View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Statement by

E. Gerald Corrigan

President, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

before the

Subcommittee on Conservation, Credit and Rural Development




Committee on Agriculture

House of Representatives

July 1, 1981

Thank you for inviting me to appear before you today.
I welcome this opportunity to share with you my thinking on
the current problems and prospects for our economy, and I look
forward to the opportunity to learn of your views on these
complex issues.
Obviously, the United States economy is going through
a difficult but necessary period of adjustment and transition.
The symptoms of these difficulties abound here in the Dakotas
and throughout the country at large.

In that setting, there is

a natural and understandable tendency to focus on w h a t 's wrong —
to take a one dimensional view of the problems of the day.
tendency can be misleading,

That

for even from the vantage point of

the last 18 months, it is possible to point to some positive
developments.

For example, as recently as the first quarter

of 1980 we were all looking at a very bleak picture;

financial

and commodity markets were in disarray; oil prices were surging
dramatically higher; political events, particularly in the MidEast, had taken on an alarming tone; the grain embargo was in
place; the dollar was being buffeted in the world markets and,
most ominously of a l l , the headlines in our newspapers told of
an alarming rise in the inflation rate, with some measures showing
the inflation rate

at a

Indeed, to some observers,

15 to 18 percent annual rate of increase.
it seemed as if the economy was on the

verge of a classical inflationary blow-out.
Now, some fifteen short months later, I think we can say
that things have not turned out anywhere near as badly as some




-

2

-

of the doomsday scenarios that were on people's minds in
early 1980.

To be sure, we did experience a short-lived and

sharp decline in economic activity in the second quarter of
last year, but in the ensuing months the aggregate economy has
been surprisingly strong.

Market conditions, while still not

wholly satisfactory, have improved, the dollar is strong abroad,
and —

most importantly —

tentative —

we now have some signs —

however

that the inflation rate may be receding a bit.

And, if we are all a bit tentative in concluding that inflation
is turning down, certainly we can say with some confidence that
the prospect of an inflationary blow-out has been arrested.
Yet, I would be far less than candid if I left you with
the impression that I think we are out of the woods.
Economic performance still leaves much to be desired.

We are not.
Inflation

remains high, unemployment is high, savings and investment are
low, and sustained productivity gains are, at best, elusive.
Finally, interest rates remain high and the associated balance
sheet pressures on businesses and households remain r e a l .
In that setting, I will confess to a certain trepidation
about appearing here with you this morning,

in part because I

suspect that some of you may look upon the Federal Reserve as the
primary cause of the current high level of interest rates.

The

Federal Reserve undeniably has something to do with the interest
rate situation, but I hope to use this occasion to put that situation
in its proper perspective and, in the process, shed some light on
the causes and cures for high interest rates.




-

3

-

It is not my purpose to speak to you today only about
interest rates as an isolated phenomenon, but rather to use
this occasion to discuss with you some of the more general
economic problems, institutions, and the policies that create,
and will ultimately cure, today's high interest rates.
Some of the symptoms of these problems are seemingly
conflicting and certainly confusing:

the simultaneous occurrence

of high inflation and high unemployment; the simultaneous occurrence
of low and, in many instances, declining real incomes; the
simultaneous and self-defeating effort of all groups to escape
inflation by striving to increase their real income —
"share of the pie" —

their

at the expense of others.

Other symptoms are less ambiguous.

Fifteen years of

essentially escalating rates of inflation produced a clear
tendency to "buy now" and "borrow now."

That tendency produced

low savings and therefore low investment, low capital formation,
and sluggish productivity, and contributed to the deterioration
of balance sheets for both individuals and businesses.

Similarly,

our markets, whether the market for precious metals, for wheat,
or for Treasury bills, have been buffeted by short-run price
variability, which, in my view,

illustrates forcefully the

heightened sensitivity of market participants —

small and large —

to changes in inflation and expected inflation.
At the risk of a gross oversimplification,

I think it is

fair to say that the symptoms of which I speak can all find their
roots in a decade and a half of essentially accelerating inflation.
And I would submit to you that the experience of 15 years of




-

4

-

progressively higher inflation was not altogether an accident
or an outgrowth of OPEC.

In part, it was a reflection of the

fact that many, if not most, of us convinced ourselves that
we could somehow live with a "little" more inflation.

We

could somehow isolate or insulate, we could somehow index or
subsidize, we could somehow muddle through.

Nearly all of us —

economists, journalists, teachers, liberals, and conservatives —
we all accepted that thinking because we believed that the
"little more" inflation seemed to buy so much more in terms of
lower unemployment and increased availability of goods and
services.
Unfortunately, we, like many before us, were wrong.
Indeed, in retrospect it is now clear that had we been willing
to look hard enough and had we been willing not to delude our­
selves, we would have recognized that accelerating inflation
is not something that can be lived with.
thing as a "little more" inflation.

There is no such

Inflation is inherently

debilitating, and as it grows, the resulting distortions and
inequities grow with it.
haven.

There is no escape —

there is no

In short, inflation must be attacked and it must be

rooted out.

Avoiding that reality only intensifies the problem

and increases the pain and discomfort associated with the process.
That is why I believe it is so important that we, as a nation,
come to grips with inflation now —

now before both the problem

and its ultimate solution reach proportions that could make our
current difficulties look mild by comparison.




-

5

-

I do not mean to suggest for one minute that this
implies that our national priorities and our national policies
need be or should be designed to the exclusion of other pressing
and legitimate concerns.

Certainly there is a long agenda of

other priorities which must be addressed.

However, I do mean

to suggest that we should keep one steady eye on the manner in
which our efforts to solve these other problems will either
contribute to or detract from the ongoing effort to control
inflation.
Nor do I mean to suggest that the task of rooting out
inflation will be easy.

It will not be.

But I do very much

believe that we have the knowledge, the tools, and above all,
the opportunity to get on with the job.
All of which brings me to the role of monetary policy.
I know full well that monetary policy and the Federal Reserve
are not easily understood, and I know full well that perceptions
about monetary policy can be the subject of heated controversy
and debate.

That is understandable, for monetary policy —

particularly in a day-to-day operational sense —

is highly

complex and is subject to many kinds of misunderstandings.
I'm sure you appreciate that.
technical problems and —

It's also subject to many

I would freely acknowledge —

it may

even be subject to some short-run miscalculations on our part
now and then.

These issues can and should be matters of concern,

but they should not stand in the way of an appreciation of the
core and essence of our policy.




-

6-

Simply put, that policy is one that seeks to restrain
the creation of new money and credit and, over time bring the
rate of new money creation down to a pace compatible with a
low rate of inflation.

That policy, I firmly believe, is a

necessary prerequisite to containing inflation and creating
conditions for sustained and sustainable economic growth.
is plain from history —

both here and abroad —

It

that inflation

cannot be turned around in an environment of rapid and un­
disciplined growth in money and credit.

This is not to suggest

that the appropriate monetary policy can or should do the job
by itself, but it is meant to say that without that policy other
efforts will surely fail.

I have no doubt, for example, that

a compatible and credible fiscal policy can be a potent and
perhaps essential complement to a disciplined monetary policy.
Stated differently, an appropriate monetary policy is a necessary
but not a sufficient condition for controlling inflation.
What then about interest rates?

What then about the

claim that the Federal Reserve is the cause of the current high
level of interest rates that I know is such a concern to all of
you?

There is, I must confess, an element —

only an element —

of truth to that claim.

and I emphasize,
It is true, for

example, that our policy of restraining the growth in the supply
of money does imply that only a certain amount of credit demands
can be satisfied at a given interest rate level.
demands are sizable —

and especially when they are fueled by

inflation and inflationary expectations —




When credit

interest rates will

-

rise.

7

-

I wish I could tell you that there was some easy way

to avoid or circumvent the resulting problem of high interest
rates but, in the short run, I see no such easy solution to
the problem.
In fact, in the short run and given some set of overall
economic and financial conditions, I can see only three alter­
natives.

First, the Federal Reserve could back off.

It could

speed up the printing press and push enough new money out into
circulation to validate all of the credit demands.
be done.

That could

But I think you recognize as readily as I , that such

a response would only fuel more inflation and higher inflationary
expectations, and in very short order, higher, not lower, interest
rates would result.

In short, I don't think much of that alter­

native.
A second approach might be to try to somehow structure
a program of credit controls or interest rate ceilings.
surface, at least, that idea may seem to have appeal.

On the
However,

on reflection, it too, I believe, is fraught with problems and
doomed to failure.

Experience has shown all too vividly that

controls don't work; they entail massive governmental bureaucracies
and arbitrary and sometimes counterproductive allocations, and
they are fundamentally in conflict with the system of markets
and free enterprise that is so revered here in the agricultural
heartland of America.

But there is another and perhaps even

more fatal practical flaw with credit controls and interest rate




-

ceilings.

8

-

That is, with the advent of high technology in

the money transfer business, trying to impose artificially
low lending rates by law or regulation would only ensure
that money —

which is highly fungible —

markets, even to foreign markets.

would flee to other

From where I stand, those

are not the results we want either.
There is a way, however, that can help to lessen the
pressures on interest rates, even in the short run.

For

example, it is clear that pressures on interest rates would be
relieved

if the demands for money and credit were more moderate.

Unfortunately, such a softening in credit demands is often
associated with a fall-off in economic activity —

a process

that we saw very clearly in the second quarter of 1980.

However,

achieving some moderation in credit demand need not be associated
with a large decline in economic activity, particularly when we
recognize that the government itself and its sponsored agencies
are by far the largest single source of credit demand.

Indeed,

there now seems to be widespread recognition in the Congress and
elsewhere that large and persistent patterns of government
borrowing work to place upward pressures on interest rates and
in the process work to limit the amount of credit that is avail­
able to private borrowers —

small and large.

This is heartening,

for I am convinced that we simply cannot have successive and
large federal deficits —
needs of the Treasury —

with all they imply for the borrowing
and at the same time expect to meet the

legitimate credit demands of businesses, households, and farmers
in a climate of moderate interest rates.




-

9

-

Thus reducing and eliminating deficits in the govern­
ment will work toward moderating congestion in our financial
markets and thereby easing upward pressures on interest rates.
One should not conclude from this that I believe that we must
have a balanced budget or a surplus every year.

There may,

for example, be periods in which reduced levels of economic
activity would justify a deficit.

Similarly, one should not

conclude from this that I believe that we must immediately
balance the budget.

To the contrary, in the current setting —

a setting that is already characterized by high and stifling
tax burdens, seeking to balance the budget immediately would
probably entail unacceptable

strains on the economy generally.

What is needed in the short run —
to be achieved —

and what I sense is beginning

is a firm and credible sense of direction —

a sense that we are moving in the right direction.

That alone

can unleash expectational forces that can help moderate interest
rates, particularly long-term rates which are so critical for
housing and other forms of fixed investment.
I said before that none of this will be easy.

Certainly

the realities of fiscal policy point in that direction for even
under the best of circumstances the Treasury will have a major
presence in our credit markets for some time to come.

That will

mean that for the time being the burden of the inflation fight
will continue to fall heavily on monetary policy.




-

10

-

In closing, let me also say that I am acutely aware
that the burden of high interest rates falls quite unevenly
on various sectors of the economy.

I am aware of that from

looking at economic statistics, but I am even more keenly
aware of it from my meetings with business leaders, farmers,
ranchers and bankers throughout the Ninth Federal Reserve District.
For the nation as a whole and right here in

the Dakotas, we

have a situation in which some sectors of the economy —
as energy —

such

seem virtually immune from the effects of high

interest rates.

At the same time, other sectors such as home

building, automobiles and smaller businesses are severely
pinched by high interest rates.

Some of these pressures are

moderated by instrumentalities such as the Farm Credit System,
but even allowing for these programs there can be no questioning
the proposition that the burden of high interest rates is far
more real for some than for others.

I wish I could tell you

that there was some way around this problem, but I fear there
is not.

Nor is there a way we can overcome these larger problems

and regain a stable and sustainable pattern of economic growth
without incurring some measure of difficulty and strain.
When all is said and done, there is only one sure formula
for lower interest rates and that is through lower inflation and
reduced expectations of inflation.

I said earlier that there

were some hopeful signs that the inflation rate may at last be
starting to recede a bit.

However,

I don't think we are yet

at the point where expectations of future inflation have begun




-

11

-

to depart from the deeply ingrained view that we are somehow
destined to see prices rising by 10 percent per year.

Achieving

that milestone will be the next critical step on the long and
tough road back to a truly prosperous economy.

With that goal

in sight, it seems to me that now is the time that we should
redouble our convictions and our commitment and I, for one,
have the clear sense that we are prepared to get on with the
job.

That sense of optimism grows out of my belief that we

have learned from our past mistakes and from my belief that
there is a widespread recognition that prosperity —
prosperity for all —
environment.

can only be achieved in a non-inflationary

This is the road —

the only sure road —

lower interest rates.




true

Thank you.

to