View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
6:00 p.m. EDT
June 15, 2009

Containing the Crisis and Promoting Economic Recovery

Remarks by
Elizabeth A. Duke
Member
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
Women in Housing and Finance Annual Meeting
Washington, D.C.

June 15, 2009

When I joined the Board of Governors last August, the other Board members
were already formulating monetary policy to limit the economy-wide consequences of a
very substantial housing downturn and actively responding to a severe financial crisis.
In September, the crisis intensified when the collapse and subsequent bankruptcy
of Lehman Brothers triggered a sequence of events that brought credit markets--and in
particular, the commercial paper (CP) market and interbank funding market--to a near
standstill.1 The enormity of these events--and their potential implications for the
economy--should not be underestimated. Credit plays a critical role in the undertaking of
almost all production activities in the economy and a large portion of expenditure
activities as well. The breakdown of credit markets that followed the collapse of
Lehman, if left unchecked, could have meant a very significant contraction in economic
activity. Indeed, you may have heard the anecdote soon after the Lehman collapse about
Chairman Bernanke being asked, “Well, what if we don't do anything?” To which he
replied, “There will be no economy on Monday.”
Policymakers in the United States and the world certainly did not follow the
course of “not doing anything,” either with regard to the events of last September or more
generally through the financial crisis. Policymakers in the Congress, the Department of
the Treasury, the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC), and the Federal
Reserve--and their counterparts abroad--were well aware of the dire implications that a
lack of access to credit would have had on economic outcomes. And they were

1

Losses on Lehman Brothers’ debt securities that resulted from the investment bank’s bankruptcy caused
one money market mutual fund to “break the buck,” with others also rumored to do so. This situation led
to a rapid escalation in money market mutual fund outflows such that short-term funding markets for
businesses and municipalities essentially froze. Interbank funding markets also stopped functioning, and
overnight rates soared to extraordinarily high levels.

-2extremely active in formulating policies aimed at alleviating pressures in credit markets
so as to ensure that the economy continued to function.
What I would like to do today--now nine months after the collapse of Lehman
Brothers and the tumultuous events that followed--is to look back on the policies that
have been implemented throughout the financial crisis and consider how well they have
worked to lessen the broader impact of financial market disruptions. Of course, it is too
early to gauge the influence of policy on the economy’s evolution through the financial
crisis. It is difficult to do this with precision in general, and it is especially difficult to
undertake analysis so soon after the events have occurred with so little data since the
policy implementation. However, what we can do is look at how conditions in specific
financial markets, and credit volumes more generally, have evolved, and ask whether this
information is at least suggestive that the policies that we have implemented have worked
to avert a far more severe and detrimental outcome.
I will talk first about programs aimed at conditions in specific markets and the
responses of those markets. I will then move to a discussion of credit aggregates more
generally. I will use the Federal Reserve Flow of Funds data for four major credit types-residential mortgages, consumer credit, commercial real estate lending, and commercial
and industrial loans--to compare credit aggregates in the current cycle to previous
recessions generally considered to be credit-crunch periods. In particular, I will compare
credit in the current crisis to the 1990-1991 episode that, as you might remember, also
included a financial crisis. To preview my conclusions, I confess that I was actually
rather startled by the pattern of the data. I originally started to look at these data to
determine how much worse the credit contraction in this episode was compared with

-3previous episodes. Instead, the data suggest that the actual credit contraction in this
episode has been quite subdued compared with what might have been expected. So I do
think that policies have helped maintain the flow of credit to businesses and households.
How Well Have Policies to Contain the Crisis Worked? A Market-by-Market
Perspective
The policy responses to the financial crisis have been substantial and have
occurred on all fronts. Fiscal policy and monetary policy, as well as policies relating to
government guarantees and safety nets, such as deposit insurance, have been used to
improve conditions in the financial sector. In discussing these policies and how they
appear to have worked (or will likely work in the case of more-recent policies), I will
start with policies and programs implemented by the Federal Reserve before moving to
policies implemented by the government generally.
Apart from traditional monetary policy, the goal of which is to strengthen
aggregate demand, the ultimate goal of the other policies is to maintain credit availability
to households and businesses. In the more immediate term, these policies are focused on
relieving stresses in particular markets or strengthening the financial condition of
specific, or classes of, institutions.
Traditional Interest Rate Methods of Monetary Policy
The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) has responded to the financial
crisis by aggressively easing short-term interest rates, beginning in September 2007. At
its December 2008 meeting, the Committee reduced its target for the federal funds rate
close to its lower bound, setting a range between 0 and 1/4 percent. With inflation
expected to remain subdued for some time, the FOMC has indicated that short-term

-4interest rates are likely to remain low for an extended period. By communicating this
expectation, the FOMC reinforced market beliefs that its policy is likely to remain on
hold, thereby putting downward pressure on longer-term rates, which have the greatest
effects on spending behavior. This sort of communication can be very useful in
stimulating borrowing and spending by businesses and households and promoting growth
in economic activity.
Balance Sheet and Credit-Easing Policies
In addition to easing the traditional interest rate instrument of monetary policy,
the Federal Reserve has been supporting credit markets through an expansion of the asset
side of its balance sheet. This approach--described as credit easing--is conceptually
distinct from quantitative easing, the policy approach used by the Bank of Japan from
2001 through 2006. Credit easing and quantitative easing both share the feature that they
involve the expansion of the central bank's balance sheet. That said, the ways in which
the policy approaches expand the balance sheet--and act to stimulate lending--are
different.
Quantitative easing can be thought of as an expansion of the central bank’s
balance sheet with no intentional change in its composition. That is, the central bank
undertakes more open market operations with the objective of expanding bank reserve
balances, which the banking system should then use to make new loans and buy
additional securities. However, when credit spreads are very wide, as they are at present,
and the credit markets are quite dysfunctional, it becomes less likely that new loans and
additional securities purchases will result from increasing bank reserve balances.

-5In contrast, credit easing focuses on the mix of loans and securities that the central
bank holds as assets on its balance sheet as a means to reduce credit spreads and improve
the functioning of private credit markets. The ultimate objective is improvement in the
credit conditions faced by households and businesses. In this respect, the Federal
Reserve has focused on improving functioning in the credit markets that are severely
disrupted and that are key sources of funding for financial firms, nonfinancial firms, and
households.
Figure 1 graphs the asset side of the Federal Reserve balance sheet, which has
expanded substantially since the end of the third quarter of 2008. Federal Reserve
initiatives with regard to the expansion of the asset side of its balance sheet can be
grouped by the markets those initiatives are intended to help: (1) targeted actions to
prevent the failure or substantial weakening of specific systemically important
institutions, which are shown by the red area; (2) liquidity programs for financial
institutions, which are shown by the light blue area; (3) lending to support the functioning
of key financial markets, which are shown by the green area; and (4) large-scale
purchases of high-quality assets, which are shown by the pink area.
1. Targeted actions aimed at specific systemically important institutions.
Targeted actions to prevent the failure or substantial weakening of specific systemically
important institutions include the first Maiden Lane transaction in March 2008, which
extended support to facilitate the merger of Bear Stearns and JPMorgan Chase. It also
includes loans and facilities supporting American International Group (AIG). These
actions were driven by concerns that the disorderly failure of a large, complex,
interconnected firm would impose significant losses on creditors, including other

-6financial firms, dislocate a wide range of financial markets, and impede the flow of credit
to households and businesses.2 To be sure, in no sense were these actions taken to protect
the affected firms’ managers or shareholders from the costs of past mistakes. Although I
was not present for the Bear Stearns transaction, I can tell you that the decisions
regarding loans to AIG were extremely difficult and uncomfortable. But at the time, the
Federal Reserve was the only government entity with authority to act, and the tremendous
risks to the financial system and the real economy implied by the failure of a large,
complex, interconnected firm made the option of not acting unthinkable.
2. Liquidity programs for financial institutions. Since the onset of the crisis, the
Federal Reserve has also modified existing facilities and implemented a number of new
ones to provide liquidity to sound financial institutions in an environment in which
interbank funding markets and repurchase agreement, or repo, markets (for securities
other than Treasury securities) are severely disrupted.
For example, the Federal Reserve has improved banks’ access to short-term credit
by temporarily relaxing the terms on the discount window and by expanding--through the
introduction of the Term Auction Facility and the establishment of reciprocal currency
arrangements (liquidity swap lines) with foreign central banks--the range of programs
through which it can lend to depository institutions.3 Ultimately, the objective of

2

Losses sustained by other financial firms could then erode their financial strength, limiting their ability to
play their intermediation role or even cause them to fail, thereby reinforcing financial pressures. In
addition, the disorderly failure of a large, complex, interconnected firm could undermine confidence in the
U.S. financial sector more broadly, potentially triggering a widespread withdrawal of funding by investors
and an additional tightening of credit conditions, which would, in turn, cause a further reduction in
economic activity.
3
Specifically, the Federal Reserve has relaxed the terms on the discount window by lowering the spread
between the discount rate and the target federal funds rate from 100 to 25 basis points and extending the
maturity on discount window loans, which now have a maximum duration of 90 days.
The Term Auction Facility provides credit to depository institutions through an auction mechanism,
and liquidity swap lines provide U.S. dollar funding indirectly to foreign banks whose liquidity demands

-7liquidity programs is to facilitate the intermediation of credit to households and
businesses. The immediate goal of such facilities, however, is the reduction of stresses in
the interbank funding market. The significant narrowing since the start of this year in
important measures of stress in this market--specifically, Libor-OIS spreads, shown in the
left panel of figure 2--together with diminished usage of these facilities--shown to the
right--suggest that some easing in this market has occurred in line with the
implementation and expansion of these initiatives.
In a similar manner, the Term Securities Lending Facility (TSLF) and Primary
Dealer Credit Facility (PDCF) provide liquidity to primary dealers to allow them to
perform their function of making markets to support their customers’ needs to buy, sell,
and issue securities.4 The immediate goal of these facilities was the reduction of stresses
in repo markets for securities other than Treasury securities. The narrowing of spreads
between repo rates on agency and mortgage-backed securities (MBS) and Treasury
general collateral repo rates--shown in the left panel of figure 3--together with diminished
usage of the TSLF and PDCF--shown to the right--suggest that stresses in this market
have eased since November.
3. Lending to support key financial markets. Credit-easing policies have also
been targeted at improving conditions in key financial markets--specifically, markets for
commercial paper, asset-backed securities (ABS), and commercial mortgage backed
securities (CMBS).
ultimately affect U.S. financial markets. Both of these initiatives have been expanded several times during
the crisis, most notably when market turmoil reached a peak in September last year.
4
The TSLF was established in March 2008 as some large investment banks faced increasingly severe
liquidity pressures, which began to limit their ability to hold inventories of financial assets and thereby
make markets. The TSLF allows primary dealers to borrow Treasury securities from the Federal Reserve
for one-month terms against less-liquid collateral, which they can then use as collateral to borrow cash
from private counterparties. The PDCF was established shortly after as a backstop source of liquidity for
primary dealers.

-8Money market mutual funds have significant investments in CP. When Lehman
Brothers failed, it caused at least one money market mutual fund to “break the buck,”
leading to a run on money market funds. Three facilities--the Asset-Backed Commercial
Paper Money Market Mutual Fund Liquidity Facility, the Commercial Paper Funding
Facility and the Money Market Investor Funding Facility--were created to restore the
functioning of CP markets and allow money market mutual funds to manage through the
volatility.5 Conditions in the CP market have improved markedly since the introduction
of the various Federal Reserve facilities aimed at fostering market liquidity. CP spreads-shown in the left-hand panel of figure 4--have declined sharply since these facilities went
into effect. As with the bank and primary dealer-oriented facilities, when spreads
narrowed, usage subsided, as shown in the right-hand panel. While usage has declined
significantly, market participants tell us that the backstop provided by the facilities
continues to bolster market confidence.
The Term Auction Lending Facility (TALF) was created as a joint endeavor of
the Federal Reserve and Treasury to support economic activity by making credit more
readily available for consumers and businesses. The facility provides loans with
maturities of up to five years to investors to help finance their acquisitions of certain ABS
and CMBS. The program was announced in late 2008 at a time when ABS and CMBS
markets had essentially shut down, which thereby threatened to limit credit availability to

5

The Asset-Backed Commercial Paper Money Market Mutual Fund Liquidity Facility finances purchases
of high-quality asset-backed commercial paper by U.S. depository institutions and bank holding companies
from money market mutual funds, and the Money Market Investor Funding Facility provides liquidity to
U.S. money market mutual funds and certain other money market investors. Both facilities are aimed at
assisting money market mutual funds that hold CP to meet investor redemption demands, thereby
increasing these funds’ willingness to invest in money market instruments. The Commercial Paper
Funding Facility was set up to provide a liquidity backstop to U.S. issuers of CP through a specially created
limited liability company, which could purchase three-month unsecured and asset-backed commercial
paper directly from eligible issuers.

-9households and businesses. Initially, eligible collateral included newly issued triple-Arated ABS backed by a variety of loans to consumers and small businesses. Recently, the
Board announced that triple-A-rated newly issued and legacy CMBS would also be
accepted as collateral.6
Conditions in the markets for consumer ABS have improved notably since the
beginning of this year and more recently have improved in the markets for CMBS.
Estimates of spreads on triple-A-rated consumer ABS have narrowed between 70 to
80 percent from peak levels in December 2008. Estimates of spreads on triple-A-rated
CMBS have also moved down since March, although such spreads remain well above
their levels observed a year ago.7 While the now familiar improvement in spreads is
good news, the real story of TALF is in new issuance, shown in figure 5. Remembering
that these securities are used to finance new loans, look at the virtual shutdown of
securitization that occurred starting last fall in the credit card, auto, student loan, and
commercial real estate markets. The TALF began operation in March. For the first two
months, TALF lending and associated ABS issuance was fairly low, in part because
investors were unfamiliar with the program, but investor interest picked up considerably
in May and June and consumer ABS issuance has returned to levels near those seen

6

The types of collateral eligible under TALF are: the highest investment-grade-rated tranches of ABS
issued on or after January 1, 2009, for which the underlying credit exposures are auto loans, student loans,
credit card loans, equipment loans, floor plan loans, insurance-premium finance loans, small business loans
fully guaranteed as to principal and interest by the U.S. Small Business Administration, and receivables
related to residential mortgage servicing advances or commercial mortgage loans; the highest investmentgrade-rated tranches of CMBS issued on or after January 1, 2009; and certain high-quality CMBS issued
before January 1, 2009.
7
The observed narrowing of spreads likely represents both direct and indirect benefits of the TALF to
financial markets. The direct benefit is the increased demand for the specific types of securities that are
eligible for the TALF, which has likely contributed to the observed reduction in spreads. The indirect
benefits are the increase in the general level of confidence in the financial system, which has almost
certainly contributed to the narrowing of risk premiums in a wide variety of markets, including cash
markets--such as the corporate bond and leveraged loan markets--as well as markets for a range of
structured products.

- 10 before the disruption of ABS markets last fall. In addition, some ABS issues have come
to market outside of the TALF, and these are taking place at greatly improved spreads.
We hope to see similar improvements in the CMBS market later this summer when the
first TALF loans collateralized by newly issued and legacy CMBS are expected.
4. Large-scale purchases of high-quality assets. Credit-easing policies have also
been implemented through the purchase of high-quality assets aimed at improving
mortgage lending and housing markets as well as overall conditions in private credit
markets. In November 2008, the Federal Reserve announced plans to purchase a total of
up to $1.25 trillion of agency MBS and up to $200 billion of agency debt by the end of
the year, and in March 2009, the Federal Reserve announced that it may also buy up to
$300 billion of Treasury securities by the fall. 8
The program appears to be having its intended effect. Yields on mortgages
relative to Treasury yields have come down since November 2008. As shown in figure 6,
the 30-year fixed mortgage rate relative to the 5-year constant maturity Treasury rate
benchmark has declined about 1-1/4 percentage points since the first MBS purchase
program was announced. Indeed, today mortgage spreads are a lot closer to their mean
for 2000-2007 than they were in November. That said, mortgage rates have recently
risen with the increase in Treasury rates.
Fiscal Policy: Emergency Economic Stabilization Act
In October 2008, the Congress passed the Emergency Economic Stabilization Act
(EESA), which enabled a series of initiatives to provide confidence in the financial
system and to strengthen market stability. The ultimate goal of all these initiatives was to
8

As of June 10, the Federal Reserve held $427 billion of agency MBS and $84 billion of agency debt (of
which almost all was purchased since late November) and $622 billion of Treasury securities (of which
$210 billion was purchased since March).

- 11 increase the flow of financing to U.S. businesses and consumers and to support the U.S.
economy.
Lending activities require both capital and liquidity. While the Federal Reserve
had been providing liquidity, equity markets were virtually closed to financial firms last
fall. Using authorities and funding provided by EESA, the Treasury’s Capital Purchase
Program provides government capital investments to banks in good condition. Since last
fall, nearly $200 billion has been invested under this program.
Confidence in the U.S. banking system has also been supported by temporary
extensions of government safety net policies. A component of EESA was the temporary
raising of the basic limit on federal deposit insurance coverage from $100,000 to
$250,000 per depositor. In line with this change, the FDIC also announced the provision
of full coverage of noninterest bearing deposit transaction accounts under its temporary
Transaction Account Guarantee Program. In addition, the FDIC began guaranteeing
newly issued senior unsecured debt of banks, thrifts, and certain holding companies under
the Temporary Liquidity Guarantee Program (TLGP).9 Since late April, some banks
have issued debt outside of the TLGP, albeit with spreads of several percentage points
higher than debt issued under the program. This activity suggests that the TLGP is
providing an important source of support to the funding needs of banks, thrifts, and their
parent companies.
The Supervisory Capital Assessment Program
In February of this year, the Federal Reserve, as part of the Treasury’s Financial
Stability Plan, initiated the Supervisory Capital Assessment Program (SCAP) to evaluate
9

Since the TGLP went into effect in November 2008, $265 billion in debt has been issued by 30 parent
companies and 37 firms, with spreads over Treasury securities in recent months remaining on the order of
1/4 to 3/4 percent, depending on the maturity

- 12 whether large U.S. banking institutions would need to raise a temporary capital buffer to
be able to withstand losses in a more challenging economic environment than generally
anticipated. The SCAP determined the capital buffer by estimating losses and internal
resources to absorb losses at the 19 largest U.S. banking institutions. The scenario used
to estimate the buffer was more adverse than that expected by the consensus of private
forecasters. The exercise was conducted by more than 150 examiners, analysts,
economists, accountants, attorneys, and other professionals from the Federal Reserve, the
Office of the Comptroller of the Currency, and the FDIC.
When completed, the assessment indicated that additional capital buffers--with a
total value of $185 billion--were required by 10 out of the 19 institutions to maintain
Tier 1 capital in excess of 6 percent of total assets and Tier 1 common equity capital in
excess of 4 percent under the more adverse scenario. Of the $185 billion, the equivalent
of $110 billion had already been raised or committed prior to the announcement of the
results in early May. And since the announcement, these firms have raised about
$50 billion from equity offerings, preferred stock conversions, and asset sales. I believe
the early success shown by firms in accessing private capital demonstrates the
improvement in market confidence provided by the SCAP exercise. With renewed
access to nongovernment debt and private capital, many institutions have announced
intentions to repay the government preferred stock issued under the CPP.
How Well Have Policies to Contain the Crisis Worked? An Aggregate Credit
Perspective
So far I have discussed evidence that programs directed at dysfunction in specific
markets has been successful in alleviating stresses in those markets. But the ultimate

- 13 goal of those policies as well as those aimed at strengthening financial institutions is to
improve the flow of credit to households and businesses. I now want to look at this
ultimate goal by examining how credit volumes have evolved over this current business
cycle downturn relative to previous downturns, as identified by the National Bureau of
Economic Research (NBER) Business Cycle Dating Committee. I will do this using the
Federal Reserve’s Flow of Funds data. In most instances, I will focus only on those
downturns associated with credit crunches.10
A credit crunch, according to the White House Council of Economic Advisers,
“occurs when the supply of credit is restricted below the range usually identified with
prevailing market interest rates and the profitability of investment projects.”11 Judging
whether a credit crunch is happening in real time--and, to some extent, even in hindsight-is not easy. It is extremely difficult to sort out the relative importance on the flow of
credit of reduced demand due to weaker economic activity, reduced supply because
borrowers appear less creditworthy, or reduced supply because lenders face pressures,
such as a shortage of capital, that restrain them from extending credit. In other words,
while demand considerations could certainly result in a decline in credit flows, a
reduction in the supply of credit--caused either by bank balance sheet pressures or by
banks being reluctant to lend to less-creditworthy borrowers--could produce the same
result. Anecdotal evidence and some academic research suggest that the recessions that
followed the business cycle peaks in 1969, 1973, 1981, and 1990 were credit-crunch

10

In these cases, however, accompanying charts (figures A.1 and A.2) that show the paths of credit over
business cycle downturns in both credit-crunch and non-credit-crunch recessions are available online.
11
Council of Economic Advisers (1992), Economic Report of the President (Washington: Government
Printing Office), p. 46.

- 14 recessions. 12 Clearly, the current downturn--specifically, that following the December
2007 business cycle peak--is also considered a credit-crunch recession.
How Has Credit Evolved during This Business Cycle?
Growth of the broad credit aggregates. In looking at the evolution of credit in
both the current and past business cycle downturns, I will look at four major types of
credit: home mortgages, commercial mortgages, consumer credit, and nonfinancial
business credit. Figure 7 presents four-quarter growth rates for each credit type from
1952 to 2008, where the shaded areas denote NBER recession periods. As can be seen
from the figure, credit growth typically declined prior to and during economic downturns,
and this time-series pattern is readily apparent in the current downturn in all four panels.
In the current downturn, the reduction in lending growth that stands out as being
the most “out of the ordinary” is that of home mortgages, which is shown in the top-left
panel. Home mortgage volumes actually contracted for the first time in the Flow of
Fund’s 50-plus year history over the four quarters ended 2008:Q4, after having always
maintained growth above 4 percent. In terms of being an outlier relative to past business
cycles, the current experience for home mortgages is similar to that of commercial
mortgages in the 1990-91 recession, which is shown in the top-right panel.
In the downturn following the 1990 business cycle peak, commercial mortgage
volumes contracted after having never contracted (in nominal terms) before that. This
downturn also included a financial crisis, although then it was due to commercial real

12

More specifically, the business cycle peaks occurred in 1969:Q4, 1973:Q4, 1981:Q3, and 1990:Q3.
Kaufman (1991) cites credit crunches that occurred in 1959, 1969-70, the mid-1970s, 1981-82, and 199091. See Henry Kaufman (1991), “Credit Crunches: The Deregulators Were Wrong,” Wall Street Journal,
October 9. Also see Albert M. Wojnilower (1980), “The Central Role of Credit Crunches in Recent
Financial History,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, vol. 11, pp. 277-340.

- 15 estate rather than residential real estate, as it is now. Given the similarities between these
two business cycle downturns, it seems interesting to compare them.
A comparison of the current downturn with the one that followed the 1990:Q3
peak. Figure 8, which shows the same credit types as figure 7, provides “butterfly” charts
for inflation-adjusted levels of four different types of lending--home mortgages (top-left
panel), consumer credit (bottom-left panel), commercial mortgages (top-right panel), and
nonfinancial business credit (bottom-right panel)--over the current downturn and the
1990-91 recession. The series in the charts have been normalized to 100 at each business
cycle peak, which is also marked with the vertical bar.13 Normalized lending data for
quarters prior to and after each business cycle peak are color-coded to each peak. Data
associated with the 1990:Q3 peak are shown using thick dark green lines, and data
associated with the recent 2007:Q4 peak are shown using thick red lines. Activity to the
left represents the 16 quarters leading up to the peak, and the activity to the right
represents the 8 quarters following the peak. A steeper line to the left of the vertical bar
implies higher credit growth prior to the peak; a more negatively sloped line to the right
implies a larger reduction in credit during the downturn.
The right side of the chart considers commercial mortgages and nonfinancial
business credit. Both of these lending aggregates expanded more rapidly in the lead up to
the 2007 business cycle peak than in the lead up to the 1990 peak, and both also
contracted (or continued to contract) immediately after the 1990 business cycle peak.

13

The normalization of each series is also made so that the difference between the level of a lending series
at any date and the level at the business cycle peak has a percentage interpretation. For example, if a line
has a value of 80 at some date before or after the business cycle peak, it means that the level of the category
of lending that the line represents is 20 percent below the level of lending at the business cycle peak.
Likewise, if a line has a value of 110 at some date, it means that the level of the category of lending that the
line represents is 10 percent above the level of lending at the peak of the business cycle.

- 16 Until recently, neither lending aggregate had declined in the current downturn, but in the
first quarter of this year, nonfinancial business credit contracted quite sharply.
For consumer credit (in the lower-left panel), it matters--in the lead up to the most
recent business cycle peak--how we measure it. Without home equity lines of credit
(HELOCs) and home equity loans, the increase in consumer credit in the lead up to the
1990 and the 2007 business cycle peaks are broadly similar. If we include all HELOCs
and home equity loans, which can be used in a similar way to consumer credit, then
lending in the lead up to the 2007 business cycle peak--represented by the thin red line-increases more notably.14 Consumer credit contracted in the 1990-91 recession but has
remained broadly flat in the current downturn, albeit with a slight downward drift in more
recent quarters.
For home mortgages, shown in the top-left panel, lending expanded similarly in
the lead up to both the 1990 and the 2007 business cycle peaks. In contrast to the other
types of credit, this type of lending did not contract in the 1990-91 recession but has
contracted since the peak of this cycle.
Apart from home mortgages, the drop-off in credit in the 1990-91 recession was
notably more severe than what has been experienced so far in the current downturn.
There are two possible reasons why this might happen. One is that demand for credit
turned down more sharply in the 1990-91 recession than in the current downturn, but I do
not think that this is the reason. The slowdown in economic activity in the 1990-91
recession was nowhere near as severe (either in terms of depth or duration) as it has been
to date in the current recession, which the NBER still considers to be ongoing. This

14

Note that cash-out refinancing--like HELOCs and home equity loans--can also be used in a similar way
to consumer credit, which is not included in the chart.

- 17 difference in economic activity across the two recessions suggests that it is unlikely that
credit demand contracted more sharply in the 1990-91 recession than in the current
downturn. The other possible reason, which I think more likely, is that credit supply
conditions have been a little more favorable--albeit still stressful--in the most recent
downturn relative to those during the 1990-91 recession. I believe this difference does
reflect policy. That is, all the facilities and programs laid out earlier have acted to shore
up the financial sector and to prevent a notably more severe contraction in credit than we
have seen.
Given the stark differences between the paths of credit in the current recession
compared with those of 1990-91, I want to see if the same patterns hold true in
comparison with other credit-crunch recessions.
A comparison of the current downturn with other credit-crunch recessions that
occurred within the past 40 years. Figure 9 provides butterfly charts for the same four
inflation-adjusted levels of credit as shown in figure 8, now shown with the last five
business cycle peaks that preceded credit-crunch recessions--specifically, the business
cycle peaks in 1969, 1973, 1981, 1990, and 2007. Data associated with the most recent
peak continue to be shown by thick red lines. Data associated with the 1990 peak are
now shown by thinner dark green lines.15
Figure 9 indicates that, with the exception of housing, lending over the current
downturn does not appear particularly weak or subdued relative to other downturns.
Indeed, for all categories of lending other than home mortgage lending (shown in the topleft panel), there are at least two other downturns for which the paths of lending after the

15

A set of charts (figures A.1 and A.2) are provided online that also include the paths of credit around the
business cycle peaks preceding non-credit-crunch recessions

- 18 business cycle peak lie below that following 2007:Q4 (that is, the drop-off in credit was
more pronounced). Even for home mortgages, the decline in lending is not tremendously
large relative to the experience of past business cycle downturns. In contrast, over the
1990-91 recession, lending, with the exception of home mortgages, experienced either the
largest or the second-largest contraction of all credit-crunch-associated downturns.
This feature is even more prominent when lending only by depositories is
considered. Figure 10 has the same format as figure 9 but presents time-series data on
lending by depository institutions only--that is, commercial banks, savings institutions,
and credit unions. 16 Figure 10 indicates that lending by depositories over the current
downturn does not appear particularly weak or subdued relative to other downturns.
Indeed, for all components of credit other than home mortgages, the path of lending in
the current downturn lies toward the upper end of the range of outcomes for past business
cycle downturns. Of course, some of the observed lending by depositories in the current
downturn does reflect the safety-valve role played by financial intermediaries in the
financial system--that is, households and, in particular, businesses drawing on existing
lines of bank credit when alternative sources of finance have become more difficult to
obtain. Finally, when home mortgages made by depositories only is considered, the path
of lending lies within the range of outcomes for past business cycle downturns (albeit
toward the lower part of the envelope).
Given the enormity of some of the events of the past year, the findings of these
business cycle comparisons may seem somewhat surprising. However, as was evident
from the facilities and programs discussed earlier, policy has been extremely active in the
current credit crisis, especially with respect to the banking sector.
16

Note that the data for depositories shown in figure 10 also use the Flow of Funds Accounts.

- 19 Given the similarities between home mortgages in the current downturn and
commercial mortgages in the 1990-91 recession, as well as the commonality that both
recessions were characterized by a financial system crisis, the outcomes for lending in the
1990-91 recession could be thought of as a possible scenario for lending in the current
downturn in the absence of any policy response. That said, the likely path of lending in
the current downturn without any policy response would have been notably more
contractionary than in the 1990-91 recession given that the earlier episode--while
characterized by a financial crisis--did not face as extreme an episode as the one
experienced last September.
Conclusion
Today I have reviewed developments in specific financial markets following the
introduction of Federal Reserve and other agency facilities and programs, and have
considered the evolution of the major categories of credit in both the current economic
downturn and past downturns. This assessment of the data suggests that these
government programs have been broadly successful in relieving stresses in the key credit
markets. This success is also reflected in aggregate credit data, which indicate that most
categories of household and nonfinancial-firm lending in the current recession do not
appear especially weak relative to past recessions. Given the enormity of events over the
past year, this result is a surprising but reassuring early indication that the combined
policies have been successful at shoring up credit despite these events.
A note of caution is in order however. In the past, economic downturns were
deepened or prolonged by the premature withdrawal of monetary or fiscal stimulus. To
the extent that the severity of the current downturn has thus far been mitigated by

- 20 extraordinary credit support, a significantly weaker path of lending--and thereby
economic activity--could very likely occur if policy support for the financial sector is
withdrawn too soon. In this case, stigmatization of support tools such as liquidity
programs, direct lending programs, or government capital injections that make
participants unwilling to use such programs will have the same effect as a direct policy
withdrawal of the programs. And while the path of credit in this cycle compared with
others is encouraging, the downturn in credit evident in the most recent quarter provides a
reminder that conditions are still far from normal.