View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Remarks by Governor Edward M. Gramlich

At the Federal Reserve Board Models and Monetary Policy Conference, Washington,
D.C.
March 26, 2004

The Board's Modeling Work in the 1960s
I am delighted to be speaking at a conference honoring Dale Henderson, Dick Porter, and
Peter Tinsley. I remember all of them from long ago. Peter and I joined the Board staff in
September 1965, when Pat Hendershott and Bob Parry also joined. At least in terms of
longevity, that was a pretty significant hiring month. I remember being on a panel with Dick
at an academic conference in those days. He had not yet joined the Board, being an assistant
professor at Ohio State. Being thoroughly a Michigan man now, I probably should not admit
it, but I also met him, along with Dave Lindsey, when I interviewed for a job at Ohio State.
The job interview didn't pan out, I think mainly on my side but perhaps on theirs too.
I also knew Dale back then. He joined the Board shortly after I left, but I met him socially in
the early 1970s. Frankly, I still remember one thing he said to me. When I mentioned that I
used to be on the Board's staff, he said he knew--he had read some of my stuff. "Well," I
said expectantly. "Oh, some of it's OK," he said. With his subsequent international exposure,
Dale has gotten much more diplomatic over the years.
All three principals have made great contributions to economic modeling at the Board. Peter
started with optimal control techniques and distributed lags, and continued with rational
expectations estimation procedures. Dick's work focused on money demand and monetary
control techniques. Dale was instrumental in developing the Board's global model. All three
have generally promoted research at the Board, helped younger scholars get established,
sponsored working paper series, and fought for better computers and other support.
As for the models themselves, the topic of the conference, I feel like Rip Van Winkle. In the
very early days, 1965-70, I was here and indeed right in the middle of the producer side of
the model work. Then I went off and did other things for twenty-seven years, returning in
1997 as a consumer of models. Things changed a lot in those twenty-seven years.
Most of you are reasonably familiar with what the model looks like now. But apart from the
real graybeards, the three principals and I, most of you were probably in grade school when
this work actually started. Let me recall a few stories from the old days.
The main motivator at the Board in those days was Frank de Leeuw. For all who knew
Frank, he was one of the most "market undervalued" economists of all time. All the young
people at the Fed then felt he walked on water. Frank formed a team of economists here-Tinsley, Hendershott, Al Tella, and me among others--and an academic team featuring the
late Franco Modigliani from MIT and the late Albert Ando from Penn. Bob Rasche, now
research director at the St. Louis Fed, and Harold Shapiro, later to be my university

president at Michigan, were also junior professors at Penn and part of the team. Jerry Enzler,
whom many of you remember fondly, as I do, was somewhere in transition, starting as a
Penn graduate student and moving to the Board staff, where he too stayed many years.
The model we put together in those days has been enshrined in publications and I won't
describe it much. It probably had about the coverage of the present day FRBUS, and it had
many of the then exotic channels of monetary policy. There was a consumption-wealth
effect working through equity values and housing values, and both of those prices were
endogenous. At one point, Franco got one of his graduate students, a lively kid named Larry
Meyer, to do his thesis on this link. There was a foreign sector, but exchange rates were
exogenous because we had pegged rates back then. There was also a credit-rationing
channel based largely on the work of another Franco graduate student, Dwight Jaffee, who
is now an authority on government-sponsored enterprises at Berkeley.
What we didn't have in those days was forward-looking expectations behavior. In qualitative
terms we all knew the difference between adaptive and rational expectations, but nobody
knew how to estimate rational expectations equations. This is one area where technical work
over the years has made a large difference, and I gather that several people in the room,
especially Peter Tinsley, have been responsible. In more immediate terms, the aspect of the
model that still recalls frustration was that whenever we ran dynamic full-model
simulations, the simulations would blow up. I can't tell you how many hours Jerry Enzler
and I spent feeding in our regression cards, and our simulation cards, to work on this issue.
Yes, we fed in punch cards in those days. Nowadays when Board economists present the
results of dynamic simulations in briefings, and the simulations look very reasonable, I think
I am one of the few people in the room who is deeply impressed.
Doctrinal historians will have fun with the naming of this model. Whenever Board people
wrote about it, it was the Fed-MIT model, or perhaps the Fed-MIT-Penn model. When Ando
wrote it became the MPS model--MIT-Penn-Social Science Research Council model. All
the Social Science Research Council did was to give Ando a grant. And where was the Fed?
We did do a lot of the early work on the model.
A number of people have raised questions about monetary and fiscal policy itself in the
1960s--how could policy have been so misguided? First off, let me say that the modeling
group was quite aware of the natural rate hypothesis then. We knew that an adaptive
expectations Phillips Curve would explode if the lag coefficient was one--we just couldn't
get its estimated value to be one. We had yet to apply Kalman filters or other split-sample
techniques and were yet to realize the problems with the sum of the lagged coefficients test.
But even apart from lag effects, as papers by Bill Poole (another Division of Research and
Statistics staff member from those days), George de Menil (another Franco student), and
Jerry Enzler show, our nonlinear Phillips Curves became very, very steep at low
unemployment rates, implying that inflation would become uncontrollable at low
unemployment rates.
On the point Athanasios Orphanides raises about the value of the natural rate, we probably
were wrong about that. I remember being stunned by a Bob Hall paper in the 1970s that
placed the natural rate at about 5 percent. By the way, in the mid-1970s Franco began
calling this rate NIRU, and later Jim Tobin, I think, switched it over to NAIRU.
But the main problems with policy in those days were, um, with the policymakers. First off,

presidential interference on discount rate policy got the discount rate set below the funds
rate in 1965, a problem we never fixed until two years ago. I think this artificially low
discount rate may have held down the funds rate, leading to the overly expansionary
monetary policy amply documented by John Taylor. It was obvious to virtually all
economists that the country needed a permanent budget shift as Vietnam spending
increased, but what came out of that was a delayed temporary tax increase. Anything else
would have made the war less popular, and by then the Vietnam War was pretty darn
unpopular. Quite possibly, our intellectual understanding was not where it should have been
in the late 1960s, but 90 percent of the policy problems were political, with the
policymakers themselves.
These days the Board staff makes a baseline forecast and grafts on FRBUS to get the results
for alternative scenarios. We actually began to do these types of experiments once our
model was put together in the late 1960s. I was dying to present the results to the Board, but
never could get past Lyle Gramley, our sponsor but also our gatekeeper. He didn't trust the
model enough when it was used as a pure forecasting device. Then, as I suppose now, we
had the most trouble forecasting equipment investment--most of the other final demand
sectors worked pretty well. The investment accelerator was also the reason our dynamic
simulations ran off-track. When we would suspend the investment equation, things would
work reasonably well. I have heard the modern day staff complain about estimating an
accelerator effect for equipment and software and, believe me, I am sympathetic.
Another place where the intervening years have made a real difference is the way in which
the baseline forecast itself was put together. In our day it was totally anticipations data-leading indicators of this or that, for a quarter or two ahead at most. Today I hear Dave
Stockton describe the baseline forecast in very model-oriented terms--this effect, that
coefficient, and so forth. Nowadays the baseline forecast also runs out a few years,
something the judgmental forecasters of earlier days would never have attempted, and it
even has measures of forecast uncertainty. All of these are real improvements, far beyond
what was done in the 1960s.
For me, this work all came to an end in May 1970. At the time I felt we had brought the
model as far as I thought we could bring it, at least for a while, and I really wanted to do
some other kind of economics. Whether the external pastures were in fact greener I will
never know--they just seemed greener at the time. So I left the Board staff, confident that I
would never return either to the Board or to large-scale macro modeling. But sure enough,
there were some other twists of fate and here I am, back, as a model consumer. And, I think,
an ideal consumer because I realize how hard it is to do this kind of work.
Return to top
2004 Speeches
Home | News and events
Accessibility | Contact Us
Last update: March 25, 2004