View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FOR RELEASE AT 1:15 P.M., E.S.T.
Thursday, April 11, 1985




Observations on the Dollar's Strength

Remarks by

Brinett J. Rice

Member

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

before

Conference of

Hie Swed ish-Amer ican Chamber of Commerce

Washington, D. C.

April 11, 1985

I am pleased to be with you today to discuss the effects of the
strong U.S. dollar on the world economy.

Few developments have so confounded

economic forecasters as the dollar's persistent appreciation since late 1980.
The associated flows of capital and the resultant redirection of trade
have become a principal topic of discussion and policy debate.

For private

planners and makers of public policy alike, the outlook for the dollar is a
major uncertainty.

And in a broader sense, by giving rise to more forceful

calls in the United States for protectionism, the dollar's strength has
clouded the prospects for continued expansion of world trade, growth of the
world economy, and resolution of the international debt problem.
Whether measured in nominal or in real terms, the dollar's
appreciation over the last four years has been stunning.

The dollar's rise

since the fourth quarter of 1980 canes to about 75 percent on the tradeweighted index of the dollar's value against the other G-10 currencies that
is used at the Federal Reserve Board.

This figure somewhat overstates the

gain in the dollar's relative purchasing power because inflation has
proceeded more rapidly on average abroad than in the United States.
terms —
abroad —

In real

adjusted, that is, for changes in consumer price levels here and
the trade-weighted value of the dollar has increased nearly 70

percent, still a very large figure.
While the extent of the dollar's climb has been remarkable, to be
sure, perhaps the most striking feature of the dollar's rise is the fact that
it has continued even as the U.S. deficits on trade and current account have
expanded to unprecedented magnitudes.

The persistence of this combination of

developments points to a complex of causes for the dollar's appreciation.




-

2 -

The dollar has derived its strength in part from the historically
high level of dollar interest rates relative to the recent rate of inflation
in the United States.

There can be little doubt that high real interest

rates are at least partly attributable to enormous current and prospective
deficits in the U.S. government's budget.

The enhancement of tax incentives

for investment by U.S. firms in the early 1980s likely contributed, as well,
to increased demands for credit and upward pressure on U.S. interest rates.
Technological change also may have helped boost investment demand.
According to econometric work at the Board, however, differentials
between real interest rates on dollar assets and those on assets denominated
in other currencies explain only a little more than half of the rise in the
dollar's real exchange rate over the last four years.

While any such

estimate must be regarded as imprecise, it seems fair to conclude that a
substantial portion of the dollar's rise is attributable to influences other
than real interest-rate differentials.

Investors apparently have come to

desire that a larger proportion of their wealth be in dollar-denominated
claims for any given differential in real interest rates.
Several factors may account for this apparent shift in investor
attitudes.

The vigor and dynamism of the U.S. economy have contrasted

favorably with economic performance elsewhere, especially in Europe.

A

demonstrated U.S. comnitment to improve price stability has eased concern
that a resumption of rapid inflation might erode real returns on dollar
assets.

The political and social, as well as economic, stability of the

United States has made this country a relatively secure place in which savers
may want to keep their wealth.

Meanwhile, instability elsewhere,

particularly in debt-burdened developing countries, has discouraged further




-

3

-

foreign lending to those nations and has prompted capital flight from which
the United States has probably benefitted disproportionately.
As I turn now to the effects of the strong dollar, I think it is
important to emphasize at the outset that I am really speaking of the
consequences that flow from the policies and other developments both in the
United States and abroad that have raised the dollar's value.

The exchange

rate, per se, is merely a transmission mechanism through which the U.S.
economy influences the rest of the world and vice versa.

Insufficient

attention to this fact, I believe, has at times produced some confusion in
domestic and international debate on economic policy.
In the United States, the dollar's appreciation has helped bring
down inflation and keep it low during one of the strongest economic
recoveries of the postwar period.

The dollar's rise has held down both the

cost of imported inputs and prices in industries whose products compete with
imports.

This effect has kept the overall pace of inflation below the rate

of price increase in sectors producing nontraded goods and services.
According to Board staff estimates, the increase in the exchange rate over
the last four years, if not reversed, will ultimately reduce the level of
prices by roughly 5 to 7 percent.

This effect on the price level, Which has

been spread out over several years, has depressed the measured annual
inflation rate by about 1-1/2 percent.

If the dollar were to stay at its

present value, the effects of its appreciation to date would be preserved in
the U.S. price level, but the depressive effect on the inflation rate would
not continue.
By holding down the observed rate of price increase, the dollar's
advance has helped greatly to alter the inflationary psychology prevalent in




-

the United States in the 1970s.

4

-

The dollar's appreciation has reduced the

cost in lost U.S. output and employment that might otherwise have been
necessary to accomplish the dampening of inflation expectations that has
occurred.

In the process, it has given the Federal Reserve somewhat greater

flexibility in the implementation of monetary policy, but only for a time.
When the dollar's climb ends —

and it may have already —

its moderating

influence on the U.S. inflation rate also will cease, with some lag.
Vigilance against a pickup in inflation and a possible resurgence of
inflation expectations then will be especially important, and it will be all
the more crucial should the dollar depreciate, as seems likely eventually.
Abroad, the price effects of the dollar's strength generally have
been adverse, though perhaps not from the point of view of producers for
export.

Foreign-currency prices of many traded goods have tended to rise

relative to prices of other goods and have exerted upward pressure on general
price levels.

In order to limit increases in measured inflation rates and

the potential increase in inflation expectations that might ensue, many
governments, it appears, have pursued more restrictive policies than they
might have otherwise.

The associated slack in domestic demand has held down

prices in nontraded goods sectors and to some extent also in world markets
for basic commodities, thereby limiting increases in average price levels,
but at the cost of lost production for domestic use, static employment, and
high unemployment. This, along with other considerations, suggests that the
benefits that the rest of the world derives from the United States'
stimulative policies can be overstated.
It is true that the rapid growth of the U.S. economy and the
appreciation of the dollar, by enlarging U.S. trade and current account




-

5

-

deficits, have provided a major force for expansion in the rest of the
world.

Growth of demand in the United States represented 70 percent of the

total growth of demand in the OECD area from 1982 to 1984, even though we
accounted for only 40 percent of OECD GNP in 1982.

This is to say, the

United States accounted disproportionately for the increase in OECD demand in
this recovery.
U.S. demand for the exports of developing countries, in particular,
has been of critical importance to their difficult process of adjustment.
U.S. inports from non-OPEC developing countries expanded nearly 40 percent
from 1982 to 1984, accounting for about half of the total increase in these
countries' exports.

The U.S. contribution to adjustment has helped to

stabilize the world financial system generally.
The United States also has provided powerful stimulus to industrial
countries.

U.S. imports from Western Europe, for example, rose 35 percent

from 1982 to 1984.
percent.

U.S. imports from Sweden, in particular, rose nearly 65

In the case of our industrial trading partners, however, stimulus

from the United States, while welcome, also has had some negative sideeffects.

As I noted earlier, the united States' expansionary fiscal policy

may have induced other countries to exercise greater restraint than was
otherwise desirable.

Moreover, forms of stimulus other than demand frcm the

United States might have been more beneficial to economies abroad —

for

example, enhancement of incentives for investment in these economies.

In addition, the shift in investor attitudes that apparently has
helped boost the dollar has simultaneously exerted upward pressure on
interest rates abroad, tending to discourage interest-sensitive expenditure.
This reduction in domestic demand has subsequently been offset to some




-

6

-

extent, of course, by export demand from the United States.

By boosting

the dollar and exports, the shift in asset demands has brought a partial cure
for its ill effects on economies abroad.

But the cure is only partial.

While total demand for the production of foreign economies tends to be
sustained by exports, investment and other interest-sensitive expenditures
tend to remain depressed.

It is not surprising, therefore, that foreign

governments are dissatisfied with the dollar's strength despite resultant
improvements in their trade and current account balances.

At the same time,

it seems, the proper response to the shift in investor attitudes is not for
the United States to make dollar assets less attractive, but rather for other
countries to make their economies more attractive by ameliorating structural
rigidities, by enhancing incentives, and maybe in certain cases by stimu­
lating their economies more directly.

In this regard, Sweden's 1982 actions

to trim marginal income tax rates and its recent decision to liberalize entry
for foreign banks appear to be helpful steps.
The counterpart to the U.S. current account deficit, the growing
net inflow of capital to the United States, has been a critically important
factor in enabling the United States to finance both rising investment and
its enormous federal deficit.

Foreign capital has supplemented the domestic

savings of individuals, businesses, and state and local governments by nearly
one third and has helped keep U.S. interest rates lower than they otherwise
would have been.

Hie federal budget deficit consequently has crowded out

less domestic private investment than it might have.

Instead, crowding-out

effects have fallen partially on investment in the rest of the world as the
United States has taken a greater share of available capital.




- 7 Uiis result has not been unambiguously beneficial to the United
States.

We have become increasingly dependent on funding from abroad, and

were dollar assets suddenly to fall into disfavor, we would suffer a painful
adjustment.

In addition, the dollar's strength has imposed severe strains on

the export and import-competing sectors of our economy at the same time that
it has benefitted those sectors of foreign economies.

While in macroeconomic

terms the resultant loss of jobs in our traded-goods industries largely has
been offset by the creation of new jobs in other sectors, complaints at the
microeconomic level of specific industries and communities are understand­
able.

Moreover, sectoral shifts both here and abroad are to be regretted to

the extent that they represent a distortion induced by U.S. fiscal imbalance.
Indeed, it is difficult to believe that the world's productive resources are
being allocated efficiently when U.S. federal borrowing absorbs a flow of
credit greater than the large net capital inflow to the United States, and
vrfien a consensus is lacking in the United States for the possible future
sacrifice of consumption and investment that may be necessary to service a
prospectively large external debt incurred at high real interest rates.
By holding down U.S. interest rates, capital inflows to the United
States probably have obscured the urgency of dealing with our federal budget
deficit.

I am hopeful that an earnest reassessment of U.S. fiscal policy is

now in train and that a substantial reduction in the budget deficit is being
sought.

Economic analysis and common sense tell us that budgetary and trade

deficits of the magnitude we are running are not sustainable indefinitely.
If left unchecked, these deficits sooner or later will impair confidence in
our economy and undermine our growth and prosperity.




-

8

-

Correction of our fiscal imbalance is the appropriate way to
alleviate strains on our export sector and on our import-competing
industries.

By lowering U.S. interest rates over time, reduction of the

federal deficit also would tend to bring the dollar's value down and thereby
make U.S. goods more competitive in world markets.

Correspondingly, foreign

producers of traded goods would experience pressure on their market shares
and profits.
abroad.

But a reduction in U.S. credit demands would promote investment

All in all, global welfare probably would increase through an

improvement in the allocation of resources.
Protectionist measures are not the proper solution to the strains
imposed by the dollar's high value.

Indeed, measures that are now being

proposed in the United States are likely to do serious harm.

For instance,

if such measures reduced U.S. imports from developing countries, they would
severely impair those countries' ability to service their debt.

Even if we

could somehow shield developing countries by exempting them from import
restraints, there are other severe economic costs to protectionism.

Quotas,

tariffs, or import surcharges all would act directly to raise U.S. prices.
This problem might be compounded by a renewal of inflation expectations,
undoing some of the progress that has been made on this front.

Ironically,

if the fundamental sources of the dollar's strength were not addressed, then
protectionist measures that effectively reduced some imports probably would
put additional upward pressures on the dollar, which in turn would further
hurt U.S. exporters and unprotected industries.

Moreover, protectionist

action by the United States would invite retaliation by foreign countries and
a breakdown of the world trading order built up through great effort since
the 1930s.




In this event, the world generally would suffer.

looking ahead, a further upward move in the dollar's value would
give additional impetus to expansion of the U.S. trade and current account
deficits and corresponding surpluses abroad.

Even if the dollar were to

stabilize around recent levels, the lagged effects of its appreciation to
date vould include some further widening of our external deficits.

In all

likelihood, the cumulation of claims on the United States should eventually
reduce demand for additional dollar assets, causing the dollar gradually to
decline in value.

Depreciation of the dollar, in turn, would tend over time

to shrink the U.S. deficits on trade and current account.

Action to reduce

the federal budget deficit would promote external, as well as internal,
balance.
A sharp depreciation of the dollar would be very disruptive both in
the United States and abroad, but especially to this economy.

As the

dollar's fall curtailed U.S. imports, foreign exporters to the United States
would find their production capacity underutilized.

This possibility has

engendered legitimate concern abroad that the dollar's current strength may
be encouraging overexpansion of export industries.

While a substantial drop

in the dollar's value would reduce foreign surpluses in trade with the United
States, net capital outflows from foreign economies also would diminish, by
definition.

This would alleviate financial strains in those countries,

provided monetary policies were accommodative.

For the United States, on the

other hand, a sharp reversal in the dollar's value would tend to exert strong
upward pressure on prices as well as interest rates.

The pressures of

federal credit demands, notably, instead of being vented abroad, would fall
more heavily on the domestic private sector.




-

10

-

Let us hope that the potential for such an unpleasant scenario is
not realized.

Let us hope that a crisis is not needed to motivate a

correction of the U.S. fiscal imbalance.

By addressing this problem now, the

United States can help to restore world trade and capital flows to a more
reasonable pattern.

Foreign governments also can help by fostering growth

and efficiency in their own economies.