View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
10:15 a.m. EST
January 3, 2010

Monetary Policy in the Crisis: Past, Present, and Future

Remarks by
Donald L. Kohn
Vice Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at
Brimmer Policy Forum, American Economic Association Annual Meeting
Atlanta, Georgia

January 3, 2010

I’m pleased to participate in this year’s Brimmer Policy Forum. Governor
Brimmer and I did not overlap at the Board, but I admired his work from my perch at the
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, where I began my career in the System. And my
colleagues at the Federal Reserve and I have benefited greatly since then from his
analytical approach to difficult public policy issues. This morning I thought it might be
useful for me to review the course of monetary policy through the crisis and highlight a
few issues for policy in the future.
I’d like to make two important clarifications before I get started: First, despite the
title of the Forum, what I am about to discuss is not President Obama’s monetary policy-it is the Federal Reserve’s. Fortunately, the Administration has been careful to respect
the independence of the Federal Reserve in the conduct of monetary policy. It recognizes
that the Federal Reserve’s insulation from short-term political pressures is essential for
fostering achievement of its legislative objectives of stable prices and maximum
employment over time. Second, the views you are about to hear are my own and not
necessarily those of any other member of the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC).
Monetary Policy Past
As a prelude to discussing where we are now and issues for the future, I thought it
would be helpful to summarize the actions that we took over the past two years. In
August 2007, we recognized that we were coping with a potentially serious disruption in
financial markets that could feed back adversely on the economy and job creation. With
liquidity in key funding markets drying up and some securitization markets closing down,
lower policy interest rates alone were not going to be enough to keep financial conditions

-2from tightening severely for households and businesses. In the end, we had to operate on
multiple fronts to stabilize the financial markets and foster a rebound in the economy.
Expanding liquidity facilities. Our first actions were to ease the access of
depository institutions to Federal Reserve liquidity. But, as the crisis worsened, it
became apparent that these actions would be insufficient. Securities markets had come to
play a prominent role in channeling credit in our economy, and severe disruptions outside
the U.S. banking sector were threatening to reduce economic activity. To counter the
financial shocks hitting the economy and support the flow of credit to households and
businesses, we then needed to extend liquidity support to a range of nonbank institutions
and to some financial markets. As we expanded the reach of our liquidity facilities, we
generally followed the time-honored precepts of central bank behavior in a crisis: Extend
credit freely to solvent institutions at a penalty rate against adequate collateral. By
making liquidity available more broadly, we were trying to break the vicious spiral of
uncertainty and fear feeding back on asset values and credit availability, and from there
to the economy. We also found we needed to innovate by making liquidity available
through auctions as well as standing facilities to overcome firms’ reluctance to borrow
from the Federal Reserve out of concern that the borrowing could be inferred by market
participants and viewed as an indication of financial weakness.
Lowering policy interest rates. In view of the likelihood that financial
developments would lead to a weakening of aggregate demand, we began to lower the
federal funds rate in September 2007, well before any hard evidence had become
available regarding the magnitude of the restraint that it might impose on economic
activity. As it became increasingly evident over the course of 2008 that the financial

-3disruptions were sending the U.S. economy into recession, we picked up the pace of
reductions in our federal funds rate target. Importantly, our ability to move aggressively
was enhanced by an environment of already low inflation and stable inflation
expectations.
Buying longer-term assets. To ease financial conditions further even after our
policy interest rates had approached zero, we needed to operate directly on longer-term
segments of the financial markets. Even though various types of debt securities are
ordinarily quite substitutable, our purchases of agency-guaranteed mortgage-backed
securities (MBS), agency debt, and Treasury securities evidently were successful in
reducing long-term interest rates, partly because during the crisis, private-sector
participants had a very marked preference for short-term assets.
Interest rate guidance. In this highly unusual situation, and with the normal
response of monetary policy interest rates constrained by the zero lower bound, we
consider it especially important that we convey as clearly as possible our policy
intentions to market participants as they formulate their own expectations for the future
path of interest rates. To help in this regard, we have noted in the statements we have
released at the conclusion of each FOMC meeting our expectation that exceptionally low
rates will likely be warranted for an extended period.
Inflation forecasts and objectives. Keeping inflation expectations anchored is
always important but especially so in current circumstances, given the potential effects of
the unprecedented economic developments and policy actions of the past two years on
households’ and businesses’ views of the price outlook. To provide more information to
the public about our own expectations and objectives, we have extended the horizon of

-4the published projections of FOMC participants to five years and have supplemented
these projections by reporting the long-term inflation rates Committee participants view
as most consistent with satisfying our dual mandate.
Stabilizing systemically important institutions. In the absence of any other
governmental agency having the authority to fill the role, we have lent to stabilize several
systemically important institutions, any one of which--had it failed--would have posed a
serious threat to the financial system and the economy. These actions, while necessary,
were not well suited for a central bank, and we have urged the Congress to enact other
means of safeguarding financial stability in such circumstances while imposing costs on
shareholders, management, and, whenever possible, creditors.
Monetary Policy Present
The broad suite of monetary, financial, and fiscal policies that have been applied,
along with the natural resilience of the economy, has led to a marked improvement in
financial markets and the beginnings of a recovery in economic activity.
Financial markets are performing much better now than they were in early 2009.
Our liquidity facilities, the reduction of uncertainty about the capital and liquidity needs
of the largest banks after the results of our capital assessment were published in May, and
the emerging stabilization of the housing and other key sectors of the economy have
helped a number of financial markets resume more normal functioning.1 As a
consequence, borrowing from the Federal Reserve has dropped dramatically. In addition,
many securitization markets appear to be functioning more normally, partly reflecting the
support provided by the Term Asset-Backed Securities Loan Facility that we
1

For more on the results of the capital assessment, see Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
(2009), The Supervisory Capital Assessment Program: Overview of Results (Washington: Board of
Governors, May 7), www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/bcreg20090507a1.pdf.

-5implemented in early 2009 with the support of the Treasury Department. As we affirmed
at the December FOMC meeting, the Federal Reserve is in the process of winding down
and closing most of our extraordinary liquidity windows.
Our announcements of purchases of agency MBS, agency debt, and Treasury
securities helped to lower long-term interest rates and increase the availability of
mortgages to households and bond financing to businesses. In addition, our near-zero
policy rate and the improving economic outlook have induced shifts by private investors
into longer-term and riskier assets, helping to reverse a portion of the previous spike in
spreads that occurred as the economy and financial markets deteriorated. With markets
improving and the economy expanding, the FOMC has also indicated that it is tapering
down its purchases of Treasury, MBS, and agency securities.
But the cost of credit remains relatively high and its availability relatively limited
for many borrowers. Although many long-term interest rates are fairly low, spreads in
bond markets are somewhat elevated--not surprising, perhaps, as many borrowers are still
under stress with the unemployment rate quite high and utilization of the capital stock
still very low. Some securitization markets continue to be effectively closed or severely
impaired, including those for larger home mortgages and commercial real estate loans.
Under these circumstances, some borrowers will be more dependent than in the past on
banks for credit, but banks are still reluctant and very cautious lenders. Banks have been
reducing their book of loans for about a year; in part, this drop reflects weaker demand as
businesses have cut back on inventories and households have been rebuilding their
balance sheets by increasing saving. But the weakness in bank lending also results from
cutbacks in supply. Our surveys show that through late 2009, banks continued to tighten

-6terms and standards for lending and to raise the rates they charge relative to benchmark
rates. I expect bank credit to turn around only slowly as banks rebuild capital and
become less uncertain about economic prospects.
Lingering credit constraints are a key reason why I expect the strengthening in
economic activity to be gradual and the drop in the unemployment rate to be slow. Even
as the impetus from fiscal policy and the inventory cycle wanes later in 2010, however,
private final demand should be bolstered by further improvements in securities markets
and the gradual pickup in credit availability from banks. In addition, spending on houses,
consumer durables, and business capital equipment should rebound from what appear to
be exceptionally low levels. We have already seen some hints of this increase in private
demand in recent months. But, understandably, households and businesses and bank
lenders remain very cautious, and the odds are that the pickup in spending will not be
very sharp.
In an environment of considerable persisting slack in labor and product markets,
and with productivity having increased substantially in recent quarters, cost and price
inflation should remain quite subdued. In the short run, headline inflation will be driven
importantly by movements in energy and food prices; judging from the structure of
futures prices, markets are not expecting a further sharp rise in those prices, and thus
headline inflation should retreat toward core inflation. Inflation outside of the food and
energy sectors has been declining slowly, held up by relatively stable inflation
expectations. Some further slowing is possible if the economic rebound is as gradual as I
think it is likely to be. As I have already noted, keeping inflation expectations anchored
will be critical for achieving our objectives for prices and output.

-7The FOMC has recently reiterated its expectation that the considerable remaining
slack in labor and product markets and subdued trends in inflation and inflation
expectations are likely to warrant exceptionally low levels of the federal funds rate for an
extended period.
Monetary Policy Future
The Federal Reserve will face a number of challenges in the conduct of monetary
policy in the period ahead. I will discuss two of them: further exit from our
extraordinary measures, including the large volume of reserves, our outsized portfolio of
MBS, agency, and Treasury securities, and our near-zero policy interest rate; and
evaluating any lessons from the recent experience for the conduct of policy--in particular,
the potential role of financial stability and asset prices in monetary policy formulation.
Exit. I’m not going to discuss the technical aspects of an exit from our
extraordinary measures; the Federal Reserve has kept the public apprised of the
development of our exit tools, and the appropriate use and sequencing of these tools is
under active discussion by the FOMC. But I do want to make some general strategic
points.
First, we have no shortage of tools for firming the stance of policy, and we will be
able to unwind our actions when and as appropriate. Because we can now pay interest on
excess reserves, we can raise short-term interest rates even with an extraordinarily large
volume of reserves in the banking system. Increasing the rate we offer to banks on
deposits at the Federal Reserve will put upward pressure on all short-term interest rates.
In addition, we are developing and testing techniques for draining large volumes of
reserves through reverse repurchase agreements and through term deposits at the Federal

-8Reserve. And we can sell portions of our holdings of MBS, agency debt, and Treasury
securities if we determine that doing so is an appropriate approach to tightening financial
conditions when the time comes.
Second, the fiscal situation will not impede timely tightening. The trajectory of
the federal budget is a serious economic issue that must be addressed to promote
sustained and balanced economic growth. But a large and growing federal deficit will
not stop the Federal Reserve from exiting from current policies when that’s needed to
keep prices stable and the economy on a path to sustained high employment. The
alternative of letting inflation rise would be inconsistent with our mandate and would
only cause greater volatility, uncertainty, and inefficiencies that would reduce the growth
of our economy over time. Higher interest rates could complicate an already difficult
fiscal trajectory, and this possibility further underscores the critical importance of
maintaining Federal Reserve independence from short-term political pressures.
Third, because monetary policy typically acts with long lags on the economy and
price level, the choice of when and how to exit will depend on forecasts. We will need to
begin withdrawing extraordinary monetary stimulus well before the economy returns to
high levels of resource utilization. The FOMC has been clear that its expectations for the
stance of monetary policy depend on economic conditions, including resource utilization,
inflation, and inflation expectations. Accordingly, the judgment as to when to begin
initiating steps to withdraw stimulus will depend on the outlook for these variables.
Finally, it is well to remember that we are still in uncharted waters. We do not
have any recent experience with financial disruptions of the breadth, persistence, and
consequences of those that we have experienced over the past several years. And we

-9have no experience with most of the sorts of actions the Federal Reserve has taken to
counter the shock. The calibration of our exit from these policies is complicated by a
paucity of evidence on how unconventional policies work. We will need to be flexible
and adjust as we gain experience.
Financial stability and asset prices. The past few years have illustrated two
lessons about the relationship between macroeconomic stability and financial stability.
First, macroeconomic stability doesn’t guarantee financial stability; indeed, in some
circumstances, macroeconomic stability may foster financial instability by lulling people
into complacency about risks. And second, some shocks to the financial system are so
substantial, especially when they weaken a large number of intermediaries, that decreases
in aggregate demand can be large, long lasting, and not quickly or easily remedied by
conventional monetary policy.
Given the heavy costs that have resulted from the financial crisis, the question
naturally arises as to whether the circumstances that caused the crisis could have been
avoided. Among other crucial policy issues, we now need to reexamine, with open
minds, whether conventional monetary policy should be used in the future to address
developing financial imbalances as well as the traditional medium-term macroeconomic
goals of full employment and price stability. The key question is whether we are likely to
know enough about asset price misalignments and the likely effects of policy adjustments
to give us the confidence to deliberately tack away for a time from exclusive pursuit of
fostering aggregate price stability and high employment. Obviously preventing situations
like the current one would be very beneficial. But against this important objective we
need to balance the potential costs and uncertainties associated with using monetary

- 10 policy for that purpose, especially in light of the difficulty in judging the appropriateness
of asset valuations.
One type of cost arises because monetary policy is a blunt instrument. Increases
in interest rates damp activity across a wide variety of sectors, many of which may not be
experiencing speculative activity. Moreover, monetary policy generally operates with
one instrument--a short-term interest rate--and using it to damp asset price movements
implies more medium-term variability in output and inflation around their objectives.
Among other things, inflation expectations could become less well anchored, diminishing
the ability of the central bank to counter economic fluctuations. In the current situation,
with output expected to be well below its potential for some time and inflation likely to
be under the 2 percent level that many FOMC participants see as desirable over the long
run, tightening policy to head off a perceived threat of asset price misalignment could be
expensive in terms of medium-term economic stability.
Furthermore, small policy adjustments may not be very effective in reining in
speculative excesses. Our experience in 1999 and 2005 was that even substantial
increases in interest rates did not seem to have an effect on dot.com stock speculation in
the first instance, and housing price increases in the second. And larger adjustments
would incur greater incremental costs. Policy adjustments need to damp speculation; if
higher rates just weaken output and inflation without damping speculation, the economy
could be even more vulnerable when the speculative bubble bursts. We do not have good
theories or empirical evidence to guide policymakers in their efforts to use short-term
interest rates to limit financial speculation.

- 11 For all these reasons, my strong preference would be to use regulation and
supervision to strengthen the financial system and lean against developing problems.
Given our current state of knowledge, monetary policy would be used only if imbalances
were building and regulatory policies were either unavailable or had been shown to be
ineffective. But, of course, we should all be working to improve our state of knowledge,
so as to better understand economic and financial behavior and to further expand the
range of policy tools that can be employed to enhance macroeconomic performance.
That objective is one that Governor Brimmer has worked hard to promote.