View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For Release on Delivery
Expected at 9:30 a.m. (EDT)
Tuesday, June 28, 1983




Statement of
E. Gerald Corrigan, President
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
Minneapolis, Minnesota
Before the
Subcommittee on Telecommunications,
Consumer Protection, and Finance
of the
Committee on Energy and Commerce
of the
United States House of Representatives

June 28, 1983

Mr.

Chairman,

I

appreciate the opportunity to appear

before this Subcommittee and share with you some of my personal
observations about emerging trends in the structure of our
banking and financial system and their implications for public
policy.
It seems to me that any discussion of this subject
must start with an appreciation of the historic and ongoing
role that "banks" have played in the day-to-day functioning of
our financial and economic system. It also seems to me that as
we grapple with this very complex and very important subject,
we need a systematic and intellectually consistent framework
for analysis within which we can find solutions that are
reasonable, functional, and that serve the public interest.
As
the Subcommittee knows, I have attempted to provide one such
framework for analysis in my essay, "Are banks special?"
Since
much of what I have to say today draws on that analysis, I
would like to submit that essay, together with
for the record.

this

statement,

Spurred by a variety of factors which need not be
restated here, the pace of financial change and innovation here
in the United States and around much of the industrialized
world has taken on an almost breakneck pace.
Almost daily we
read in the financial press of some event or some development
which seems to challenge one or more aspects of existing law or
regulation or which seems to undermine some aspect of the once
conventional
system.
To
very hard
scorecard.




wisdom about the structure of our
financial
put it somewhat more graphically, it is, indeed,
to
It

tell the players without— or
even
with— a
is in this environment that the legislative

-

2-

moratorium on the formation of "nonbank" banks (and related
matters) suggested by the Federal Reserve seems to me to make
very good sense. More generally, in this environment, with all
of its competitive implications, it is not surprising to find a
growing sense of urgency regarding the need to update some of
our laws and regulations as they pertain to the structure of
banking and the financial system.
I share in that sense of urgency in part because I
believe that banking functions in particular and financial
activities
more
generally are too important to allow a
helter-skelter of events to run their course in the hope that
events will shake out in a manner that is consistent with the
public
interest.
While
that
sense
of
urgency
is
understandable, 1 believe it is important that we not lose
sight of the fact that, for the last five decades, our banking
system has worked remarkably well.
Indeed, over the past
decade alone, the banking system has weathered a number of
storms and, in the process, demonstrated a truly impressive
degree of underlying strength and resiliency. The demonstrated
capacity of the banking system to weather these storms also
forcefully
underscores
the
public's
deeply
entrenched
confidence in the safety and soundness of the banking system.
To some considerable, but admittedly unmeasurable,
degree
public confidence in the banking system has its roots in the
legislative and regulatory framework— much of it dating back to
the 1930s— within which banks and other financial institutions
operate. The point I am working toward should be obvious.
Namely, as we proceed with the urgent task of reshaping the
legislative and regulatory framework within which banks and
other financial institutions operate, we must not lose sight of
those characteristics of the present system that have permitted
it to work so very well for 50 years.
In general, I believe most of us can agree on the
broad objectives that should be served by the effort to reshape
our banking laws and regulations in a manner that is more in
keeping with the realities of the contemporary marketplace. We



-

want

a

system

that

3

-

promotes— indeed

encourages— fair

and

reasonable
competition
in
the provision of banking and
financial services; we want a system that provides consumers
and
businesses— small
or large— with access to the most
cost-effective means of conducting their financial affairs; we
want a system that permits the monetary authorities to conduct
monetary policy with a reasonable degree of efficiency; and,
most of all, we want a safe and sound system which will
preserve, if not solidify, the public's confidence in the
banking system.
These objectives— and others that could be
added to the list— are easy
to
articulate
and,
taken
individually, are easy to subscribe to. The problem arises,
however, because specific objectives may often be in conflict
with each other. To cite just one such conflict, the objective
of competition may, at some point, be fundamentally in conflict
with the objective of safety and soundness. Thus, the task at
hand is one that inevitably entails the weighing and balancing
of sometimes conflicting objectives in a manner that in the
final analysis best serves the public interest.
The approach I have suggested in "Are banks special?"
seeks to balance these considerations by looking first at the
unique functions historically associated with
banks.
It
identifies three such unique functions: (1) that banks issue
transactions accounts— that is, liabilities that in fact or
perception are payable on demand at par and are readily
transferable to third parties; (2) that banks are the backup or
standby
source
of
liquidity
and
credit to all other
institutions; and (3) that the
banking
system
is
the
transmission belt through which monetary policy is conducted.
The essay goes on to suggest that in order for banks— or any
class
of
institutions— to perform these functions it is
important that their financial strength— the quality of their
assets, the depth and quality of their capital, etc.— be such
as to justify public confidence in
their
strength
and
vitality.
In turn, these considerations are, fundamentally,
why

it has been deemed in the public interest to have a public




-

4-

safety net in the form of deposit
discount
window, and particular
regulation associated with banks.

insurance, access to
forms of supervision

the
and

This framework, while perhaps a bit more conservative
than others, is not one that says that banks should be
precluded from engaging in "nonbanking" activities nor that
nonbank organizations should be precluded from engaging in
banking activities. To the contrary, the analysis is quite
compatible with those results. At the same time, however, it
does suggest that just because a particular activity can be
classified as "financial" in nature, it does not necessarily
follow that such activity should be fair game for banking
organizations.
And, it clearly suggests that the historic
separation of banking and commerce more generally still seems
to make eminent good sense.
Within

that framework, it seems to me that our efforts

to decide which activities are appropriate for banks must start
with a workable definition of a bank. The definition I have
suggested is simply that a bank is any institution that issues
liabilities that are payable on demand at par and are readily
transferable to third parties— i.e., banks issue transaction
accounts.
Using that or some other definition as a point of
departure, determining what activities are appropriate for
banking organizations can then be guided by the following:




First, I believe we must keep in mind that questions
of bank powers and bank ownership are, in practice,
one and the same. That is, if we say that a banking
organization can engage in a particular
set
of
"nonbanking" activities, it seems to me to follow, as
a matter of logic and practicality, that another firm
engaged exclusively in those same activities can own a
bank, whereas a firm engaged in a still broader range
of activities should not be permitted to own a bank.




-

5

-

,

Second
nonbank activities
of
banks
should
be
financial in nature or closely related to banking, but
they should also be activities that are not unduly
risky
and they should not be activities that can
impair the impartiality of the credit decision-making
process. These criteria suggest to me that while there
is a wide range of financial activities that may be
wholly appropriate for banking organizations, they may
also
be
activities
which— while
unambiguously
financial in nature— should not be engaged in by
banking organizations.

,

Third
the bank holding company structure provides a
vehicle which can help insure that the pursuit of
nonbanking activities by bank organizations does not
impair the soundness of banks and the soundness and
objectivity of their decision making.
Indeed, the
separate capitalization of
subsidiaries
of
bank
holding
companies
and
the
restrictions
self-dealing contained in Section 23-A of the

against
Federal

Reserve Act can be thought of as something of a
firewall that
provides a measure
of
protection
against conflicts of interest and against the risk of
loss in nonbank activities impairing the financial
condition of the bank itself. However, I for one am
not persuaded
that these protections can take on
failsafe
characteristics,
particularly
since the
strength of the firewall is likely to be tested only
in times

of peril.

Let me state it differently. I think it may be asking
too much to expect that banks can stand by with the
same detached objectivity when faced with a failing or
troubled affiliate as might be the case with an
unaffiliated firm.
Similarly, I think it may be
asking
too much of even relatively sophisticated
investors, much less small depositors, to expect that

-

6-

t . c a n
reaaily disassociate the problems of a
subsidiary of a bank holding company from the bank
itself.
Partly for these reasons, I believe that we
should take a very hard look at whether banks should
be
permitted to engage in activities which— while
financial in nature— may entail excessive risk and may
threaten
the objectivity of the credit decision­
making process. In time and under some circumstances,
it may make sense to fold all financial activities
into banking organizations, but for
strongly favor a tempered approach.

now,

I

would

Regardless of where the line for permissible banking
activities is drawn, more widespread combinations of banking
and nonbank financial institutions is inevitable. In such a
setting, I believe it is fair to speculate that the blending of
financial institutions and financial functions will work in the
direction of creating still greater interdependencies in what
is already a highly interdependent and interconnected financial
system domestically and
worldwide.
However,
over
some
reasonably long period of time, it is not clear to me that
broader powers for banks— in and of themselves— will produce a
degree of interdependence that would be materially different
from what would occur in any event.
Thus, regardless of its
causes, the reality of extraordinary financial interdependence
does imply that the task of isolating and containing problems
of a financial nature becomes more difficult, as we have seen
during the past year or so.
In this context, even if the
blending of financial functions and financial institutions does
not directly and materially increase the degree of financial
interdependence from what would occur in any event, it may
produce a situation in which it is more difficult to quickly
identify the dimensions and reach of problems when they arise
and to identify the circuit breakers that need to be thrown in
order to prevent a particular problem from taking on systemic
characteristics. None of this, in my judgment, need stand in
the
way
of the expansion of banking activities and the




-

associated

7

-

blending of financial functions and institutions but

it does, in my judgment, underscore the case
approach I suggested earlier.

for

the

tempered

As
a
related
matter,
the
deregulation
of
banks— whether in the form of the de facto elimination of
Regulation Q or the expansion of banking activities— produces
an acute dilemma. That is, deregulated banks, at least at the
margin,
are
more risky.
In principle, therefore, these
institutions should be more subject to the disciplines of the
marketplace including the ultimate discipline of failure.
it is even more compelling that concerns about systemic

Yet,
risk

and public confidence in the banking system mandate that we
maintain a public safety net under the banking system.
Stated
differently, one of the most difficult and important questions
raised by banking deregulation relates to
the
task
of
dovetailing the evident need for greater market discipline on
banking organizations with the need
to
maintain
public
confidence in the banking system. We need a public safety net
that is strong and effective, but also one that permits market
discipline to play its natural role.
As I said earlier, I, like many others, look upon the
current situation with a sense of urgency insofar as the need
for legislative remedy is concerned. The tides of technology
and the marketplace cannot be held back and, in a fundamental
way, they should not be held back. These forces for change
offer the potential for a more competitive, a more innovative
and a more vital banking and financial system. At the same
time, however, they dramatically underscore the need
for
discipline and prudence in financial affairs generally and in
banking activities in particular.
The task at
hand
is
formidable, yet manageable.
As we proceed, however, it seems
to me that the overriding consideration should be to preserve
and maintain a strong banking system in Which public confidence
can safely reside.

 Thank you.