold? Do we
intend for inflation to average somewhere near the center of the range over a longer span of time?, Do we always
plan for inflation to return to the center of the range at some horizon?
7

In addition, FOMC participants would no doubt consider adjusting our medium-term inflation goal up or down
only when we (and others) had estimated that a persistent change in real rate determinants had occurred and was
likely to continue. Such an assessment is of course difficult and entails uncertainty
8

Prior to the June 2015 medians, SEP medians are only available with a five-year lag. Proxies for the medians for
the December 2013 and 2014 one-year-ahead forecasts for the fourth quarters of 2014 and 2015, for core PCE
inflation and the unemployment rate used in the forecast error calculations for Figures 2 and 3 are calculated from
the distribution of FOMC participants’ projections reported in ranges of tenths in the FOMC meeting minutes.
9

Of course, the actual values are revised over time. We have used the most up-to-date figures in the calculations.

10

While total PCE is the target for this exercise, we used core PCE to avoid outsized errors that would be related to
the often volatile food and energy prices.
11

In order to provide more clarity about how the Federal Reserve implemented the dual mandate, the FOMC issued
the Statement on Longer-Run Goals and Monetary Policy Strategy, which is important for clarifying to the public
what monetary policy is about, and also for providing FOMC members with a common framework when conducting
policy. FOMC members will have different opinions about economic conditions and where the economy is headed.
Still, according to the strategy document, the way these differences are translated into different policy
recommendations should be consistent across FOMC members, in that members agree to share the same inflation
goal and assign the same penalty to deviations of inflation and unemployment from their longer-run values. The
statement became effective Jan. 24, 2012, and was subsequently amended, effective Jan.31, 2017. See
https://www.federalreserve.gov/faqs/statement-on-longer-run-goals-monetary-policy-strategy-fomc.htm.
12

This is measured by the annual change in the price index for personal consumption expenditures.

13

For example, the natural rate has varied as the demographic composition of the labor market has changed.

14

Two percent was seen as a practical compromise between some academic work that suggested that zero (or even
negative) inflation was optimal, and work on the other hand that saw value both in “greasing the wheels” of wage
setting given reluctance of workers to take nominal wage cuts, and in providing the policy buffer that I have just
discussed that comes with a positive inflation rate.
15

Once the central bank gets stuck at near-zero rates, additional counter-cyclical monetary policy can only be
provided through alternative monetary policy measures such as quantitative easing, which aims to directly influence
longer-term interest rates and other asset prices.
16

For example, declining productivity growth and slowing labor force growth.

17

As of December 2017, the SEP median longer-run federal funds rate was 2.75 percent and the central tendency
was 2.75 to 3.00 percent. Looking at the individual observations from the SEP “dot plot” shows that the majority of
the central tendency expects a rate of 2.75 percent.

13

EMBARGOED UNTIL 4:15 P.M. Eastern Time, and 1:15 P.M. Pacific Time on Friday, January 12, 2018 OR UPON DELIVERY

18

Some have suggested simply raising the inflation goal, which would of course provide more of the policy cushion
I have discussed today. Others have proposed using price-level targeting or some variant of it, which is a way of
promising future inflation when the economy is weak, thus (in theory) adding stimulus by lowering real interest
rates. This policy also has the advantage of making the price level – the cost of living – more predictable. And some
have suggested following a nominal GDP target. The virtue of this framework is that it is flexible with respect to the
mix of overall nominal growth that comes from real growth versus inflation. When real growth is slow, inflation is
allowed to rise higher, similar to the flexible target range approach I have outlined.

14