View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
12:15 p.m.EDT
October 9, 2009

Monetary Policy Research and the Financial Crisis: Strengths and Shortcomings

Remarks by
Donald L. Kohn
Vice Chairman
Board o f Governors o f the Federal Reserve System
at the
Federal Reserve Board Conference
on
Key Developments in Monetary Economics
Washington, D.C.

October 9,2009

The first two volumes of the Handbook o f Monetary Economics were published in
1990.1 It is fitting that the Federal Reserve Board should hold a conference showcasing
the chapters of the third volume of the Handbook. Since 1990, there has been a sharp
increase in the degree of interaction between academic economists and central bank
economists in the field of monetary analysis. The beginnings of this trend were evident
in the author list of volume one of the Handbook, which featured two chapters
coauthored by economists Athanasios Orphanides and Daniel Sichel, who went on to
have long careers at the Federal Reserve Board.2 It is reflected today in the planned
contents for volume three, which feature additional collaborations between central bank
and academic economists.
The interaction between researchers at academic and policy institutions is also
reflected in the enormous amount of scholarly research on monetary policy that is
relevant for policymakers. That subject is the focus of my talk today. I will organize my
remarks around the following tw'o questions: First, what aspects of the existing literature
in monetary economics have been particularly helpful in formulating the course of
monetary policy since the onset of the financial crisis? Second, what are the gaps in this
literature that have become particularly evident since the onset of the financial crisis and,
therefore, would be fruitful directions for further research that could contribute to the

I See Benjamin M. Friedman and Frank H. Hahn, eds. (1990), Handbook o f Monetary Economics, vois. 1
and 2 (Amsterdam: North-Holland/Elsevier).
See Athanasios Orphanides and Robert M. Solow (1990), “Money, Inflation and Growth.’' in Benjamin
M. Friedman and Frank H. Hahn, eds., Handbook o f Monetary Economics , vol. 1 (Amsterdam: NorthII ol land,'Elsevier). pp. 223-61; and Stephen M. Goldfeld and Daniel E. Sichel (1990). “The Demand for
Money,” in Handbook o f Monetary Economics , vol. 1. pp. 299-356.

facilitate continued lending by financial institutions. By lending only to solvent firms
with sufficient collateral and at a penalty rate, the central bank mitigates the moral hazard
problem and other distortionary effects of its provision of assistance. To be sure, these
important central banking principles have needed to be interpreted and applied in the real
world, where the line between insolvency and illiquidity may be blurry. But the
extraordinary actions taken so far during the financial crisis by the Federal Reserve and
other central banks have closely adhered to these basic principles of central banking.
Another body of research that I believe has been valuable for the formulation of
monetary policy over the past couple of years is the w'ork that has examined the
implications of the zero lower bound on nominal interest rates. The zero lower bound
challenged monetary policy in Japan during the late 1990s, triggering a large volume of
research. One of the main insights from this literature is that even when policy rates
already stand at a relatively low level, central banks should cut rates aggressively in face
of large contractionary disturbances.5 This insight influenced the historically large cuts
in the federal funds rate during 2008.
One prerequisite for this type of aggressive policy response is a credible
commitment to long-term price stability— important implication of both standard
an
models and experience. The public’s understanding of the central bank's commitment to
price stability helps to anchor inflation expectations, thereby contributing to stability in
both prices and economic activity. The Federal Reserve has acted to enhance that
Sec. for instance, the analysis in Jeffrey C. Fuhrer and Brian F. Madigan (1997), ‘‘Monetary Policy When
Interest Rates Are Bounded at Zero,” Review o f Economics and Statistics, vol. 79 (4), 573-85: and the work
by David Reifschneider and John C. Williams (2000), “Three Lessons for Monetary Policy in a LowInflation Era," Journal o f Money, Credit and Banking, vol. 32 (4, pt. 2), pp. 936-66. For interesting
analysis on the Japanese experience, see Alan Ahearne, Joseph Gagnon, Jane Haltmaier. and Steven Kamin
(2002). “Preventing Deflation: Lessons from Japan's Experience in the 1990s,” International Finance
Discussion Papers 729 (Washington: Board o f Governors o f the Federal Reserve System. June),
wwvv. federalreserve.gov/pubs/ifdp/2002/729/ifdp729. pdf.

interest rate was lowered to about zero, the Committee has provided some guidance about
the future path of the federal funds rate.
To be sure, we have not followed the theoretical prescription of promising to keep
rates low enough for long enough to create a period of above-normal inflation. The
arguments in favor of such a policy hinge on a clear understanding on the part of the
public that the central bank will tolerate increased inflation only temporarily—
say. for a
few years once the economy has recovered—
before returning to the original inflation
target in the long term. In standard theoretical model environments, long-run inflation
expectations are perfectly anchored. In reality, however, the anchoring of inflation
expectations has been a hard-won achievement of monetary policy over the past few
decades, and we should not take this stability for granted. Models are by their nature
only a stylized representation of reality, and a policy of achieving "temporarily" higher
inflation over the medium term would run the risk of altering inflation expectations
beyond the horizon that is desirable. Were that to happen, the costs of bringing
expectations back to their current anchored state might be quite high.
A final strand of literature has contributed to our policy strategy over the past two
years by emphasizing the role of credit and financial intermediation for macroeconomic
fluctuations and monetary policy transmission, particularly the literature that developed
during the 1980s on nonprice aspects of credit restriction and the importance of such
factors in severe economic downturns.9 From the onset of this financial crisis, we were
especially alert to the possibility that limits on the availability of credit to financial

v See, for example, Ben S. Bemanke (1983 ), “Nonmonetary Effects o f the Financial Crisis in the
Propagation o f the Great Depression.” The American Economic Review , vol. 73 (3). pp. 257-76: and
Dwight Jaffee and Joseph Stiglitz (1990), “Credit Rationing,” in Benjamin M. Friedman and Frank H.
Hahn, cds.. Handbook o f Monetary Economics , vol. 2 (Amsterdam: North-Uolland/Elsevier). pp. 837-88.

Moreover, that work has tended to concentrate on the intersection between
intermediaries and nonfinancial borrowers. A characteristic o f the recent crisis, how ever,
wras the critical role of interactions within the financial sector. Although rising defaults
on subprime mortgages caused the initial turbulence in financial markets, roadblocks to
the flow of credit within the financial sector from heightened uncertainty, increases in the
asymmetry of information, and questions about the alignment of incentives helped turn a
conventional credit event into a full-blown crisis. Recent research has begun to augment
core monetary models with heterogeneous agents, multiple interest rates, and risky
lending, but even so, it has become obvious that research on the importance of
intermediation and supply constraints on credit provision and thus on spending has
lagged significantly.14 An encouraging sign in this regard is the large number of recent
studies that add the banking sector and credit creation to standard monetary policy
models.1 Some of these studies emphasize bank capital as a constraint on financial
3
intermediation, while other studies allow for heterogeneity among banks and thereby
interbank borrowing and lending.16 Future research is likely to feature a proliferation of

C hanged?” Federal R eserve Bulletin, vol. 76 (12), pp. 985-1008; and D avid Reifschneider, Robert Tetlow,
and John C. W illiam s (1999), “A ggregate D isturbances, M onetary Policy and the M acroeconom y: The
FRB/US Perspective,” F ederal Reserve B ulletin, vol. 85 (1), pp. 1-19,
www. federalreserve. gov/pubs/bulletin/1999/01991ead.pdf.
1 See, for example, Vasco Curdia and M ichael W oodford (2009), “Credit Frictions and Optimal M onetary
4
P o lic y /’ m a n u scrip t C olum bia University, M ay.
See, for exam ple, M arvin G oodfriend and B ennett T. M cCallum (2007), “ Banking and Interest Rates in
M onetary Policy A nalysis: A Q uantitative E xploration,” Jou rn a l o f M onetary E co n o m ics, vol. 54 (5j,
pp. 1480-1507; M atthew Canzoneri, Robert Cum by, Behzad D iba, and J. D avid L opez-Salido (2008),
“M onetary Aggregates and Liquidity in a N eo-W icksellian Fram ew ork.” Journal o f Money, Credit and
B anking, vol. 40 (8), pp. 1667-98; and Law rence J. C hristiano, Roberto M otto, and M assimo Rostagno
(2009), “Financial Factors in Econom ic Fluctuations,” paper presented at “Financial M arkets and M onetary
Policy,” a conference sponsored by the Federal Reserve Board and the Journal o f Money, Credit and
Banking, W ashington, June 4-5, w w w .federalreservc.gov/events/conferences/fm m p2009/papers/C hristianoM otto-R ostagno.pdf.
1 For exam ples o f studies that em phasize bank capital as a constraint on financial interm ediation, see
6
Cesaire A. Meh and Kevin M oran (2008), “The Role o f Bank Capital in the Propagation o f Shocks," Bank
o f Canada W orking Paper 2008-36 (Ottawa, Ontario, Canada: Bank o f C anada, O ctober),

among those movements, credit supply, and economic activity were not well captured by
the models used at most central banks.

17

Our limited knowledge of the determinants of asset prices and their effects on
credit has made it more challenging to respond to the crisis and explain our actions to the
public. We have had to relax our standard assumptions that financial assets are highly
substitutable, and that their rates of return can be readily arbitraged. For example, the
degree to which assets of different types and maturities are imperfect substitutes is central
to understanding the large-scale asset purchase, or LSAP, program of the Federal
Reserve. Our purchases of longer-term Treasury, agency, and agency-guaranteed
mortgage-backed securities were undertaken to support aggregate demand. These actions
were designed to lower mortgage and other interest rates by exerting downward pressure
on yields on assets that are only imperfectly substitutable for very short-term assets, and
whose substitutability for those very short-term assets likely has decreased in the crisis
period. In addition, discussions of the effects of the buildup in reserves at the Federal
Reserve and other central banks often emphasize the imperfect substitutability of reserves
for other bank assets, even when those reserves are remunerated at something like a
market interest rate. More generally, while most of the literature on the effects of
monetary policy assumes that the federal funds rate is the single relevant tool for
monetary policy, the financial crisis has shown that a wide array of policy measures,
acting on the prices of different assets, may be needed in extreme circumstances. The

' ' See Frederic S. Mishkin (2008), ‘"Monetary Policy Flexibility, Risk Management, and Financial
Disruptions.” speech delivered at the Federal Reserve Bank o f New York, New York, January 11,
w w w .federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/mishkin20080111 a.htm.

-11

-

models to take much better account of nonlinearities and tail events, which played such a
prominent role in the rapid deterioration of the global economy last year. The new
agenda will require letting go of a number of the simplifications and assumptions that
have made our models tractable and delving into literatures related to— not necessarily
but
considered traditional—
monetary economics. But the developments of the past two years
have highlighted both the strengths and weaknesses of the previous research agenda.
Policymakers will be making judgments based on what we think we have learned in that
time. We need your work to organize our thoughts and guide our judgments about the
lessons from this experience. The Handbook o f Monetary Economics has played a
critical role in this regard in the past, and I am confident that it will continue to do so in
the future.