View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Speech by Governor Edward M. Gramlich

At the Benjamin Rush Lecture, Dickinson College, Pennsylvania
March 2, 2005

The Importance of Raising National Saving
An old saw has it that central bankers are paid to worry. They are supposed to look past any superficial
good news and try to discern longer-run problems--perhaps inflation heating up, perhaps something
else. For a central banker, every silver lining has a cloud.
The present time provides a good illustration. We are just completing the forecasting season, at which
time various economists make their projections. The Blue Chip survey of leading business forecasters
predicts that the growth of real gross domestic product will average 3.5 percent over the next two
years and that unemployment rates will decline slightly. Unemployment rates are near their normal, or
equilibrium, level, yet these forecasters still look for basic stability in core inflation rates. According to
the Blue Chip survey, investment should grow at healthy rates, and productivity growth should remain
strong. In these forecasts, the Federal Reserve is expected to keep raising short-term interest rates
toward their equilibrium level. It all seems pretty healthy--what is there to worry about?
Well, unfortunately, there could be something to worry about, and that is what I want to talk about
today. It is the nation's low national saving rate, basically the share of our output that is devoted to
building up the country. This share can be defined either as the share of output not consumed either by
households or government, or as the share of output devoted to capital investment less the share
represented by borrowing from foreigners. The last clause is important--high investment is a good
thing, but if much of this investment is financed by borrowing from foreigners rather than by our own
saving, there could be trouble spots down the road. Whether there will be such trouble spots, I don't
know. That is another issue I'd like to discuss.
National Saving
As important as I think it is, national saving has always been relegated to the B list of economic
measures. When economic data are released, there is always a great deal of attention to overall output,
unemployment, inflation, interest rates, and budget and trade deficits. National saving rates have a lot
to do with shaping each of these variables, but one searches in vain for mention of such rates. Today I
am going to elevate national saving rates to center stage.
I begin with a simple identity, taken from the national income accounts:
NS = S - BD = I - B
The left side of this identity covers the sources of national saving (NS), which are private saving in the
economy (S) less budget deficits (BD). Budget deficits are subtracted because budget deficits imply
that private saving is in part going to pay for the deficits of the government and not going into private
investment.
The more interesting part of the equation involves the uses of national saving, given on the right side

of the identity. In an economy closed to international trade and capital flows, the long-time staple of
undergraduate macroeconomics classes, national saving equals just domestic investment (I), which is
spending on new capital equipment. This is the spending that raises productivity and output in the long
run, and for that reason it is of special interest. But since economies are now open to international
trade and capital flows, the identity must also account for the portion of national saving lent abroad or
the portion of investment financed by borrowing from abroad (B). This is done by deducting B,
essentially the nation's current account deficit (through another accounting identity of which I will
spare you discussion).
One value of writing out the national saving identity is to bring out an important short-run, long-run
dichotomy. In the short-run, international borrowing can go up or down depending on cyclical
movements, exchange rates, and a host of other factors. Very few countries do without any
international borrowing or lending in a particular year. But over a longer period of time international
borrowing kept close to zero stabilizes a country's ratio of international obligations to its gross
domestic product (GDP).1 When this liability ratio is stable, a nation's saving is implicitly financing
most of its domestic investment. Persistent borrowing, keeping investment above saving, may be
possible, but it is not common, and in any case it automatically implies a buildup of international
liabilities relative to its national output. If a nation wants to have its investment and not pay increasing
shares of income in interest or dividends, it has to finance this investment by its own national saving.
Or, turning the equation around, high national saving will raise future living standards whether it
finances investment directly or reduces international borrowing.
A further value in writing out the identity is to tie all this to budget and current account deficits, which
are the focus of much popular discussion. In a word, both deficits are subtraction items. Budget
deficits reduce national saving by, as I said earlier, siphoning off some private saving to pay for
government deficits. Current account deficits can be associated with low national saving if a nation
borrows to finance its investment. Some economists talk about a "twin deficit" scenario in which
budget deficits lead to current account deficits of exactly the same size. There are macroeconomic
scenarios that can lead to that result, and these, according to the equation, imply that investment and
private saving move together or are fixed. But it is also possible to imagine many scenarios in which
budget and current account deficits move independently. These deficits are certainly linked through
their impact on national saving, but they are not twins.
Finally, the numbers. National saving rates can be given in two ways, either by comparing gross
national saving with gross domestic product, or by subtracting depreciation from both sides and
comparing net national saving with net domestic product. It turns out not to matter for this discussion-by either definition, national saving rates are at a post-World War II low. The numbers since the mid1960s are shown in figure 1. As suggested in the preceding discussion, when national saving rates are
this low, the nation suffers from some combination of low investment and high borrowing. The former
is bad from the standpoint of future productivity, the latter is likely not sustainable. Neither situation is
desirable.
Sources Side
National saving has dropped because private saving rates have dropped, especially those for
households.2 Moreover, in recent years federal budget deficits have shot up. From a national saving
point of view, the rise in deficits would not be particularly alarming if private saving rates were high,
nor would the decline in private saving rates be particularly alarming if the budget were in surplus. But
the combination of low private saving rates and deficits can lead to problems.
While there are ways to influence private saving rates by policy measures, changes in national saving

for the most part follow changes in fiscal policy.3 Figure 2 shows the historical path for fiscal policy,
specifically the federal deficit (in effect consigning state and local governments to the private sector).
The dotted line shows the primary deficit, which is the total federal deficit less interest payments, as a
share of GDP. To stabilize the ratio of the stock of federal debt to GDP, this primary deficit should be
kept close to zero.4 The solid line gives just this federal debt to GDP ratio.
When viewed in a historical context the federal deficit picture does not look particularly troubling. The
primary deficit ratio has cycled around zero, and the debt-GDP ratio has cycled between 25 and 50
percent. The debt-GDP ratio had a long downswing in the 1960s and early 1970s, followed by a long
upswing in the 1980s. The United States ran fairly large primary surpluses in the 1990s, enough so to
inspire talk of paying off the entire outstanding federal debt. But that brief period of good fortune has
passed; primary deficits are back, and the debt-GDP ratio is rising again.
For the intermediate future, the picture worsens somewhat. Recently, the Congressional Budget Office
(CBO) made projections for the next decade. One of their scenarios took the so-called baseline budget,
added in likely military spending for Iraq and Afghanistan, extended the recently enacted tax cuts, and
adjusted the alternative minimum tax for inflation.5 Under these assumptions, the recent turn for the
worse is likely to be reversed only slowly. The primary deficit averages around 2 percent of GDP for
the next few years before gradually shrinking, and the debt-GDP ratio climbs back to about 45 percent
by 2015. But these projections include only relatively certain budget obligations, and one can be
forgiven for fearing that the actual numbers will turn out to be worse than the CBO projections, as they
often do through no fault of the CBO. Hence, the medium-term projections do not give much reason
for thinking that the downward pressure on overall national saving rates will be quickly reversed.
If the medium term looks uncertain, the far future looks much worse. As is well known, the population
of the United States is aging, and in a few decades a much larger share of the population will be in its
retirement years, drawing on both Social Security and Medicare. The share of output devoted to these
two programs will rise rapidly, putting even further downward pressure on national saving rates. The
trends, especially for Medicare, are so alarming that these two programs alone could, in the space of
little more than a decade, account for about half of federal spending. Changes have to be made in these
large entitlement programs to avoid a real fiscal disaster.
Of course changes can be made. While there are as yet not a great number of feasible ideas for
significantly reducing the cost of Medicare, there are a number of proposals to reform Social Security.
The President is touting a proposal, and ten years ago as chair of another Presidential advisory council
on Social Security, I devised a proposal of my own.6 This is not the place to get into a full discussion
of Social Security reform proposals, but one aspect of Social Security reform is important. Given the
low national saving rates, and the fact that many American households do not save enough to avoid a
big cut in their standard of living in retirement, it would seem desirable to have Social Security
reforms that also raise national saving. One obvious and immediate way to do that would be to raise
payroll taxes; another obvious, and perhaps less painful, way to do that would be to have individual
accounts on top of Social Security. If these "add-on" individual accounts were to be mandated, as I
proposed, those households who already save amply could reduce their other individual accounts
while those who do no private saving for retirement would be forced to do more. Hence national
saving would be increased, and increased for just those households who presently do little saving.
Other types of Social Security reform seem less promising from a national saving point of view. If, for
example, the individual accounts were to be "carved out" of present payroll tax payments, as President
Bush has recently proposed, household saving would go up but government saving, in the first
instance, would go down by the same amount, meaning that the initial impact on overall national

saving would be nil. But carve-out individual accounts might eventually reduce saving because
households getting individual accounts who are already saving for retirement might cut back on their
pre-existing saving. Hence carve-out individual accounts seem more likely to reduce than increase
national saving. This is not the only criterion for judging between add-on and carve-out individual
accounts, but I think it is an important one.
There may also be some way to compromise between mandatory add-on individual accounts that raise
national saving but could be a tough sell politically, and carve-out individual accounts that are not
likely to raise national saving. Some have suggested raising employee pension contribution rates by
automatic default options for employer defined-contribution account. Under such a plan employees
would be automatically enrolled in the employer's plan and would have to "opt out" to reject
participation. Moreover, firms could be forced to carry employer defined-contribution accounts, as is
done in Ireland.
Other measures that might raise national saving are tax incentives to increase private saving, such as
Individual Retirement Accounts (IRAs). These essentially reduce or eliminate the taxation of interest
income and hence provide a price inducement for households to save more. While such measures are
often advertised as ways to increase saving, one must be very careful. On one side, many households
can easily claim the tax advantages by diverting existing assets into IRAs and not saving any more. On
the other side, IRAs entail a federal revenue loss and a rise in deficits. Since national saving is defined
as private saving less deficits, the larger deficits can actually make national saving decline in response
to a measure that purports to increase national saving. If the private saving effect were large enough
and the revenue loss small, it is also possible that IRAs would have the anticipated effect of increasing
national saving. One cannot give a purely theoretical answer to the question--it depends on how the
numbers come out.7 For years the economics profession has been engaged in a strenuous debate about
these numbers, but it should be noted that overall household and national saving rates have declined
significantly since IRA-type provisions were first introduced to the tax code.
Even the mortgage interest deduction can enter in to the question. Through this deduction, households
can borrow, add to their mortgage, reduce their taxes, and invest the proceeds in IRAs. Hence the mere
presence of the mortgage interest deduction means that IRA-type measures, or consumption tax
measures, that purport to increase private saving will, in fact, not increase private saving and could
reduce national saving. That is why consumption-tax reform measures that omit treatment of the
mortgage interest deduction are unlikely to promote national saving.
Uses Side
We have seen that national saving is likely to continue to be low, the result of a combination of low
personal saving in the presence of possibly persisting budget deficits. As was mentioned, this sets up a
difficult quandary--either investment will have to decrease, lowering future productivity, or
international borrowing will have to continue at high levels, raising international liability ratios. The
real question is whether the large-scale borrowing is sustainable.
The historical record for the United States, presented in a form similar to that for budget deficits, is
shown in figure 3. Again, the dotted line is the primary deficit ratio, which in the case of international
accounts is just the trade deficit. The solid line is the ratio of net international liabilities to domestic
GDP, a measure of the nation's ability to afford its liabilities. As recently as 1985, net U.S. liabilities to
foreigners were zero. But since 1990 the United States has embarked on a long-term period of high
trade deficits, and now the international liability rate is close to 25 percent of GDP and rising sharply.
International wealth portfolios are getting increasingly heavy in dollar-denominated assets. How long
can this process continue?

We can first examine the international record. The international deficit that determines the growth or
decline in a country's international liability ratio is the trade deficit, and there are few cases of
countries running large-scale trade deficits for more than four or five years. By this standard, the U.S.
borrowing spurt should have ended a long time ago. In line with this record, many authors have been
predicting for some time that the combination of interest rates, income, prices, and exchange rates
would adjust to end the U.S. trade deficits.8
But the deficits have not ended, and international economists are searching for reasons to explain the
situation. Perhaps the simplest explanation is that the current situation meets the apparent needs of
many countries. Under this view, which has been labeled the "co-dependency" view, the United States
is permitted to overconsume through the combination of its inability to cut budget deficits and its
unwillingness to save much privately. Other countries are permitted to support their export industries
by keeping the dollar strong and their own currencies weak.9 These countries in effect create reserves
by buying and holding stocks of U.S. Treasury debt. These international open-market purchases keep
the dollar strong, the home currencies weak, and export industries competitive. Were countries trying
to keep their own currencies strong, they would run out of the foreign assets to sell to support their
own currency. But in keeping the dollar strong, all central banks have to do is to create reserves, and
central banks can create reserves.
Another possibility is that other countries, in Europe and much of Asia, have populations that are
aging more rapidly than those in the United States. They may want to build up a stock of assets to
prepare for their own retirement spending crises. Largely because of the productivity revolution here,
these countries have been able to get better returns on their assets in this country than in their own, and
they have been putting great quantities of saving in world capital markets, perhaps explaining the
present low level of world long-term real interest rates. As a result, foreigners may be quite willing to
accumulate dollar-denominated assets, and may appreciate the low U.S. national saving rate.
A third possibility is that the so-called "home bias" in international saving-investment choices is
gradually eroding.10 In this view, globalization has generally reduced the barriers to international asset
diversification, and we are witnessing a rebalancing of wealth portfolios which, in the transition, can
lead to persisting current account deficits or surpluses.
It is very difficult to tell which of these explanations, or some combination of them, is on the mark and
whether there are unknown fourth or fifth explanations. In each case there is an international selfinterest argument to explain the situation, and it is difficult to assess the durability of this self-interest.
The co-dependency view could have a natural stopping point when foreign central banks begin to
worry about their heavy asset concentration in dollar-denomination assets and diversify their stock.
The world-saving view could have a natural stopping point when the populations of the accumulating
countries begin to retire, run down their assets, and sell their dollar-denominated assets to support the
consumption of retirees. The disappearing-home-bias view could have a natural stopping point when
wealth portfolios are rebalanced. This is all new and unexplored territory.
But determining what explanation may be correct and stable may also be somewhat beside the point.
However stable the underlying phenomena, it is much more stable for the United States to increase its
own national saving and finance its own investment. This approach would support investment in the
short run and make this investment more profitable in the long run, because the returns on capital
would not be sent abroad. Other countries may still invest their saving here, but the United States
would have a higher base of its self-financed investment. This situation would seem to be far and away
the preferred course from a risk-management standpoint.

Under such an approach, which I will term co-independence, the United States would gradually cut its
budget deficit. Doing so would reduce aggregate demand and hence require other changes to preserve
full employment. One such change would be that currency rates might shift in the direction of
increasing U.S. net exports. To the extent that stimulation of net exports did not offset the fiscal
actions fully, there is always monetary accommodation. One of the key mandates of the Federal
Reserve is to preserve sustainable employment levels, and the Fed certainly could do that.
In this strategy, other countries would have two requirements. To the extent that currency rates might
need to adjust to restore international balance, foreign central banks should permit normal market
readjustments. And to the extent that foreign net exports might decline as the United States cut its own
trade deficits, foreign countries may need to stimulate their own economies, which they could do with
some combination of monetary and fiscal policy. The result would be to preserve full employment
around the world but with reduced capital account imbalances.
Conclusion
The message here could be worrisome but is really designed to provoke action. In the short run, output
growth is healthy and inflation rates are stable. Investment shares are reasonable, but that is largely
because the United States is borrowing such a huge amount from world capital markets. The key
question is whether this borrowing is sustainable.
However sustainable it is, the United States would seem well-advised to minimize risks by raising its
own national saving to finance its own investment. That would stabilize investment in the short run
and increase profitability in the long run. It could raise national saving with some combination of
fiscal tightening and measures to raise private saving, coupled with other measures, here and abroad,
to increase demand throughout the world economy.

Return to text

Return to text

Return to text

Footnotes
1. The precise proposition is that the primary, or noninterest, component of both budget and current
account deficits must remain close to zero to stabilize the ratio of debt to national output. For a
demonstration see Edward M. Gramlich (2004), "Budget and Trade Deficits: Linked, Both Worrisome
in the Long Run, but Not Twins," speech delivered at the Euromoney Bond Investors Congress,
February 25, 2005. Return to text
2. Leonard Nakamura (2005), The Personal Saving Rate and the Future of Consumption, Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, February, demonstrates a systematic tendency for personal saving rates
to be revised upward. If this is so, it is possible that some of the recent dip will be revised
away. Return to text
3. Economists have a Ricardian equivalence exception--national saving rates do not follow changes in
fiscal policy if private households offset fiscal actions with their own saving. In general, the evidence
does not support this proposition. See Douglas W. Elmendorf and N. Gregory Mankiw (1999),
"Government Debt," in J.B. Taylor and M. Woodford, eds., Handbook of Macroeconomics,

(Elsevier). Return to text
4. Shown in Gramlich, "Budget and Trade Deficits." Return to text
5. See Congressional Budget Office (2005), Budget and Economic Outlook, January 25. Return to text
6. Edward M. Gramlich (1998), Is It Time to Reform Social Security? (University of Michigan
Press). Return to text
7. The fall 1996 issue of the Journal of Economic Perspectives contained several articles summarizing
empirical work on this question. Return to text
8. See, for example, articles in C. Fred Bergsten, ed. (2005), The United States and the World
Economy (Washington: Institute for International Economics). Return to text
9. The co-dependency term was coined by Catherine L. Mann (2004), "Managing Exchange Rates:
Achievement of Global Rebalancing or Evidence of Global Co-dependency?" Business Economics,
vol. 39 (July). Return to text
10. The home bias term originally stemmed from results in a paper by Martin Feldstein and Charles
Horioka (1980), "Domestic Savings and International Capital Flows," Economic Journal, vol.
90. Return to text
Return to top
2005 Speeches
Home | News and events
Accessibility | Contact Us
Last update: March 2, 2005