View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Talk by Dr. Edison H. Cramer, Chief of. the Division of Research and Statistics
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, October 2, 1950, Milwaukee, Wisconsin

BUSINESS INSTABILITY: CAUSE AND REMEDY
For some time the attention of the entire nation has been
focused on the conflict, in part a cold war and in part a hot one, between
the communist bloc of nations and the rest of the world.
conflict has two important phases.

This worldwide

In part it results from an attempt

by one nation to extend its domination over the globe.

All previous

attempts of this sort have eventually failed, although some of them have
been successful over wide areas for substantial periods of time.

The other

aspect of this great struggle is a conflict between two contrasting types of
economic organization, the individualism and capitalism of Western Europe
and the United States on the one hand, and the centralized governmental
control of a totalitarian state on the other.

This phase of the conflict

is a rivalry between two very different methods of organizing people and
of handling the capital and resources used in producing goods and services
to meet national and individual needs.
If this worldwide conflict were solely a question as to what
nation is to be the dominant power of the world the result would depend
upon military planning and strategy and the ability to provide the
implements of war.

In view of the fact that the struggle involves far

more than military dominance the final outcome will probably depend upon
the question of whether private enterprise or centralized government
proves to be the more acceptable method of organizing economic activity.
This liklihood is strengthened by the fact that the leaders of the
communist group of nations are convinced that capitalism is inherently
unstable and that the economic system of the United States will be so weakened




- 2

by recurrent periods of inflation and depression that it will inevitably
collapse.

Because of this belief, the Soviet leaders are likely to

depend primarily upon continuation of the cold war with the United States,
combined with military campaigns by their satellites when favorable
opportunities occur, rather than to initiate a worldwide hot war in the
immediate future.
The belief that capitalism is inherently unstable and subject
to frequent depression, while a communistic society is not, is held not
only by communists but also by many economists who abhor communism.
There are two important reasons for this belief.

One of these is the

historical fact that during the past two centuries the economy of the
United States and that of Western Europe have both been subject to frequent
breakdowns during which millions of people were without work in the midst of
vast productive powers and unused resources and millions more found their
incomes dwindling because of collapse of the prices of the goods which
they were producing.'

The other reason for the belief that capitalism is

inherently unstable has its roots in the difference between the mechanism
of decision making and coordination in a centralized totalitarian system
and in a competitive private enterprise system.

In a totalitarian state

basic plans and decisions are made by a few people and the means by which
these plans and decisions are coordinated are obvious in the character
of the governmental machinery.

In a competitive private enterprise

economy decisions regarding production plans and the operations of
factories and other types of producing enterprises are made by a multitude
of persons, either on their own account as individual businessmen or as
officers of business enterprises.




Isn’t it inevitable, some people ask,

-'

3

-

that these plans and decisions will be poorly coordinated and that they
result from time to time in the kind of a business mess we call a depression?
The question does indeed arise as to how the multitude of
decisions by hundreds of thousands of separate business enterprises
are coordinated so that there is a reasonable degree of order in the
economic system.

To see how this coordination does take place we need

to look at business arrangements for the purchase of materials, the
hiring of labor, and the sale of goods and services.

Those arrangements,

or contracts, are made in terms of prices and promises to make payments
in money.

The prices represent the number of units of money, in the

form of currency or of checks on a bank account, which will be paid for a
given amount of materials or labor or a given quantity of goods or
services.

The system of prices which these contracts produce becomes

a kind of impersonal central regulator of the economy.

If businessmen

make inappropriate decisions and base their contracts upon them they
find that their goods remain unsold or can be sold only at a loss.

They

discover that types of goods which are comparatively scarce command
relatively high prices. Consequently the prospect of making profits as
a result of producing such goods acts as a force inducing businessmen
to shift labor and materials from making other types of goods from which
the prospective profits are less.
The prices which eventually govern these decisions of business­
men are those which individuals are willing to pay for the final products
of the economy.

As economists have often remarked, consumers cast their

votes for some goods and services and against others as they go shopping




- k~

every day in the market places.

Thus the choices and decisions not

merely of business enterprises hut of all the people, expressed as
preferences in the market, produce a price system which becomes the
governor or regulator of production.
As we think about the importance of the price system the
question arises in our minds as to whether this intricate mechanism
may sometimes get out of order.

We know also from experience that in

depression, as in a time of inflation, the price system does not seem
to function well.

Perhaps depression and inflation are results of a

distorted price system.

Certainly it is worth while to examine the

hypothesis that the economic disorders of inflation and of depression
are due to great disturbances in the price system.
In making an examination of this hypothesis we may start with
the fundamental economic principle, the law of supply and demand, and
ask the question:

Is this principle applicable only to the various

types of goods and services which are bought and sold in the economy, or
is it applicable also to the circulating medium or money which is used
in making payments and fulfilling contracts?
question is yes.

The answer to the latter

When money is in great supply relative to the need for

it, as measured in an appropriate manner, it tends to fall in value and
each unit becomes worth less and less in buying goods and services; if
money becomes scarce relative to the need, it tends to rise in value and
fewer units will be required to buy a suit of clothes, an automobile, or
a television set.

That is to say, a decline in the value of money due to

an excessive increase in its quantity is the same as a general rise in
prices.

This is what we call inflation.




Similarly, a rise in the value

- 5 -

of money due to a decrease in its'quantity is simply another way of
describing a general fall or deflation of prices.

Neither inflation nor deflation occurs instantaneously.

In

each case some prices go up or down and this produces pressure on other
prices.

Moreover, many prices are fixed by contract or custom or for

other reasons are rigid and do not move readily.
in the price structure.

This creates distortions

Generally speaking, in inflation these distortions

are such as to make business unusually profitable and hence to stimulate
businessmen to feverish activity.

Likewise, the distortions of the price

structure during deflation tend to make business unprofitable, whereupon
businessmen find it necessary or at least expedient to reduce their working
forces, thus producing unemployment.
These remarks on the role of the price system as a governor or
regulator of a private enterprise economy, and on the character and
impact of inflation and deflation, lead us back to the problem of business
instability.

If the money supply, which nowadays consists primarily of

bank deposits but also includes the currency which we carry around in
our pockets, does not remain stable in quantity with a reasonable increase
in line with the growth of the economy, occasional periods of inflation
and boom on the one hand, and of deflation and depression on the other, appear
to be inevitable.

Many economists who have studied the operations of our

banking and monetary system have concluded that the banking system has
been responsible in the past for many erratic changes in the money supply,
and that those changes in the quantity of money have been the basic cause
of business instability.

Consequently, they have concluded that maintenance

of monetary stability with a reasonable rate of growth is the key to economic
stability.

I would like to quote here from two books published during the

past few months.



-

6

-

Professor Lloyd W. Mints of the University of Chicago is the
author of a recent hook dealing specifically with the problem of monetary
policy for a competitive society.

"Monetary stabilization," Professor

Mints says, "is needed as one of the rules of a competitive society.

It

is needed to prevent undue fluctuations in the expectations of the business
community.

For this purpose stability in the general level of prices is

the essential requirement." l/
Mr. Ralph G. Hawtrey is probably the foremost English
economist who has studied the relation of banking and monetary policy
to business instability.

He has written several books dealing with this

problem, and has recently rewritten a book on currency and credit which
was first published more than thirty years ago.
of this book with these remarks:

He closes the new edition

"Monetary stability is an essential

condition of the survival of competitive private enterprise.
that economic system is challenged.
merits.

Nowadays

The challenge ought to be met on its

It would be regrettable, not to say, contemptible, if the case

for capitalism went by default because the monetary authorities of the
world do not know how to rise to their responsibilities or to take
advantage of their opportunities."

2/

But though economists who have studied the operations of the
banking system have reached this conclusion, most of the economists who
have been engaged in studying business fluctuations have paid very little
attention to the role of changes in the quantity of money.

Most business

cycle theorists today assume that business booms and depressions originate
1/ Lloyd
Hill Book Co.,
2/ R. G.
and Co., Ltd.,




W. Mints, Monetary Policy for a Competitive Society (McGraw1950), page 171.
Hawtrey, Currency and Credit, fourth edition, (Longmans, Green
1950), page 435 .

in forces outside of the banking system which impinge directly upon
effective demand, and that changes in the quantity of bank deposits and
currency in use are sequential results rather than causal factors in the
ups and downs of business.

Because of this emphasis, the economists who have

engaged in large research projects in the study of business cycles have not
made a careful examination of the factual data to see exactly what the
record of the past shows with respect to changes in the quantity of
money at business cycle peaks and troughs and during the intervening down­
swings and upswings.
Several years ago Clark Warburton, of the staff of the Division
of Research and Statistics of the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation,
began to work on the problem of determining how much deviation from
monetary stability there has been in the United States during the past
thirty years.

He thought we ought to know what an analysis of the record

would show about the relationship of monetary stability and instability to
business fluctuations.

Mr. Warburton*s starting point in this study

was a combination of the two points of view which I have just described.
In his initial hypothesis he did not assume that monetary instability is
the initiating factor in business fluctuations.

On the contrary, he

assumed that business fluctuations of moderate intensity result from
various other forces affecting the demand or supply of some important
segment of the economy.

Such changes in demand, he assumed, tend to

raise or lower the value of products sold and thus to raise or lower
prices, profits and wages in some parts of the economy, and that these
effects then spread to other parts of the economy.




-

8

-

Since the force involved in these fluctuations was assumed to
be outside of the hanking and monetary system, it was also assumed that
that force had no direct immediate effect on the quantity of hank deposits
or supply of money.

However, the reduced spending must he reflected either

in a decline in the money supply, or in the rate of use of money; and it
vas desirable to find out which of these typically occurred in the early
stages of a business recession.

Further, it was plausible to assume that

in a time of reduced spending, whatever the cause, some spending units
would tend to reduce their indebtedness to banks and others would avoid
borrowing which they might have done with better prospects.

Consequently,

a business recession was likely to be accompanied by a contraction in bank
assets and therefore in their deposits.

If this occurred, it would tend to

make recovery from the recession difficult.

The decline in the quantity of

money, in view of customary habits of use of money, would make a decline in
the general price level necessary, so that the downward price adjustments
and discouragement to business in some segments of the economy would occur
without any possibility of compensating upward adjustments in prices and
I

encouragement to business in other segments.
Mr. Warburton’s initial hypothesis continued with the assumption
that shrinkage in the money supply accompanying an ordinary business recession
should not be permitted.

He argued that monetary contraction under this

circumstance is not due to decisions of individuals or business enterprises
to reduce their cash holdings (except momentarily as with any other use
of money), but is an unwanted by-product of retirement of debt to banks, or
perhaps inability to do so with a consequent charge-off by the banks.

If

the process of reduction of debt were not accompanied by its unintended result




-

9

-

of a shrinkage in cash balances we would have the accumulation of idle
cash balances, which would show up statistically in a reduced rate of use
of money in the early stage of a business recession.

Accumulation of idle

money during the downswing would-tend to have an immediate effect upon the
availability of credit and the rate of interest at which money could be
borrowed by business and individuals, and would therefore facilitate a
rapid readjustment to the nonmonetary conditions which had initiated the
recession.

That is to say, Warburton thought that the chief difference

between moderate recessions and severe depressions might be the degree of
monetary contraction which occurs in the downward phase of the cycle, and
if so, this should show up in the statistical data.

Jf the factual record

supported this hypothesis, monetary policy directed toward maintenance of a
normal money supply should prevent the recession phase of a business cycle
from degenerating into a deep depression, and should facilitate rapid recovery.
To scrutinize the factual data relevant to this hypothesis,
statistical series of the average outstanding quantity of money and of its
rate of use were needed for periods sufficiently short to measure changes
during the early and later parts of each business upswing and downswing.
Also, a series was needed which would show the fluctuations in the amount
of spending for final products of the economy.
were then available for any of these series.

No suitable tabulations
When these tabulations were

completed an estimate was made of the rate of growth in the quantity of
money which was needed to maintain a stable price level in view of the
average rate of increase in production over the years and of demonstrated
long-run changes in the rate of use of money.




Fluctuations in the quantity

-

10

and rate of use of money, relative to the trend lines, were then compared
with business cycle peaks and troughs, and with business upswings and
downswings as described in the publications of the National Bureau of

Economic Research.
The re stilts of Warburton’s study conformed only in part with his
initial hypothesis.

The most significant results that he found were these:

First, in almost all of the business cycle peaks and troughs of the past thirty
years, corresponding peaks and troughs occurred in the quantity of money
a few months prior to the business cycle turning points; second, in almost
all of the cases peaks and troughs in the rate of use of money followed by
several months the business cycle peaks and troughs; third, there was a
highly significant relationship between the duration and degree of
departure from trend in the quantity of money and the duration and
amplitude of business upswings and downswings.

In the case of the great

depression, for example, the peak in the money supply was reached a year
before the peak of business in the middle of

1929;

and the subsequent decline

in the quantity of money, except for a few brief interruptions, was continuous
until the banking holiday in the spring of 1933»

The degree of decline was

over 40 percent, relative to the rate of growth estimated to have been
necessary for the people of the country to have purchased the full output
of the economy at a stable level of prices.

The rate of use of money, on

the other hand, did not reach its peak until several months after the
peak in business.

1929

That is to say, the factual record suggests that changes

in the quantity of money lead and thus appear to be an originating force,
and changes in the rate of use of money lag and appear to be only an
accentuating force, in the ups and downs of business. .




11

When these results of examination of the factual data became
evident, Warburton turned to the obvious question:

If an unstable

quantity of money is the leading factor in producing business fluctuations
what force initiates the changes in the quantity of money?

Since bank

deposits form the bulk of the money supply this is a question of what
forces affect bank operations and result in fluctuations in the amount of
bank deposits.

To examine this question Warburton studied the character of

the limitations on bank operations, such as legal requirements regarding
capital and reserves, and reviewed the theory of banking as developed during
the past century.

Without taking the time to go into details regarding the

results of this phase of his investigation, much of which has been
published in professional journals, I will simply say that he has
uncovered what appears to me to be conclusive proof that the quantity of
money need not be erratic*

His conclusion is that the quantity of bank

reserves is the dominant influence on bank deposits, since it is profitable
for banks to maintain their operations close to the limit permitted by
their reserve position; and that since

1917

the amount of reserves

available to the banks is the result of Federal Reserve policy.
The mechanism through which the Federal Reserve System influences
the amount of member bank reserves is that of changes in the volume of assets
of the Federal Reserve banks.

When the Federal Reserve banks acquire

additional assets the effect is an increase in member bank reserve balances
and when they dispose of assets the effect is a decrease in member bank reserve
balances.

Changes in other Federal Reserve bank liabilities, such as the

amount of Federal Reserve notes in circulation, also affect member bank
reserves. However, the Federal Reserve banks have enormous powers of




-

12

-

acquiring additional assets, or of relinquishing assets -which they
hold; and the amount actually acquired, except under rare circumstances,
is dominantly influenced hy the terms of acquisition and relinquishment
set "by the Federal Reserve authorities.

In the history of the Federal

Reserve system since 1917> the only exception to complete control hy Federal
Reserve authorities of the volume of assets of the Federal Reserve hanks,
and hence of the reserves of member hanks, was the period of a few years
following the change in the price of gold, when gold, or certificates of the
Treasury representing gold, came to the Federal Reserve hanks in very large
volume and could not he relinquished hy action of the Federal Reserve officials.
Consequently, Warburton’s study of the forces dominantly influencing the
amount of hank reserves consisted of a review of the operations of the
Federal Reserve hanks since 1917? with special attention to the policies
which produced the peaks and troughs, relative to a reasonable rate of
growth, in effective hank reserves.
Between the two World Wars there were five downswings in business
sufficiently severe to he labeled depressions hy business cycle analysts;
and there were, of course, an equal number of recoveries.
periods of depression—

1921, 192^,

1927>

1929“33 >

Each of the

and 1937-38— was

preceded hy a peak and a downswing in effective hank reserves relative to
the estimated needed rate of growth, and each of the recoveries hy a trough
and upswing in reserves.

The publications of the Federal Reserve System

show the character of the Federal Reserve policies which produced each of
these changes in the amount of effective reserves. To describe these policies
would take much more time than I can use here, hut I would like to make
some comments on postwar developments.




- 13 -

The theory that business fluctuations are the result of inappropriate
variations in the quantity of hank reserves and that these variations in
reserves result from Federal Reserve policies is supported by the course of
events during and since the close of World War II.

In 19^2 Federal Reserve

authorities announced that the System would provide the banks with all the
reserves they might need as a result of increasing their holdings of
Government obligations.

During the war years the banks acquired a huge

volume of Government obligations, and the amount of bank reserves and the
quantity of bank deposits increased rapidly.

Reserves continued to increase,

though more slowly, for two years after V-J day.

From the end of 19^-1

to the end of 19^7 Federal Reserve bank assets nearly doubled, and member
bank reserves, adjusted for changes in percentage requirements and other
factors affecting their effectiveness as a base for deposit expansion, by
about 60 percent.

The money supply, measured by the Federal Reserve series

of "adjusted deposits and currency," more than doubled, a rate of expansion
greater than that in effective reserves being made possible because of
excess reserves available in 19^-1.

This great increase in the money supply

led to some rise in prices during the war and to a rapid rise when wartime
controls were removed.

The wholesale price level rose about two-thirds

and the consumersprice index by about one-half from the first six months of

19^-2

to the first six months of

19^-8,

representing the impact of the excess

of monetary expansion over the growth of production.
In the latter half of 19^7 and the early months of 19^8 various
measures were taken for the purpose of preventing any further increase
in the money supply.
of

19^7

These measures impinged on bank reserves.

By the end

the expansion of bank reserves was halted and turned into contraction.




- Ik Between that date and the end of April 19^9, the effective amount of bank
reserves was reduced by

15

percent relative to the normal rate of growth.

Bank deposits also declined substantially though not by so large a
percentage.

The price level turned down and business activity slackened

in the fall of

19^8,

several, months after the peak in reserves, repeating

the typical sequence and lag which prevailed between the World Wars.
By the Spring of 19^9 fears were arising that a serious postwar
depression was at hand.

At this point the Federal Reserve authorities

reversed their pressure on reserves.

Early in May they started a series

of reductions in percentage reserve requirements, thus stopping the con­
traction in effective reserves and in deposits.

In the summer and autumn

business sentiment became more favorable, several, of the leading indicators
of revival appeared, and fear of a deep depression disappeared.

The Federal

Reserve authorities had stopped the postwar inflation and at the same
time avoided a postwar depression sufficiently deep to be a serious threat
to the economy.
Recently, as those of you who read the financial journals are
aware, the Federal Reserve banks have engaged in a huge double-sided process
of acquiring and relinquishing assets.

On the one hand they acquired a

large portion of the Government obligations which mature on September 15
and October 1, and therefore acquired the right and duty of subscribing to
the refunding issues which the Treasury issued in their place.

On the

other hand, the Federal Reserve banks sold other Government obligations which
they owned, consisting in part of long-term bonds and in part of bills and
certificates maturing subsequent to October 1.

This tremendous turnover

of Government obligations owned by the Federal Reserve banks is the result




- 15 -

of a slight difference "between the rate of interest which is to he paid
on the new obligations and the rate of yield at which the Federal Reserve
banks are offering to sell the various types of obligations which they
previously owned.
With such a tremendous volume of purchases of Government
obligations on one hand and of sales on the other the net results might
very readily have a considerable impact on the amount of member bank
reserves.

However, it appears that the Federal Reserve banks are being

successful in maintaining a high degree of stability in the aggregate
amount of bank reserves.

The figure for member bank reserves on September 20,

the latest date available, was $16.3 billion.

This compares with an average

of the same amount during the month of July and $l6.4 billion during August.
It is about 3^ percent larger than the figure for the corresponding date
in September

19^9,

just after the present percentage reserve requirements

went into effect, though there have been appreciable fluctuations in member
bank reserves between that date and the present time.
If member bank reserves continue to remain reasonably stable,
we can expect stability in the volume of bank assets and bank deposits, and
hence in the money supply.

Mr. Warburton predicts, and I agree with him,

that if this stability is maintained during the next few months the upsurge
in buying by consumers and speculators initiated.by developments in Korea
will subside.

As consumers and speculators meet the commitments they have

already incurred, they will find their cash balances abnormally low relative
to their spendings and will begin to reduce their expenditures to a normal
volume in order to replenish their cash.

If the Federal Reserve authorities

continue to hold bank reserves around the $l6 l /2 billion level, they will




- 16 have demonstrated their ability to prevent inflation, except for some
temporary price fluctuations, even in the face of an increase in defense
expenditures and in the government deficit.
With respect to the longer-run outlook, it has now been a long
enough period of time since the peak in the money supply at the end of
igk'J for the economy to become adjusted to the

$170

billion of "adjusted

deposits and currency" in existence on that date and also at the present
time.

As soon as the present speculative flurry dies down, it would be

an appropriate policy to resume a rate of growth at or close to the
estimated normal, which is about 5 percent per year.

For maintenance of

prosperity and a stable price level we need a reasonable growth in bank
deposits and with appropriate banking and monetary policies this will be
achieved.
That is to say, an economic society based on competitive private
business enterprise is not inherently unstable.

On the contrary, competitive

capitalism is an extremely flexible and adaptable type of economic
organization.

Its decentralization of decision-making is an aid in this

adaptability.

Adjustments to changing demands, to changing methods and

techniques of production, and to changing sources of materials do not
have to be funnelled through a single set of decision-makers.

But there

is one essential condition if this method of decision-making is to work well,
and that is stability in the value of the monetary unit or level of prices
of the output of the economy.

All business decisions are made in terms of

money, and instability in the value of the monetary unit creates vast
uncertainties and upsets business planning.




Maintenance of monetary stability is a governmental function
and the powers of accomplishing it have been given by Congress to the
authorities who determine Federal Reserve policy.

If these powers are

appropriately exercised we will never again have a depression like that
of the

1930*s j

and as time goes by our experience with continuous prosperity

will show the world that we have eliminated the weakness of» our economic
system on which our enemies rely for our defeat in the cold war.

This

is the key to our victory in the cold war and to the survival of liberty,
individualism, and private enterprise.