View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
9:10 a.m. EDT
April 3, 2009

Policies to Bring Us Out of the Financial Crisis and Recession

Remarks by
Donald L. Kohn
Vice Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
Forum on Great Decisions in the Economic Crisis
College of Wooster
Wooster, Ohio

April 3, 2009

I am glad to be back at Wooster. As I know from my time here, a strength of a
small liberal arts school like Wooster is its ability to draw on the diverse perspectives of
people of different disciplines and backgrounds to work closely with students in
examining important issues, and I’m pleased to be part of such an effort today.
My role today is to discuss the actions the government is taking to address our
current financial and economic difficulties. Although my fellow panelists will be
discussing how we got here and the regulatory policies we should adopt to prevent a
recurrence, I won’t be able to fulfill my task without impinging a bit on their topics. The
choice of policies follows by necessity from the diagnosis of the causes of the problems
being addressed. And, as we address the challenges of the here and now, we cannot lose
sight of the longer-term policy adjustments that we will have to make to avoid similar
crises in the future. 1
I should say at the outset that I will focus today on the economic and financial
problems and policy responses in the United States. However, because capital markets
and financial institutions are linked globally, financial dislocations and their
consequences have been felt around the world. Moreover, other countries have taken
policy steps similar to those taken here, including traditional and nontraditional monetary
policy, programs to support banking institutions, and fiscal stimulus. This is truly a
global crisis, and it is a hopeful sign that the need for forceful policy responses to the
serious challenges we face is broadly recognized.

1

The views are my own and not necessarily those of other members of the Federal Open Market
Committee. William English of the Board’s staff contributed to these remarks.

-2Characteristics of the Crisis
A defining characteristic of the crisis has been a deepening adverse feedback loop
in which financial strains have caused economic weakness, which has in turn led to credit
losses and heightened financial strains, which then contribute to further economic
weakness, and so on.
The trigger for the crisis when it broke in the summer of 2007 was a weakening of
the housing market and a sharp rise in delinquencies on subprime mortgages. These
delinquencies were importantly the result of a breakdown in underwriting standards that
reflected, in part, incentive problems in the securitization process. Lenders did not see a
need to underwrite carefully because they did not intend to hold the loans themselves.
Moreover, based on experience over recent years, investors expected property prices to
rise; they did not appreciate the extent of the bubble in housing prices, and so they did not
focus as much as they should have on the ability of the borrowers to repay the loans--or
pieces of loans--they were purchasing. Complex and opaque securitizations of loans
made due diligence on the underlying credits nearly impossible.
As losses on subprime loans mounted, investors realized that even highly rated
securities backed by subprime mortgages could face large write-downs, and the prices of
such securities declined sharply. Uncertainty about the extent of banks’ mortgage-related
losses and their potential liquidity needs to support off-balance-sheet entities led banks to
become much less willing to lend to each other and to other financial institutions. The
result was a sharp widening of risk spreads in key funding markets. Leverage in the
financial sector, which had contributed to higher profits during the financial boom, was

-3now seen to be excessive. As financial firms moved to reduce their exposures, they
became less willing to make markets, and the liquidity of many securities declined.
Although housing was the trigger and the largest single source of problems, as
time went on it became clear that problems in financial institutions and markets were
more broadly based. Risk on a variety of assets had not been priced appropriately, and
risk spreads in a range of markets increased, as did the equity risk premium. Markets for
private asset-backed securities (ABS) were hit especially hard. Reflecting the
deterioration in funding conditions, as well as efforts to conserve capital and liquidity,
banks tightened lending standards and terms on loans to both businesses and households.
With both financial markets and intermediaries under considerable strain, credit
became more expensive and, in some cases, unobtainable, causing spending to be
reduced. The weaker economy in turn contributed to further deterioration in asset quality
and concerns about greater losses to come. As a result, banks and other lenders tightened
their lending stance further, which put additional downward pressure on spending.
This adverse feedback loop, which was already visible from late 2007, intensified
considerably last fall. Failures and near-failures of some major financial institutions
greatly undermined confidence in financial institutions and severely disrupted financial
markets, leading to a further sharp tightening of credit conditions. Risk spreads, which
were already elevated, escalated further and equity prices fell. In addition, the financial
turmoil contributed to a sharp decline in consumer and business confidence. The result
was a major pullback in spending as consumers responded to decreases in wealth and the
deterioration in their future employment prospects and as businesses, worried about the
demand for their products, cut back on capital spending and sharply reduced production

-4to avoid an accumulation of unsold stocks. A gradual decline in economic activity
through most of 2008 took a decided turn for the worse late in the year.
The Policy Response
Because the threat to economic stability in the current episode has been so closely
related to problems in the financial sector, most of the policy responses have been
focused on financial institutions and markets and the flow of credit to households and
businesses. Many of these policies have been aimed at countering the tightening of
financial conditions that occurred as lenders became more risk averse and took steps to
conserve capital and liquidity. To that end, the Federal Reserve has lowered interest
rates, made backup sources of liquidity available to private lenders, and used its own
lending capacity to try to revive a variety of financial markets. In addition, the Federal
Reserve, the Treasury, and the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) have taken
a number of steps to stabilize and repair financial institutions in order to limit the
tendency of those institutions to pull back from lending and thereby intensify the decline
in spending.
Other government policies operate at the intersection of the financial and real
sectors. Foreclosure mitigation, for example, not only serves to keep people in their
homes, but also should reduce downward pressures on house prices and hold down loan
losses at lenders. Finally, fiscal stimulus works directly on demand, in effect bypassing
the financial sector in its first-round effects; by strengthening aggregate demand, it too
should help alleviate strains on lenders and contribute to stemming the vicious cycle.
Although I’ll be discussing each of these policy initiatives separately, it is
important to keep their interactions in mind. They all attempt to break into that adverse

-5feedback loop we’ve been talking about at different points in the chain of cause and
effect and then cause again. The expectation of recovery rests importantly on the natural
recuperative powers of the economy, but it also depends on the effects of the various
policy efforts reinforcing each other: A stable financial system is critical to realizing the
positive effects of monetary and fiscal policies; the financial system won’t stabilize very
quickly without monetary and fiscal stimulus to help support spending and ease credit
problems.
Monetary Policy
In response to the rise in credit spreads and tightening of credit conditions, the
Federal Reserve has aggressively eased monetary policy, as conventionally defined by
the target for the federal funds rate. In the second half of 2007 and into the spring of
2008, the federal funds rate target was cut rapidly, and, as the financial turbulence
intensified last fall and the economic outlook deteriorated, the Federal Open Market
Committee (FOMC) responded by cutting the target further, setting a range of 0 to 1/4
percent by the end of last year.
With the federal funds rate already near zero, the FOMC noted, in the statement
after its March meeting, “that economic conditions are likely to warrant exceptionally
low levels of the federal funds rate for an extended period.” By communicating this
expectation, the Committee reinforced market beliefs that policy is likely to remain on
hold, and so put downward pressure on longer-term rates. Because it is these longer-term
rates that have the largest effects on spending behavior, this sort of communication can
be very useful in stimulating borrowing and spending by businesses and households.

-6In addition to easing the traditional interest rate instrument of monetary policy,
the Federal Reserve has taken a range of other policy steps to ease credit conditions and
support the broader economy. From the onset of the crisis in the summer of 2007, we
could see that widening spreads in interbank funding markets were putting upward
pressure on the interest rates paid and charged by banks. To combat the strains in these
markets, the Federal Reserve provided credit to banks on more generous terms and at
longer maturities than usual. The Federal Reserve subsequently introduced the Term
Auction Facility, under which it holds auctions of fixed amounts of term credit to banks
on a regular schedule. By providing banks with a more assured source of liquidity, these
changes limited banks’ need to bolster liquidity through fire sales of assets and so made
them more willing to lend and to make markets.
The Federal Reserve also expanded its provision of liquidity beyond U.S. banking
institutions to other financial institutions and market participants. Because foreign dollar
funding markets affect U.S. markets, swap lines were established with foreign central
banks in late 2007 (and have since been expanded significantly), allowing them to obtain
dollars so that they could meet the dollar liquidity needs of banks in their jurisdictions.
As some large investment banks came increasingly under pressure in early 2008, the
Federal Reserve, consistent with its role as lender of last resort and in light of the key
roles these institutions play in a range of financial markets, introduced programs under
which it could provide liquidity to primary dealers. 2 And, as the financial situation
deteriorated last fall, the Federal Reserve established liquidity facilities for money market
mutual funds and introduced programs to provide liquidity directly to borrowers and

2

Primary dealers are broker-dealers that trade in U.S. government securities with the Federal Reserve Bank
of New York.

-7investors in key credit markets, including the commercial paper market, where strains
threatened the ability of many financial and nonfinancial firms to place their paper.
More recently, the Federal Reserve and the Treasury have teamed up to try to
restart the markets in which loans had been securitized to be sold to final investors. Until
the crisis, ABS issuance was a key source of funding for consumer loans, small business
loans, student loans, and other types of household and business credit. However, after the
substantial losses on residential mortgage-backed securities, and with the economy
weakening, investors became wary of all structured securities; spreads on ABS rose
sharply and issuance tailed off last fall. Under the Term Asset-Backed Securities Loan
Facility (TALF), the Federal Reserve will provide loans against a variety of ABS while
the private sector and the Treasury take most of the risk.
Finally, the Federal Reserve has begun making substantial purchases of longerterm securities in order to support market functioning and reduce interest rates in the
mortgage and private credit markets. As recently as our March meeting, the FOMC
increased the total planned amount of purchases of agency-guaranteed mortgage-backed
securities and initiated a program of buying longer-term Treasury securities. 3
I believe these efforts have been somewhat successful at addressing the
“tightening in financial conditions” side of the adverse feedback loop. Short-term
interest rates are much lower than they were when the crisis began, and so are mortgage
rates--at least those on mortgages eligible to be guaranteed by Fannie Mae and Freddie
Mac. Functioning of the commercial paper market has greatly improved. Banks,

3

To improve transparency regarding its programs to help stabilize the financial sector, as well as its other
operations, the Federal Reserve has established a resource, Credit and Liquidity Programs and the Balance
Sheet (www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/bst.htm), on its website that provides detailed information
on credit and liquidity programs and the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet.

-8investment banks, and money market mutual funds tell us that without the liquidity
backstops we have provided, they would have had to shrink and deleverage much more
rapidly, which would have put downward pressure on asset prices and would have further
reduced credit availability for households and businesses.
But we are not out of the woods yet. For many borrowers, credit remains much
harder to get and far more expensive than it was in the summer of 2007. Some reductions
in leverage and tightening of credit conditions relative to earlier this decade clearly were
needed, and I expect that lower leverage and tighter lending standards and terms will be
enduring features of the financial landscape. But current credit conditions are far tighter
than these adjustments would seem to justify. Many financial markets remain under
considerable stress, asset prices have been reduced by the lack of liquidity in markets,
and credit spreads and availability still reflect very high aversion to risk. These
conditions are not conducive to a substantial and sustained economic rebound, and the
Federal Reserve will continue to be alert to ways that monetary policy can contribute to
economic recovery.
We are also conscious of a potential adverse feedback loop between persistent
economic weakness and a continuing decline in inflation and inflation expectations.
With the federal funds rate about as low as it can go, significant further decreases in
inflation as a result of the substantial slack in resources, lower import prices, and declines
in the prices of oil and other commodities could imply an increase in the real federal
funds rate. Indeed, if such a process continued for some time, we could fall into
deflation, much as Japan did for a time in the 1990s and earlier this decade. Then again,
the substantial increase in the size of the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet as a result of the

-9credit programs that have been implemented have led some to worry that inflation could
rise sharply when the economy recovers unless the Federal Reserve moves quickly when
the time comes to unwind the programs and limit the growth in credit.
Because inflation expectations play a key role in the setting of prices and wages,
firmly anchored inflation expectations can help avoid both of these outcomes. To help
anchor inflation expectations, the FOMC is now providing extended projections of
inflation--along with growth and unemployment--in its quarterly economic projections.
To address concerns about its ability to rein in its balance sheet, the Federal
Reserve must be prepared to exit from its various programs when the time is right. We
have designed many of our facilities to discourage use when markets are functioning
more normally, and securities that have been accumulated can be sold when such sales
are judged to be appropriate. However, given very large purchases of long-term assets
and substantial long-term lending for the TALF and other purposes, the Federal Reserve
would benefit from new tools that would allow it to drain reserves from the banking
system. We are working with the Treasury and the Congress to obtain such tools.
Financial Repair
In addition to the Federal Reserve’s monetary policy actions, which broadly
support the financial sector and the economy, the government--including the Treasury,
the Federal Reserve, and the FDIC--has been working to provide more direct support to
financial firms. 4

4

To clarify the appropriate roles of the Federal Reserve and the Treasury during the current financial crisis
and in the future, the Federal Reserve and the Treasury issued a joint statement on March 23, 2009. See
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System and U.S. Department of the Treasury (2009), “The Role
of the Federal Reserve in Preserving Financial and Monetary Stability,” joint press release, March 23,
www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/20090323b.htm.

- 10 In part, this effort has involved targeted actions to prevent the failure or
substantial weakening of specific systemically important institutions, including Bear
Stearns, Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, AIG (American International Group, Inc.), Citigroup,
and Bank of America. These actions were not taken to protect the affected firms’
managers or shareholders from the costs of past mistakes. Indeed, managers have been
replaced in some cases, and shareholders of the weakest firms have experienced massive
losses. Instead, our actions have been driven by concerns that the disorderly failure of a
large, complex, interconnected firm would impose significant losses on creditors,
including other financial firms, dislocate a range of financial markets, and impede the
flow of credit to households and businesses. Losses sustained by other financial firms
could erode their financial strength, limiting their ability to play their intermediation role,
or even cause them to fail, reinforcing financial pressures. Moreover, the disorderly
failure of a large, complex interconnected firm could undermine confidence in the U.S.
financial sector more broadly, potentially triggering a widespread withdrawal of funding
by investors and an additional tightening of credit conditions, which would, in turn, cause
a further reduction in economic activity.
Besides this targeted support, the government has undertaken programs to inject
capital more broadly into the banking system. Since last fall, nearly $200 billion has
been distributed under a Treasury program that provides government capital investments
to banks in good condition. More recently, the Treasury, in conjunction with the bank
supervisory agencies, announced a new program to ensure that U.S. banking institutions
are appropriately capitalized. Under this program, the capital needs of the major U.S.
banking institutions are being evaluated relative to the losses that would be anticipated

- 11 under a significantly more challenging economic environment than anticipated in the
consensus of private forecasters. Should that assessment indicate that an additional
temporary capital buffer is warranted, institutions will have an opportunity to raise the
capital from private sources. If these efforts are unsuccessful, the temporary capital
buffer will be made available from the government. By providing additional capital, the
government can reduce concerns about the adequacy of bank capital, build investor
confidence in U.S. banking institutions and the U.S. financial sector more generally, and
so ease financial pressures and encourage new lending.
In addition to providing capital, the government, through the FDIC, has
temporarily guaranteed selected liabilities of insured depository institutions and their
holding companies. This program provides a stable source of funds for these institutions
and so eases the pressures on funding that some of them faced.
Finally, the Treasury recently announced a program to assist banks and other
lenders in reducing their “legacy assets”--that is, real estate loans held directly on their
books (“legacy loans”) and securities backed by loan portfolios (“legacy securities”) that
were accumulated during the housing boom and which have since declined in value and
become relatively illiquid. Uncertainty about the value of legacy assets is weighing on
confidence in banks, reflecting concerns that the assets will turn out to be worth much
less than currently thought and so undermine the financial strength of the banks holding
them. Moreover, the lack of liquid markets for legacy assets means that banks cannot
readily manage the associated risks and cannot easily make room on their balance sheets
for new loans if they have attractive lending opportunities. In part, buyers for these

- 12 assets are scarce because credit is expensive and difficult to obtain and because investors
are highly averse to risk.
Under the new program, the Treasury, with the participation of the FDIC and the
Federal Reserve, is establishing public-private investment funds to purchase legacy
assets. Capital for the funds will be provided jointly by private investors and the
Treasury. In addition, the government will provide the funds with leverage (through
Federal Reserve lending or FDIC guarantees) that currently cannot be raised from market
sources, allowing the funds to increase their purchases of legacy assets. These facilities
are structured to give the government a share of any gains in the value of assets
purchased while protecting the private-sector investors from some of the downside risks
inherent in real estate credit at present. By providing such protection along with leverage
that is unavailable in markets today, the government hopes to bolster demand for these
assets and restart markets in them.
Taken together, these financial repair programs are a comprehensive and
substantial effort to help financial institutions resume lending and so support economic
activity. Banks worried about the adequacy of their capital have been reassured by the
capital provided by the Treasury, and they may also be more optimistic about their ability
to raise private capital once they have shed legacy assets. At the same time, concerns
about the availability of funding should be eased by access to government-guaranteed
funding options. Moreover, as I noted at the outset, these programs need to be viewed as
complementing the monetary, fiscal, and other policies put in place to alleviate financial
strains and support aggregate demand. Indeed, when I think back to the exceedingly
perilous financial situation last September and October, I judge the efforts at financial

- 13 repair as at least a qualified success. Risk spreads in bank funding markets have
narrowed, and the liquidity positions of many institutions have improved. Despite
significant pressures on many financial firms, we have generally avoided fire sales of
assets by institutions that were troubled or were anticipating trouble.
Despite this progress, financial markets remain very fragile, lenders are still very
protective of their capital and liquidity, risk spreads remain elevated, and many
segments--especially securitization markets--continue to be impaired. However, some of
the government programs I have discussed--those to restart markets, provide additional
capital buffers, and open outlets for legacy assets--are just now being implemented.
While these programs are quite promising, we will not be able to judge their success at
restarting lending for a time.
Foreclosure Mitigation
Another way that the government has intervened to limit the spillovers of
financial problems to the real economy, and vice versa, is by taking steps to reduce
unnecessary foreclosures. Most notably, the Treasury recently announced the Making
Home Affordable program that will provide financial incentives to encourage lenders and
servicers to refinance existing mortgages with new mortgages having lower payments,
thereby helping at-risk homeowners to avoid foreclosure. The large supply of foreclosedupon houses coming onto the market has placed added downward pressure on house
prices, and clusters of vacant properties can lead to higher crime rates and strains on
municipal budgets as well. Thus, in addition to helping homeowners stay in their houses,
limiting foreclosures should benefit lenders, mitigate adverse impacts on affected

- 14 communities, and, by limiting the decline in overall home prices, help support the
macroeconomy.
Fiscal Policy
In addition to the wide range of policies to bolster financial firms and markets and
so damp the adverse feedback loop of the past year and a half, the government has put in
place fiscal stimulus that will support spending and economic activity directly. The fiscal
package includes tax cuts to bolster household incomes, new infrastructure investments,
and financial assistance to state and local governments, many of which would otherwise
have had to cut spending in light of declining revenues. The economy is very weak and
is likely to remain so for a while despite strong application of both conventional and
unconventional monetary policy actions; as such, this point in time would seem to be a
textbook moment for substantial fiscal stimulus. With monetary policy likely to be quite
accommodative for an extended period and the margin of unused capacity extraordinarily
large, crowding out of private-sector spending by the fiscal expansion should be limited.
Potential Policy Risks
The policies that we have pursued have been targeted to the problems we face-strains in funding markets, tight credit conditions, balance sheet weaknesses at some
banking institutions, rising foreclosures, and weak overall economic activity. By taking
this broad approach to the situation, we allow for positive interactions among the policies
we put in place and have the best chance of countering the adverse feedback loop that has
been an important driver of economic and financial developments since the outbreak of
the crisis. Nonetheless, the success of these policies is subject to a number of risks.

- 15 Protectionism and Financial Nationalism
One risk is that the crisis and the accompanying deterioration in economic
conditions will lead to increases in protectionism and financial nationalism. In hard times
countries may turn inward, focusing on the difficulties facing their own financial firms
and the dislocations in their own economies. And taxpayers may conclude that
commitments of government money should be devoted primarily to policies that will
directly benefit their nations’ citizens. Although these reactions are natural, we need to
recognize that if all countries react in this way, the result will be great inefficiency and a
worse outcome for all. For example, as is well known, international trade benefits all
nations by allowing for the more efficient production of goods and services. The current
system of relatively open international trade has been gradually built up over many years
and has contributed substantially to global prosperity. To backtrack now would be a
tremendous setback that likely could not be reversed for a very long time. And if
governments responded to problems at financial institutions in their countries by
attempting to protect only domestic investors, the result would be a rapid, and likely very
disruptive, unwinding of the international capital flows that run through the global
banking system, resulting in greater strains on financial institutions and so on the
economy.
Re-creating the Problems That Got Us Here?
A second risk that we should consider is whether in our efforts to deal with the
financial crisis, we are inadvertently re-creating many of the structures and behaviors that
contributed to the crisis. For example, the government is providing increased leverage
even as markets are calling for deleveraging; some of the government programs make use

- 16 of credit ratings from the same agencies that so evidently fell short in their assessments of
structured financial instruments; some of these programs employ financial structures
similar to the off-balance-sheet entities that proved unstable in the crisis; we are trying to
keep interest rates very low to support asset prices and spending after an episode in which
low long-term rates probably contributed to unsustainable housing prices; and, finally, we
are supporting economic activity by further increasing government deficits at a time
when the longer-term fiscal outlook is already troubling. So are we just perpetuating the
errors and misjudgments that led to the crisis, and thus sowing the seeds of a new crisis in
the years to come?
I don’t think so. The steps we have taken need to be seen as part of an effort by
the government to smooth the transition of our financial sector and economy to a more
sustainable situation. Both markets and regulators are going to press financial firms to
employ less leverage. Similarly, households will need to save more of their income over
time, and in that process domestic spending will be brought more into line with our
nation’s potential to produce, thus reducing our dependence on foreign savings.
However, the speed and force of the private-sector adjustments risk overshooting.
Investors, badly surprised by the performance of some structured instruments and also by
the extent of the economic downturn, have--at least for the time being--pulled back
sharply from risk-taking. But they will regain confidence over time and return to markets
that are now at a standstill. Government programs, like the TALF, can help rebuild that
confidence. Similarly, the prices of some assets may be in the process of overshooting
their long-run levels, reflecting heightened risk aversion and the very weak economic
outlook. And low asset prices could lead to a prolonged period of depressed consumer

- 17 and business confidence and what will ultimately prove to be an excessive shortfall in
consumer spending and business capital outlays. While these adjustments are playing
out, we are, in effect, temporarily substituting the government’s balance sheet and
spending for their private-sector counterparts.
However, while near-term stability seems to require slowing these adjustment
processes, we must put in place frameworks for exiting these programs if we are to end
up with a market-based economy that is more balanced and more resilient. Over time,
the Federal Reserve must reduce its lending; the government must put its deficits on a
distinct downward track; financial institutions must retire government assistance and
operate on their own.
Dealing with the Government
The success of these policies requires that they be utilized. Because the
government must protect the taxpayer, it needs to be sure that institutions taking taxpayer
money are using the resources efficiently to address the intended problem. To ensure that
government money is used appropriately, the government must monitor how it is used
and impose conditions on those receiving it. However, the conditions for government
assistance need to be carefully calibrated to protect the taxpayer while still allowing the
policy objectives to be accomplished. Firms might hold back on accepting government
help if they saw the cost of meeting the conditions as greater than the benefit of the
assistance or if they were concerned that the conditions might change in an undesirable
way after the assistance had been accepted. Such hesitance could impede the
effectiveness of government programs and slow the recovery of jobs and income.

- 18 Will We Need to Do More?
My final issue is the hardest: Are the policies we have put in place sufficient to
restart the flow of credit, or will the government need to do more? The answer, of
course, is that we don’t know--we have no reliable precedents for the current situation.
Policymakers are operating in a highly uncertain environment--one marked by a huge
amount of unquantifiable risks.
Most people, including policymakers, did not anticipate the depth, breadth, and
severity of the financial meltdown and economic downturn. We have had to remain very
flexible and open to policy actions that had no precedent. And all of us--the Federal
Reserve, the Administration, and the Congress--must continue in this posture. We must
keep our ultimate objectives for the economy firmly in mind--sustained recovery to high
levels of output and employment with price stability. We will continue to adapt our
policies as necessary to accomplish these objectives.