View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Testimony of Governor Edward M. Gramlich
Social security reform
Before the Committee on Finance, U.S. Senate
September 9, 1998

I am pleased to appear before the Committee to testify on Social Security reform. I speak for
myself, as past chair of the 1994-96 Quadrennial Advisory Council on Social Security, and
not in my current status as a member of the Federal Reserve Board.
Let me first engage in some retrospection. At the time our Advisory Council released its
report in early 1997, there was much publicity about the fact that we couldn't agree on a
single plan, but had three separate approaches. Since that time it strikes me that there has
been a coalescence around the middle-ground approach I advocated. After our report, both
the Committee for Economic Development (CED) and Senator Moynihan came out with
plans which were similar to my plan and adopted some of its features. Earlier this year the
National Commission on Retirement Policy (NCRP) came out with a similar plan, again
adopting some features of my plan. In political terms the center seems to be holding--since
our report there has been increased interest in sensible middle-ground approaches, and I
would encourage this Committee to work in that direction.
In trying to reform Social Security, I have stressed the importance of two goals. The first is
to make affordable the important social protections of this program that have greatly
reduced aged poverty and the human costs of work disabilities. The second is to add new
national saving for retirement-both to help individuals maintain their own standard of living
in retirement and to build up the nation's capital stock in advance of the baby boom
retirement crunch.
The Individual Accounts Plan
My compromise plan, called the Individual Accounts (IA) Plan, achieves both goals. It
preserves the important social protections of Social Security and still achieves long term
financial balance in the system by what might be called kind and gentle benefit cuts. Most of
the cuts would be felt by high wage workers, with disabled and low wage workers being
largely protected from cuts. Unlike the other two plans proposed in the Advisory Council
report, there would be no reliance at all on the stock market to finance Social Security
benefits, and no worsening of the finances of the Health Insurance Trust Fund.
The IA plan includes some technical changes such as including all state and local new hires
in Social Security and applying consistent income tax treatment to Social Security benefits.
These changes go some way to eliminating Social Security's actuarial deficit.
Then, beginning in the 21st century, two other measures would take effect. There would be
a slight increase in the normal retirement age for all workers, in line with the expected
growth in overall life expectancy (also proposed by the CED, Senator Moynihan, and the
NCRP). There would also be a slight change in the benefit formula to reduce the growth of

Social Security benefits for high wage workers (also proposed by the CED and NCRP).
Both of these changes would be phased in very gradually to avoid actual benefit cuts for
present retirees and "notches" in the benefit schedule (instances when younger workers with
the same earnings records get lower real benefits than older workers). The result of all these
changes would be a modest reduction in the overall real growth of Social Security benefits
over time. When combined with the rising number of retirees, the share of the nation's
output devoted to Social Security spending would be approximately the same as at present,
limiting this part of the impending explosion in future entitlement spending.
These benefit cuts alone would mean that high wage workers would not experience rising
real benefits as their real wages grow, so I would supplement these changes with another
measure to raise overall retirement (and national) saving. Workers would be required to
contribute an extra 1.6 percent of their pay to newly-created individual accounts. These
accounts would be owned by workers but centrally managed. Workers would be able to
allocate their funds among five to ten broad mutual or index funds covering stocks and
bonds. Central management of the funds would cut down the risk that funds would be
invested unwisely, would cut administrative costs, and would mean that Wall Street firms
would not find these individual accounts a financial bonanza. The funds would be converted
to real annuities on retirement, to protect against inflation and the chance that retirees would
overspend in their early retirement years.
Some have objected to these add-on individual accounts because they seem like a new tax.
First off, I should point out that since the accounts will be returned to the individual in the
future (with investment earnings), they are very different from a tax. Indeed, if people who
already have significant pension saving beyond Social Security want to reduce their private
contributions and preserve their disposable income, there is nothing to stop them. Finally, as
a further sweetener it may be possible to let those who can certify the existence of their own
private pensions opt out of these add-on accounts, and thus save Social Security the
administrative costs. Whatever is done, the basic idea is to raise national saving for the
people who do not have much pension saving beyond Social Security, and this scheme
seems well-suited for that.
Federal Budget Surpluses
A welcome new development since our Council issued its report is the arrival of surpluses in
the overall federal budget. Some observers have suggested using these surpluses in some
way to build up the individual accounts. One example is your own bill, Mr. Chairman.
While the advent of these overall surpluses lessens future interest payments and the overall
growth of entitlement spending, I see some problems with "using" the surpluses for Social
Security. A first problem from a budget standpoint is that the surpluses already are being
used in that way. The overall surplus is more than accounted for by the OASDI surplus,
which is already used to finance future Social Security benefits, so there is double-counting
in using these federal surpluses again for retirement programs, whether to finance individual
accounts or to finance future Social Security spending. The second problem is that use of the
surplus in such a way does not generate new national saving, and I continue to think that
that should be an important part of Social Security reform. Hence I would not favor taking
any additional steps to use the surpluses to raise future retirement benefits.
Conclusion
The Social Security and pension changes that I have recommended would mean that

approximately the presently scheduled level of benefits would be paid to all wage classes of
workers, of all ages. The difference between the outcome and present law is that under this
plan these benefits would be financed, as they are not under present law. The changes would
eliminate Social Security's long run financial deficit while still holding together the
important retirement safety net provided by Social Security. They would reduce the growth
of entitlement spending. They would significantly raise the return on invested contributions
for younger workers. And, the changes would move beyond the present pay-as-you-go
financing scheme, by providing new saving to build up the nation's capital stock in advance
of the baby boom retirement crunch.
As the Congress debates Social Security reform, I hope it will keep these goals in mind and
consider these types of changes in this very important program. Thank you very much.
Return to top
1998 Testimony
Home | News and events
Accessibility | Contact Us
Last update: September 9, 1998, 9:30 AM