View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Remarks by Governor Edward M. Gramlich
Second Annual Robert J. Lampman Memorial Lecture, University of Wisconsin,
Madison
June 16, 1999

A Policy in Lampman's Tradition: The Community Reinvestment Act
It is a pleasure to speak at the Lampman symposium. I first met Bob nearly three decades
ago. At the time I was a young economist in the process of switching jobs from working on
macroeconomics at the Federal Reserve Board to working on poverty problems at the Office
of Economic Opportunity (OEO). In those days OEO was the main funder of Wisconsin's
Institute for Research on Poverty (IRP), and Bob was of course the intellectual mainstay of
IRP. Time has marched on, and I am now back at the Fed, ironically working on both macro
and poverty issues at the same time.
Bob used to promote his anti-poverty agenda in two parts. The first was to ensure "high
levels of employment and increasing average product per worker." This is, of course, one of
the fundamental mandates of the Fed, and we are trying to achieve the objective daily. One
often reads about these efforts in the newspapers, and there is little more about them that I
want to say today. The second was "special private and public programs for those groups
who do not readily share in the benefits of economic progress."1 It turns out that the Fed
administers a very important program of this type as well, the Community Reinvestment Act
(CRA). This is the program I would like to speak about today. Although to my knowledge
Bob never studied the program, I think he would be very interested in the act.
CRA began back in 1977 as a little-known bank law, responding to reports of redlining and
other credit market distortions. Based on the charters of banks and savings and loan
associations, which require these financial institutions to meet the convenience and needs of
the communities they serve, the CRA specifically encourages institutions to serve the credit
needs of low- and moderate-income borrowers in their communities. The financial
regulatory agencies grade financial institutions on their CRA performance, the grades are
made public, and the institutions' CRA records are to be considered by the regulators in
assessing proposed mergers and acquisitions.
The actual number of mergers denied by the regulators because of CRA problems is small,
but the act has acquired much more importance and visibility than numbers alone would
suggest. On the political side, it has become a major bone of contention in discussions about
new financial reform legislation. On the economic side, it seems to have been responsible
for about $120 billion annually in loans to low- and moderate- income homeowners, small
businesses, small farms, and community development activities. Though some of these
loans would no doubt have been made in the absence of CRA, and some may not benefit
low-income groups disproportionately, $120 billion is a lot of money, far more than was
ever contemplated for anti-poverty programs back in Bob's heyday.

Most poverty scholars are studying changes in the income support system in this country,
but the impact of credit market programs such as CRA could be just as important in
influencing the long-term economic prospects of low- and moderate-income groups. The
University of Wisconsin has been a leader in studying social and poverty problems for a
long time now, beginning with John R. Commons and Edmund Witte, continuing through
Lampman and then up to the other leading present day IRP researchers. The ultimate point
of my talk here today is to encourage you modern-day poverty scholars to get interested in
credit market programs such as CRA. The impact of this program is likely to be significant,
and social scientists interested in fields such as anti-poverty policy, urban development, and
social policy should focus research attention on it.
How CRA Works
The CRA encourages financial institutions to make housing and business loans to low- and
moderate-income borrowers in low- and moderate-income neighborhoods within their
communities, or assessment areas in the language of the law. Larger institutions must satisfy
a lending test focusing on their mortgage, small business, and community development
lending; an investment test focusing on their grants for and equity participations in
community development activities; and a service test focusing on branch location and the
availability of normal banking services to low- and moderate-income groups.
The law is administered by the federal regulatory agencies that already supervise the
relevant financial institutions--the Fed, the Office of Comptroller of the Currency (OCC),
and the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) for banks and the Office of Thrift
Supervision (OTS) for savings and loan associations. These regulatory agencies examine
and rate financial institutions every two or three years, giving grades of outstanding,
satisfactory, needs improvement, and substantial noncompliance. There has been evolution
of the testing criteria and grade distribution over time, but today the following grade
distribution has become characteristic:
z
z
z
z

Outstanding--about 20 percent of the cases
Satisfactory--about 75 percent of the cases
Needs Improvement--less than 5 percent of the cases
Substantial Noncompliance--rarely

Staff from the regulatory agencies meet frequently to try to standardize their CRA criteria
and ratings as much as possible.
All CRA ratings are made public, and low ratings can be used by the regulatory agencies to
block mergers and acquisitions, providing the real teeth in the CRA law. In addition to the
formal CRA ratings, there is a public comment period for mergers and acquisitions, and in
many cases a public meeting. If some point about the applicant's CRA record is raised in
either the comment period or a public meeting, the agencies try to assess the validity of the
claim objectively. Given the rating distribution above, it is rare that mergers are actually
blocked because of low CRA ratings or negative public comments, but the publicity is
certainly not good, and the great majority of financial institutions try hard to establish good
CRA records--probably the main reason for the high CRA grades. It also, of course, means
that we might expect CRA to be responsible for a significant amount of lending activity.
The biggest component of CRA loans is for mortgages to low- and moderate- income
borrowers. There are detailed reporting requirements for mortgages made to these and other

borrowers under the Home Mortgage Disclosure Act (HMDA). In 1997, the 10,000
commercial banks and savings and loan associations subject to this act made about 1.1
million new loans to low- and moderate-income homeowners or to those living in low- and
moderate-income Census tracts in their communities. According to Fed staff research, the
aggregate volume of these mortgage loans made under CRA in 1997 was about $58 billion,
a total that has remained roughly stable through the 1990s.
The other main component of CRA lending is for small businesses and farms. The formal
statistics from the Federal Financial Institutions Examination Council (FFIEC) peg the
aggregate amount of new small business loans in 1997 at $159 billion, but the Fed staff
estimates that only about one-fourth of these loans, $41 billion, were made as a result of
CRA. Adding in another $18 billion of community development loans, we get an aggregate
of $117 billion of these loans made under CRA for 1997, with similar totals for other recent
years.
Nobody has studied these totals carefully enough to generate counterfactual evidence--that
is, what share of these loans would have been made in the absence of CRA. Nevertheless,
the fact that the CRA law was passed in response to fears of redlining and other barriers to
credit in low- and moderate-income areas, and the eagerness of financial institutions to
receive CRA credit for their low-income lending, suggests that a large share of the loans
probably would not have been made in the absence of CRA.2 The econometrics are still
unclear, but the law certainly could have been responsible for a sizable amount of new
lending, dwarfing the expenditures on any other poverty program--in Lampman's day and
today.
Perhaps as significant as the numbers themselves are the activities that take place. While
there is a wide range of such activities, the prototype CRA project features a community
group supplying the entrepreneurship and organizational capability. This group may procure
some cheap vacant land from the city, obtain other grants or funds for construction or
rehabilitation of housing units, and then sell the units to lower-income homeowners. The
mortgages on the properties will be made by banks or savings and loan associations, which
get CRA credit for these loans. The community group will take funds from the sale of the
new homes and roll them over into a revolving loan fund. The bank or savings and loan will
often sell the mortgage to some secondary buyer, often a government-sponsored enterprise
such as Fannie Mae or Freddie Mac. These transactions take place roughly at market prices,
however, so it makes sense to give the originating unit the CRA credit for the loan. Fannie
Mae and Freddie Mac will then securitize the mortgages and sell them privately.
The repayment experience has generally been very good for CRA loans. Confidential data
for one large but anonymous mortgage lender give a cumulative three-year foreclosure rate
of 2.3 percent for loans that were likely to be made under CRA.3 This is an overestimate of
the annual loss rate on CRA loans because the foreclosure rate is for the first three years
after the loan and because on average only about half the value of the loan to the lender is
lost at foreclosure. The Fed staff estimates that annual loss rates on CRA loans over the
1993-97 period are on the order of one-third of 1 percent. The aggregate annual loss rate on
the $282 billion CRA mortgage loans over this five-year period is .0039; the aggregate
annual loss rate on the $191 billion in CRA small business loans over this period is .0035.
There is no evidence that the loss rate for CRA small business loans is any higher than the
loss rate for other (non-CRA) small business loans, though there is evidence that the loss
rate on CRA mortgage loans is slightly higher than the extremely low loss rate on non-CRA

mortgage loans.
These low loan loss rates, when combined with some slight loan subsidies by many financial
institutions, imply that CRA loans are nearly as profitable as other loans. A survey of large
residential mortgage lenders showed that 98 percent of these lenders found CRA loans
profitable, with 24 percent finding them as or more profitable than other loans.4 Hard
evidence is difficult to come by, but the profitability of CRA loans could be rising over time
as lenders learn more about screening and credit-scoring for this segment of the population
and as new opportunities arise for secondary market sales.
Given the rapid rise in bankruptcy filings in recent years, it is natural to wonder if CRAinduced expansions of credit are not partly to blame. The evidence weighs in against the
hypothesis. Again, the Fed staff has looked into the matter and attributes, at most, 3 to 4
percent of overall bankruptcy losses to CRA loans. Moreover, the time patterns differ.
While overall bankruptcy filings and chargeoffs for consumer credit cards and other loans
have increased sharply since 1995, CRA loan losses have been low and stable throughout
the 1990s.
Questions Regarding CRA
While CRA definitely promotes programs that are popular with those actually trying to
arrange credit for low- and moderate-income borrowers, a number of questions could be
raised about it. Some of these concern the operation of the law; some concern its ultimate
impact. Many of these questions reflect the fact that CRA simply has not been studied much
by researchers. For the rest of the lecture I discuss a number of interesting research
questions that have developed about CRA. Some of these research leads may be difficult or
impossible to pursue; some may prove very fruitful. At this point, I am just trying to get
researchers to start up their engines.
Structure of the Law
As noted above, the main leverage of CRA is through its impact on the review of proposed
mergers. Financial institutions are graded on their CRA performance, and their CRA records
are examined in the merger process. Although institutions can be held liable for lending
discrimination under the Equal Credit Opportunity Act, they cannot be held liable for poor
CRA records per se. Superficially, this would seem to aim CRA only at institutions
intending to merge at some point, not at those that may have poor CRA records but have no
plans to merge. From a social point of view, one would then expect there to be excessive
scrutiny of merging institutions with good CRA records, and insufficient scrutiny of
institutions with no plans to merge but with poor CRA records.
Since about 95 percent of these institutions generally receive passing CRA grades -outstanding or satisfactory--one would expect about 90 percent of the mergers between two
randomly chosen institutions to be approved without a detailed CRA review. In fact, more
than 99 percent were. The Treasury Department reports that of the 86,000 merger
applications filed since 1985, there were only 755 CRA protests.5 In these protested cases,
690 mergers were approved, and only 65 were denied on CRA grounds, a rejection rate
of .0008.
One can get more detailed information from the Federal Reserve, one of the regulatory
agencies included in the above statistics. Over 1993-97, the Fed considered an average of
1,100 merger cases a year in which the merging institution was subject to CRA. In 1,030 of

these cases the merger was approved without a CRA protest. In the remaining 70 cases,
issues serious enough to trigger a detailed CRA review were raised. Sometimes there were
CRA protests raised in writing or in public meetings held to discuss the potential merger.
Sometimes the issue involved the CRA rating itself. Sometimes the issue involved an
alleged fair-lending problem or some other compliance matter. In each instance the Board
staff would analyze the case and bring a recommendation to the Board. During this period
there was an average of only one denial per year based primarily on CRA, but in another
seven cases per year the application was withdrawn, perhaps for CRA-related reasons. In
factual terms, then, mergers were disapproved in somewhere between one and eight cases
out of 1,100.
These numbers do not make the CRA test look very formidable, but that impression is
belied by other considerations. One is the simple amount of lending, and the share of banks
with good CRA records. Both sets of facts suggest either that the CRA test is stronger than it
looks or that banks are increasingly finding it in their own interest to do CRA-type lending.
Another consideration is the organizational impact of CRA. Many banks devote significant
resources to their CRA efforts, often creating special divisions to manage their CRA
projects. Bank personnel work very hard on their CRA submissions, and regulatory
personnel work very hard on their examinations. Often, potentially merging banks make
substantial prospective CRA lending commitment agreements with community groups, even
though the Fed and other regulatory agencies have often stated that they go only by the past
record, not by any prospective CRA agreements.
These CRA agreements have caused some problems in and of themselves because there are
allegations that community groups "hold up" banks by threatening to file protests or to
speak against them at public meetings unless they sign CRA agreements. Given the
announced stance of the regulatory agencies--that the regulators look only at past CRA
records and not at future agreements--it is puzzling that community group threats, if indeed
they are made, should have such power over banks.
In the end, coming to a judgment about the structure of the CRA law is difficult. On one
side, the present structure does seem to have been effective at getting a wide range of
financial institutions to pay serious attention to low- and moderate-income credit needs,
buttressed by government examinations but not by a costly CRA legal enforcement process.
The law has certainly opened up a dialogue between financial institutions and community
groups, and it seems to have opened up profitable new lending opportunities to low- and
moderate-income borrowers--opportunities that financial institutions may not have
discovered without the push of federal legislation. On the other side, there may well be more
focus than is socially optimal on banks in position to merge, as opposed to being in position
to improve lending practices to the benefit of low- and moderate-income groups. There may
also be gaps in the coverage of CRA across lending markets--not all markets may be served
by financial institutions subject to CRA. Scholars interested in government regulations
should study CRA to see what can be learned about desirable ways to regulate financial
activities.
Predatory Lending
Many businesses have their less-than-noble side, and the subprime lending business does as
well. While many new loans are now being made to low- and moderate- income borrowers,
there are at the same time numerous reports of predatory or fraudulent lending practices,
common fare for exposé-type TV programs.

Because competition in providing credit to low- and moderate-income borrowers is still
limited, it may be possible for unscrupulous lenders to give superficially attractive terms on
loans. Loans for home repairs or debt consolidation might give cash up front to cash-poor
borrowers but carry high interest rates, high fees, unnecessary insurance, and repayment
terms that make the repayment schedules difficult to meet down the road. Loans may also
feature balloon payments that end up forcing borrowers into default or refinancing, at still
more unfavorable terms.
Many such dubious practices are reported. Loan sales people are reported to search
neighborhoods for low-income but high-equity borrowers, often elderly, starved for cash
and barely literate. There are reports of deceptive advertising, excessive fees, sales of
useless insurance (credit life insurance for borrowers with no dependents, disability
insurance for retirees, credit insurance that exceeds the loan balance), high penalty
payments, and even of outright forgeries on loan forms. These reports indicate that
borrowers are unwittingly led to rapid turnover of home equity loans--a process known as
"loan flipping"--with high finance charges every time. As borrowers pay the fees and get
even more cash-starved, the equity they have built up in their homes over a long period of
time gets reduced--a process known as "equity stripping."
While there are reports of outright frauds and forgeries, the more common problem seems to
be plain old deception. If borrowers were careful, financially astute, and had good
counseling, these loans would rarely be entered into, and fraudulent lending should not be
much of a problem. But this is a segment of the borrowing population that can be trusting, is
often illiterate about credit matters, and is potentially vulnerable.
Knowing what to do about the problem is a major public policy challenge. Often the
reported abuses revolve around refinancing of homes and balloon payments. There are
plenty of borrowers out there who greatly benefit from such credit arrangements, so it makes
no sense to outlaw the practices altogether. Earlier there were attempts to limit high loan
charges such as interest rates with usury laws, but these just prevent mutually advantageous
transactions between knowledgeable lenders and borrowers and cause credit to dry up when
general levels of interest rates rise. Better disclosure laws might help, but disclosure forms
are already complex with much fine print, and the supposed readers of these forms often
cannot understand them and sometimes cannot even read.
In response to earlier reports of fraudulent lending, the Congress in 1994 passed the Home
Ownership Equity Protection Act (HOEPA). HOEPA prevented balloon payments in the
first five years of a loan--hence limiting early loan-flipping but perhaps taking even further
advantage of myopic borrowers. It also defined a class of "high cost" loans, loans that
charge closing fees of 8 points or more, or have an annual percentage interest rate 10
percentage points above prevailing Treasury rates. For these HOEPA-protected loans there
are thorough disclosure requirements and prohibitions of some practices that often lead to
abuses. What has happened is that many lenders have skated just below the HOEPA
requirements, there has continued to be rapid growth of subprime lending, and there are
continued reports of predatory lending.
The connection between CRA and predatory lending is potentially quite interesting and, at
this point, is not very clear. There may be very little connection. Or there is a possibility that
CRA might inadvertently foster predatory lending because institutions subject to CRA can
receive credit for lending to low- and moderate-income borrowers regardless of the terms of

the loan. Or CRA could limit predatory practices, by bringing more competition to low- and
moderate-income credit markets. Predatory lending would be held in check if there were
true competition in these markets, where even low-income and vulnerable borrowers had a
real choice of borrowing possibilities and clear explanations of lending terms. By
encouraging banks to get into these markets--banks that are subject to regulation, that use
standard loan packages, that are used to working with community groups, and that have a
CRA service test--CRA might be a force for the good.
But this whole set of issues has not been studied much by researchers. It would first of all be
desirable to find out just how widespread the predatory practices are: The only remotely
quantifiable information on this score is now from data on legal actions.6 It would be helpful
to understand the low- and moderate-income lending process better, to determine the
conditions under which predatory lending can and cannot thrive. It would be helpful to
identify the role of competition, or the lack of it, in the predatory lending process. And it
would be helpful to determine the role of CRA in bringing about better competition.
Different geographic areas could be studied, with different concentrations of vulnerable
borrowers and different intensities of CRA activities, to answer some of these questions.
The Overall Impact of CRA
In the end what is important about CRA is its effect on society. With something as
complicated as a credit program, there could be many types of effects. Here are a few of the
possibilities.
A first question is the relatively straightforward one of determining the impact of CRA on
low- and moderate-income lending. CRA seems to have had a large effect, but perhaps not
as much as the gross figures would indicate because some of this lending would have taken
place without CRA. The growth of subprime lending by institutions not covered by CRA is
one such indication.7 On the other side, having been shown the way by banks, a number of
nonfinancial corporations are now getting into the community lending business, a factor that
might be counted in favor of CRA. Researchers could try to understand these loan statistics
better. How much new lending is truly due to CRA? Has CRA inspired nonbank lending, or
has bank and nonbank subprime lending grown for similar reasons? What are the properties
of this lending, and what is the impact of CRA on underserved segments of the credit
market?
A second question involves the impact of CRA on lending discrimination. CRA was passed
largely in response to allegations of discrimination, redlining, and more general concerns
about unequal access to credit in different areas. It is now more than twenty years since that
time, and four years since the CRA testing criteria were fine-tuned to focus particularly on
low- and moderate-income lending in low- and moderate- income areas. What has
happened? There is evidence that the amount of loans to low- and moderate-income
borrowers has risen, but is there evidence that lending discrimination is reduced, or that
housing neighborhoods are more integrated?8 It would again seem that CRA has been
around long enough that these types of evaluation studies could be done.
A third question involves the impact of CRA on financial evolution. Many CRA
arrangements are very elaborate, with either outright gifts of urban properties from the city
or city funds for land acquisition and development, funds from foundations and private
developers, and CRA-type lending from financial institutions. Community groups that
formerly would have been either agitating or running small local programs have become

financial entrepreneurs--putting together deals, working with city bureaucracies and banks,
even wearing charcoal grey suits. Similarly, city bureaucracies have changed and know how
to work with these groups, and many banks now have community development divisions. It
would seem that this sort of financial institution-building would be profoundly important,
but at this point the changes and their effects are largely observed anecdotally. Putting
rigorous form on all of these developments is a very challenging research task, but there
may be big institutional changes out there, and one would like to think that social science
researchers would have something to say about them.
A fourth question involves the impact of CRA on overall credit markets. Lenders are now
perfecting analytic techniques such as credit-scoring that permit and facilitate identification
of good credit risks among the low-income population. Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac have
developed their own financial models to provide a functioning secondary market for the
mortgage loans, without which the primary lenders would do much less lending.
Researchers at the Fed and government-sponsored enterprises have already begun to
understand the effects of these changes on credit markets.9 But there is more to do, both in
understanding the impact of credit-scoring and in developing improved scoring techniques.
The fifth question seems most important of all, the impact of CRA on economic
development. As one tours the country and visits projects partially or fully funded under
CRA, there are clear suggestions of success. In some cities there seems to be a visual
difference between neighborhoods with and without CRA projects--the houses look better,
housing occupancy is more complete, the neighborhoods are neater. But these impressions
are superficial and nonsystematic. One would think it possible to examine Census tract
housing records, or city property value records, to do formal comparison studies of CRA
and non-CRA activity areas in the same city, or pre- and post-CRA activities. Again, many
of these projects are old enough now that if there were differences in property values, home
ownership, school attendance, crime rates, teen pregnancy rates, or whatever, these
differences should be showing up by now. The law is ultimately designed to improve urban
and rural life on these dimensions, and at some point scholars should take on the question of
ascertaining whether it really does so.
Conclusion
In this talk I have tried to acquaint researchers with an important law and to stimulate
academic thinking and research on it. The CRA law is two decades old now, apparently
responsible for a great deal of lending, at least in the 1990s. Many cities have CRA projects
that look lively and vital, and of which the cities and their banks are justifiably proud. But
unlike many interesting public programs that are studied to death before they even get off
the ground, the CRA law has gotten well off the ground, but has been very little studied. It is
time for the researchers to take note. The University of Wisconsin researchers could lead
others into these fertile and interesting areas, as they have led researchers to so many other
important social topics throughout the past century.

Footnotes
1 Both quotes are taken from Robert J. Lampman, The Low Income Population and
Economic Growth, Study Paper No. 12, U.S. Congress, Joint Economic Committee
(Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1959).

2 Suggests, but does not prove. There is a developing debate on the issue. On one side,
Jeffery W. Gunther, Kelly Klemme, and Kenneth J. Robinson, "Redlining or Red Herring,"
Southwest Economy, May/June 1999, Issue 3, pp. 8-13, argue that credit market barriers to
low-income lending have been breaking down anyway, and that CRA has not played much
of a role in the process. On the other side, Douglas O. Evanoff and Lewis M. Segal, "CRA
and Fair Lending Regulations: Resulting Trends in Mortgage Lending," Economic
Perspectives, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 1997, pp. 19-43, find evidence that the
recent increase in mortgage lending to low- and moderate-income groups was due to CRA.
3 Michael LaCour-Little, "Does the Community Reinvestment Act Make Mortgage Credit
More Widely Available? Some Evidence Based on Performance of CRA Mortgage Credits,"
Mimeo, May 4, 1998. LaCour-Little also attributes a large role to CRA in the growth of
low- and moderate-income mortgage lending.
4 Larry Meeker and Forest Myers, "Community Reinvestment Act Lending: Is it
Profitable?" Financial Industry Perspectives, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, 1996,
pp. 13-45. This finding is supported by Robert B. Avery, Raphael W. Bostic, Paul S. Calem,
and Glenn B. Canner, "Credit Risk, Credit-Scoring, and the Performance of Home
Mortgages," Federal Reserve Bulletin, July 1996, pp. 621-48.
5 Treasury Department release, May 4, 1999.
6 Luxman Nathan, "Borrower Beware: Equity Strippers Are Preying on Elderly
Homeowners," Compensation and Banking, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, Spring 1999,
pp. 6-18.
7 Gunther, Klemme, and Robinson, "Redlining or Red Herring." The Shadow Committee on
bank regulatory policy has the same skepticism--see George J. Benston, "Discrimination in
Mortgage Lending: Why HMDA and CRA Should Be Repealed," Journal of Retail Banking
Services, Volume 19, No. 3, Autumn 1997, pp. 47-57.
8 Helen Ladd, "Evidence on Discrimination in Mortgage Lending," The Journal of
Economic Perspectives, Spring 1998, Volume 12, No. 2, pp. 41-62, summarizes the recent
evidence on housing discrimination.
9 Robert B. Avery, Raphael W. Bostic, Paul S. Calem, and Glenn B. Canner, "Credit Risk,
Credit-Scoring, and the Performance of Home Mortgages."
Return to top
1999 Speeches
Home | News and events
Accessibility | Contact Us
Last update: June 16, 1999, 5:30 PM