View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
9:00 a.m. EDT
May 13, 2010

The Federal Reserve’s Policy Actions during the Financial Crisis
and Lessons for the Future

Remarks by
Donald L. Kohn
Vice Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at
Carleton University
Ottawa, Canada

May 13, 2010

The financial and economic crisis that started in 2007 tested central banks as they had not
been tested for many decades. We needed to take swift and decisive action to limit the damage
to the economy from the spreading distress in financial markets. Because the financial distress
was so deep and pervasive and because it took place in financial markets whose structure had
evolved dramatically, our actions also needed to be innovative if they were to have a chance of
being effective. Many central banks made substantial changes to traditional policy tools as the
crisis unfolded. But the epicenter of the financial shock was in U.S. mortgage markets, with
severe effects on many of our financial institutions, and our financial markets had perhaps
evolved more than many others. As a consequence, no central bank innovated more dramatically
than the Federal Reserve.
We traditionally have provided backup liquidity to sound depository institutions. But in
the crisis, to support financial markets, we had to provide liquidity to nonbank financial
institutions as well. Just as we were forced to adapt and innovate in meeting our liquidity
provision responsibilities, we also needed to adapt and innovate in the conduct of monetary
policy. Very early in the crisis, it became evident that lowering short-term policy rates alone
would not be sufficient to counter the adverse shock to the U.S. economy and financial system.
We needed to go further--much further, in fact--to ease financial conditions and thus encourage
spending and support employment. We took steps to reinforce public understanding of our
inflation objective to prevent the development of deflationary expectations; we provided
guidance on the possible future course of our policy interest rate; and we purchased large
amounts of longer-term securities, and in the process created unprecedented volumes of bank
reserves. Now, careful planning is under way to remove that stimulus at the appropriate time.

-2My discussion today will focus on innovations in both our role as liquidity provider and in our
monetary policy tools: their motivation, their effectiveness, and their lessons for the future.

1

The Federal Reserve’s Liquidity Tools
Before the crisis, the implementation of monetary policy was fairly straightforward, and
our approach minimized its footprint on financial markets. The Federal Reserve adjusted the
liquidity it provided to the banking system through daily operations with a relatively small set of
broker-dealers against a very narrow set of collateral--Treasury and agency securities. These
transactions had the effect of changing the aggregate quantity of reserve balances that banks held
at the Federal Reserve, and that liquidity was distributed by interbank funding markets through
the banking system in the United States and around the world. In addition, the Federal Reserve
stood ready to lend directly to commercial banks and other depository institutions at the
“discount window,” where, at their discretion, banks could borrow overnight at an above-market
rate against a broad range of collateral when they had a need for very short-term funding.
Ordinarily, however, little credit was extended through the discount window. Banks were able to
obtain their funding and reserves in the open market and generally turned to the window only to
cover very short-term liquidity shortfalls arising from operational glitches or transitory
marketwide supply shortfalls, as opposed to more fundamental funding problems.
During the financial crisis, however, market participants became highly uncertain about
the financial strength of their counterparties, the future value of assets (including any collateral
they might be lending against), and how their own needs for capital and liquidity might evolve.
They fled to the safest and most liquid assets, and as a result, interbank markets stopped
functioning as an effective means to distribute liquidity, increasing the importance of direct

1

The views expressed are my own and not necessarily those of my colleagues on the Federal Open Market
Committee. James Clouse and Fabio Natalucci of the Board’s staff contributed to these remarks.

-3lending through the discount window. At the same time, however, banks became extremely
reluctant to borrow from the Federal Reserve for fear that their borrowing would become known
and thus cast doubt on their financial condition. Importantly, the crisis also involved major
disruptions of important funding markets for other institutions. Commercial paper markets no
longer channeled funds to lenders or to nonfinancial businesses, investment banks encountered
difficulties borrowing even on a short-term and secured basis as lenders began to have doubts
about some of the underlying collateral, banks overseas could not rely on the foreign currency
swap market to fund their dollar assets beyond the very shortest terms, investors pulled out from
money market mutual funds, and most securitization markets shut down. These disruptions to
financing markets posed the same threats to the availability of credit to households and
businesses that runs on banks created in the more bank-centric financial system of the 1800s and
most of the 1900s. As a result, intermediaries unable to fund themselves were forced to sell
assets, driving down prices and exacerbating the crisis; moreover, they were unwilling to assume
the risks necessary to make markets in the debt and securitization instruments that were critical
channels supporting household and business borrowing--and households and businesses unable
to borrow were thus unable to spend, thereby deepening the recession.
These liquidity pressures were evident in nearly every major country, and every central
bank had to adapt its liquidity facilities to some degree in addressing these strains. At the
Federal Reserve, we had to adapt somewhat more than most, partly because the scope of our
activities prior to the crisis was fairly narrow--particularly relative to the expanding scope of
intermediation outside the banking sector--and partly because the effect of the crisis was heaviest
on dollar funding markets. Initially, to make credit more available to banks, we reduced the
spread of the discount rate over the target federal funds rate, lengthened the maximum maturity

-4of loans to banks from overnight to 90 days, and provided discount window credit through
regular auctions in an effort to overcome banks’ reluctance to borrow at the window due to
concerns about the “stigma” of borrowing from the Federal Reserve. We also lent dollars to
other central banks so that they could provide dollar liquidity to banks in their jurisdictions, thus
easing pressures on U.S. money markets. As the crisis intensified, however, the Federal Reserve
recognized that lending to banks alone would not be sufficient to address the severe strains
affecting many participants in short-term financing markets. Ultimately, the Federal Reserve
responded to the crisis by creating a range of emergency liquidity facilities to meet the funding
needs of key nonbank market participants, including primary securities dealers, money market
mutual funds, and other users of short-term funding markets, including purchasers of securitized
loans. 2
Why couldn't the Federal Reserve maintain its routine lending practices and rely on
lending to commercial banks, which in turn lend to nonbank firms? The reason is that financial
markets have evolved substantially in recent decades--and, in retrospect, by more than we had
recognized prior to the crisis. The task of intermediating between investors and borrowers has
shifted over time from banks--which take deposits and make loans--to securities markets--where
borrowers and savers meet more directly, albeit with the assistance of investment banks that help
borrowers issue securities and then make markets in those securities. An important aspect of the
shift has been the growth of securitization, in which loans that might in the past have remained
on the books of banks are instead converted into securities and sold to investors in global capital
markets. Serious deficiencies with these securitizations, the associated derivative instruments,
and the structures that evolved to hold securitized debt were at the heart of the financial crisis.

2

Primary dealers are broker-dealers that trade in U.S. government securities with the Federal Reserve Bank of New
York.

-5Among other things, the structures exposed the banking system to risks that neither participants
in financial markets nor regulators fully appreciated. Banks became dependent on liquid markets
to distribute the loans they had originated. And some parts of the securitized loans were sold to
off-balance-sheet entities in which long-term assets were funded by short-term borrowing with
implicit or explicit liquidity guarantees provided by the banks. Securitization markets essentially
collapsed when banks became unwilling to increase their exposure to such risks during the crisis,
when the liquidity guarantees were invoked, and when other lenders in securitization markets
became unwilling to supply credit.
Although the Federal Reserve’s lending actions during the crisis were innovative and to
some degree unprecedented, they were based on sound legal and economic foundations. Our
lending to nonbank institutions was grounded in clear authority found in section 13(3) of the
Federal Reserve Act permitting a five-member majority of the Federal Reserve Board to
authorize a Reserve Bank to lend to individuals, partnerships, or corporations in “unusual and
exigent circumstances.” These actions also generally adhered to Walter Bagehot’s dictum, a
time-honored central banking principle for countering a financial panic: Lend early and freely to
solvent institutions at a penalty rate and against good collateral. 3 Central banks are uniquely
equipped to carry out this mission. They regularly lend to commercial banks against a wide
variety of collateral and have the infrastructure to value and perfect their interest in the
underlying collateral. During a panic, market functioning is typically severely impaired, with
investors fleeing toward the safest and most liquid assets, and the resulting lack of liquidity, even
for sound banks with sound assets, can result in funding pressures for financial institutions and
others. By lending to solvent institutions against illiquid collateral, central banks effectively step
3

Walter Bagehot ([1873] 1897), Lombard Street: A Description of the Money Market (New York: Charles
Scribner’s Sons).

-6in to assume the liquidity risk of such assets--that is, the risk that assets can only be sold in the
near term at fire sale prices. And their ability to substitute for private-sector intermediation in a
panic is unlimited since they create reserves. For the most part, the Federal Reserve priced these
facilities to be attractive when markets were disrupted but not economical to potential borrowers
as market functioning improved.
Importantly, lending against good collateral to solvent institutions supplies liquidity, not
capital, to the financial system. To be sure, limiting a panic mitigates the erosion of asset prices
and hence capital, but central banks are not the appropriate authorities to supply capital directly;
if government capital is necessary to promote financial stability, then that is a fiscal function.
This division of responsibilities presented challenges in the crisis. The securitization markets
were impaired by both a lack of liquid funding and by concerns about the value of the underlying
loans, and broad-based concerns about the integrity of the securitization process. To restart these
markets, the Federal Reserve worked with the Treasury in establishing the Term Asset-Backed
Securities Loan Facility (TALF): The Federal Reserve supplied the liquid funding, while the
Treasury assumed the credit risk. The issue of the appropriate role of the central bank and fiscal
authority was present in other contexts as well. We were well aware that we were possibly
assuming a risk of loss when we lent to stabilize the systemically important firms of Bear Stearns
and American International Group (AIG). Unfortunately, at the time, alternative mechanisms
were not available and we lent with the explicit support of the Secretary of the Treasury,
including a letter from him acknowledging the risks.
An important task before us now is to assess the effectiveness of these actions. Not
surprisingly, rigorous studies that evaluate the extent to which the emergency liquidity facilities
contributed to improved financial conditions are just beginning to emerge. Nonetheless, market

-7reactions to the announcement of the emergency facilities, anecdotal evidence, and a number of
the studies we do have suggest that the facilities forestalled potentially much worse outcomes
and encouraged improvements. For example, some asset-backed securities (ABS) spreads, such
as those for consumer ABS and commercial mortgage-backed securities, narrowed significantly
following the creation of the TALF, and activity in ABS markets has picked up. While the
overall improvement in the economic outlook has no doubt contributed to the improvement in
ABS markets, it does appear that the TALF helped to buoy the availability of credit to firms and
households and thus supported economic activity. Indeed, following the kick-start from the
TALF, a number of these markets are now operating without any governmental backing.
Another example is the reduction in pressures in U.S. dollar funding markets (as evidenced by
the sharp narrowing of spreads between Libor (London interbank offered rates) and OIS
(overnight index swap) rates and the decline in premiums paid for U.S. dollars in foreign
exchange swap markets). These developments followed the establishment of the Term Auction
Facility (which auctioned discount window credit to depository institutions) and also of liquidity
swaps between the Federal Reserve and foreign central banks, which enabled those banks to lend
dollars to commercial banks in their jurisdictions. Our willingness to lend in support of the
commercial paper and asset-backed commercial paper markets helped to stem the runs on money
market funds and other nonbank providers of short-term credit. Of note, usage of these
emergency liquidity facilities declined markedly as conditions in financial markets improved,
indicating that they were indeed priced at a penalty to more normal market conditions. They
were successfully closed, suggesting that market participants had not become overly reliant on
these programs and were able to regain access to funding markets. Except for the TALF and the
special Bear Stearns and AIG loans, all were repaid without any losses to the Federal Reserve.

-8The funding markets evidently remain somewhat vulnerable, however. Just this week, with the
reemergence of strains in U.S. dollar short-term funding markets in Europe, the Federal Reserve
reestablished temporary U.S. dollar liquidity swap facilities with the Bank of Canada, the Bank
of England, the European Central Bank, the Bank of Japan, and the Swiss National Bank. 4
Lessons for Handling Future Liquidity Disruptions
What lessons can be drawn from the Federal Reserve’s experience in the financial crisis
when designing a toolbox for dealing with future systemic liquidity disruptions? First, the crisis
has demonstrated that, in a financial system so dependent on securities markets and not just
banks for the distribution of credit, our ability to preserve financial stability may be enhanced by
making sure the Federal Reserve has authority to lend against good collateral to other classes of
sound, regulated financial institutions that are central to our financial markets--not on a routine
basis, but when the absence of such lending would threaten market functioning and economic
stability. Thus, it would seem that authority similar to that provided by section 13(3) will
continue to be necessary.
Second, we recognize that holding open this possibility is not without cost. With credit
potentially available from the Federal Reserve, institutions would have insufficient incentives to
manage their liquidity to protect against unusual market events. Hence, emergency credit should
generally be available only to groups of institutions that are tightly regulated and closely
supervised to limit the moral hazard of permitting access to the discount window, even when
such access is not routinely granted. If the Federal Reserve did not directly supervise the
4

See Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (2010), “Federal Reserve, European Central Bank, Bank of
Canada, Bank of England, and Swiss National Bank Announce Re-establishment of Temporary U.S. Dollar
Liquidity Swap Facilities,” press release May 9,
www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/20100509a.htm; and Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System (2010), “FOMC Authorizes Re-establishment of Temporary U.S. Dollar Liquidity Swap
Arrangement with the Bank of Japan,” press release, May 10,
www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/20100510a.htm.

-9institutions that would potentially receive emergency discount window credit, it would need an
ongoing and collaborative relationship with the supervisor. The supervisor should ensure that
any institution with potential access to emergency discount window credit maintained
conservative liquidity policies. The supervisor would also provide critical insight into the
financial condition of the borrower and the quality of the available collateral and, more
generally, whether lending was necessary and appropriate. Most importantly, no such institution
should be considered too big or too interconnected to fail, and any losses should be shouldered
by shareholders and other providers of capital, by management, and, where consistent with
financial stability, by creditors as well.
Third, the United States needs a resolution facility for systemically important institutions
that meets the criteria I just enunciated. That authority must have access to liquidity to stabilize
situations where necessary, but the fiscal authorities, not the central bank, should be the ones
deciding whether to take on the credit risk of lending to troubled institutions in order to forestall
financial instability.
Fourth, transparency about unusual liquidity facilities is critical. The public
appropriately expects that when a central bank takes innovative actions--especially actions that
might appear to involve more risk than normal lending operations--then it will receive enough
information to judge whether the central bank has carried out the policy safely and fairly. The
required degree of transparency might well involve more-detailed types of reporting than for
normal, ongoing, lending facilities.
Finally, the problem of discount window stigma is real and serious. The intense caution
that banks displayed in managing their liquidity beginning in early August 2007 was partly a
result of their extreme reluctance to rely on standard discount mechanisms. Absent such

- 10 reluctance, conditions in interbank funding markets might have been significantly less stressed,
with less contagion to financial markets more generally. Central banks eventually were able to
partially circumvent this stigma by designing additional lending facilities for depository
institutions; but analyzing the problem, developing these programs, and gathering the evidence to
support a conclusion that they were necessary took valuable time. Going forward, if measures
are adopted that could further exacerbate the stigma of using central bank lending facilities, the
ability of central banks to perform their traditional functions to stabilize the financial system in a
panic may well be impaired.
Monetary Policy and the Zero Bound
The Federal Reserve and other central banks reacted to the deepening crisis in the fall of
2008 not only by opening new emergency liquidity facilities, but also by reducing policy interest
rates to close to zero and taking other steps to ease financial conditions. Such rapid and
aggressive responses were expected to cushion the shock to the economy by reducing the cost of
borrowing for households and businesses, thereby encouraging them to keep spending.
After short-term rates reached the effective zero bound in December 2008, the Federal
Reserve also acted to shape interest rate and inflation expectations through various
communications. At the March 2009 meeting, the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC)
indicated that it viewed economic conditions as likely to warrant “exceptionally low” levels of
the federal funds rate for an “extended period.” This language was intended to provide more
guidance than usual about the likely path of interest rates and to help financial markets form
more accurate expectations about policy in a highly uncertain economic and financial
environment. By noting that the federal funds rate was likely to remain at “exceptionally low”

- 11 levels for an “extended period,” the FOMC likely was able to keep long-term interest rates lower
than would otherwise have been the case.
To provide the public with more context for understanding monetary policy decisions,
Board members and Reserve Bank presidents agreed in late 2007 to prepare more frequent
forecasts covering longer time spans and explain those forecasts. In January 2009, the
policymakers also added information about their views of the long-run levels to which economic
growth, inflation, and the unemployment rate were likely to converge over time. The additional
clarity about the long-run level for inflation, in particular, likely helped keep inflation
expectations anchored during the crisis. Had expectations followed inflation down, real interest
rates would have increased, restraining spending further. Had expectations risen because of
concern about the Federal Reserve’s ability to unwind the unusual actions it was taking, we
might have needed to limit those actions and the resulting boost to spending.
Given the severity of the downturn, however, it soon became clear that lowering shortterm policy rates and attempting to shape expectations would not be sufficient alone to counter
the macroeconomic effects of the financial shocks. Indeed, once the Federal Reserve reduced the
federal funds rate to zero, no further conventional policy easing was possible. The Federal
Reserve needed to use alternative methods to ease financial conditions and encourage spending.
Thus, to reduce longer-term interest rates, like those on mortgages, the Federal Reserve initiated
large-scale purchases of longer-term securities, specifically Treasury securities, agency
mortgage-backed securities (MBS), and agency debt. All told, the Federal Reserve purchased
$300 billion of Treasury securities, about $175 billion of agency debt obligations, and $1.25
trillion of agency MBS. In the process, we ended up supplying about $1.2 trillion of reserve

- 12 balances to the banking system--a huge increase from the normal level of about $15 billion over
the few years just prior to the crisis.
How effective have these various steps been in reducing the cost of borrowing for
households and businesses while maintaining price stability? Central banks have lots of
experience guiding the economy by adjusting short-term policy rates and influencing
expectations about future policy rates, and the underlying theory and practice behind those
actions are well understood. The reduction of the policy interest rate to close to zero led to a
sharp decline in the cost of funds in money markets--especially when combined with the creation
of emergency liquidity facilities and the establishment of liquidity swaps with foreign central
banks that greatly narrowed spreads in short-term funding markets. Event studies at the time of
the release of the March 2009 FOMC statement (when the “extended period” language was first
introduced) indicate that the expected path of policy rates moved down substantially. Market
participants reportedly interpreted the characterization of the federal funds rate as likely to
remain low for “an extended period” as stronger than the “for some time” language included in
the previous statement. 5 Nonetheless, the extended period language has not prevented interest
rates and market participants’ expectations about the timing of exit from the zero interest rate
policy from reacting to incoming economic information, though each repetition of the extended
period language has appeared to affect those expectations a little.
By contrast, the economic effects of purchasing large volumes of longer-term assets, and
the accompanying expansion of the reserve base in the banking system, are much less well
understood. One question involves the direct effects of the large-scale asset purchases
5

A clear-cut assessment of the effects of the introduction of the “extended period” language, however, is
complicated by the fact that the FOMC also decided at the March 2009 meeting to increase the size of the Federal
Reserve balance sheet further by purchasing up to an additional $750 billion of agency MBS, bringing its total
purchases of these securities to up to $1.25 trillion, and to increase its purchases of agency debt by up to $100 billion
to a total of up to $200 billion.

- 13 themselves. The theory behind the Federal Reserve’s actions was fairly clear: Arbitrage
between short- and long-term markets is not perfect even when markets are functioning
smoothly, and arbitrage is especially impaired during panics when investors are putting an
unusually large premium on the liquidity and safety of short-term instruments. In these
circumstances, purchasing longer-term assets (and thus taking interest rate risk from the market)
pushes up the prices of the securities, thereby lowering their yields. But by how much and for
how long? Good studies of these sorts of actions also are sparse. Currently, we are relying in
large part on event studies analyzing how much interest rates declined when purchases were
announced in the United States or abroad. According to these studies, spreads on mortgagerelated assets fell sharply on November 25, 2008, when the Federal Reserve announced that it
would initiate a program to purchase agency debt and agency MBS. A similar pattern for
Treasury yields was observed following the release of the March 2009 FOMC statement, when
purchases of longer-term Treasury securities were announced. 6 Effectiveness, however, is hard
to quantify, partly because we are uncertain about how, exactly, the purchases put downward
pressure on interest rates. My presumption has been that the effect comes mainly from the total
amount we purchase relative to the total stock of debt outstanding. However, others have argued
that the market effect derives importantly from the flow of our purchases relative to the amount
of new issuance in the market. Some evidence for the primacy of the stock channel has
accumulated recently, as the recent end of the MBS purchase program does not appear to have
had significant adverse effects in mortgage markets.

6

Treasury yields also declined notably on December 1, 2008, following a speech by the Chairman noting that the
Federal Reserve could purchase longer-term Treasury securities in substantial quantities. See Ben S. Bernanke
(2008), “Federal Reserve Policies in the Financial Crisis,” speech delivered at the Greater Austin Chamber of
Commerce, Austin, Tex., December 1, www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20081201a.htm.

- 14 A second issue involves the effects of the large volume of reserves created as we
purchased assets. The Federal Reserve has funded its securities purchases by crediting the
accounts that banks hold with us. In explanations of our actions during the crisis, we have
focused on the effects of our purchases on the prices of the assets that we bought and on the
spillover to the prices of related assets, as I have just done. The huge quantity of bank reserves
that were created has been seen largely as a byproduct of the purchases that would be unlikely to
have a significant independent effect on financial markets and the economy. This view,
however, is not consistent with the simple models in many textbooks or the monetarist tradition
in monetary policy, which emphasizes a line of causation from reserves to the money supply to
economic activity and inflation. According to these theories, extra reserves should induce banks
to diversify into additional lending and purchases of securities, reducing the cost of borrowing
for households and businesses, and so should spark an increase in the money supply and
spending. To date, this channel does not seem to have been effective: Interest rates on bank
loans relative to the usual benchmarks remain elevated, the quantity of bank loans is still falling,
and money supply growth has been subdued. Banks’ behavior appears more consistent with the
standard Keynesian model of the liquidity trap, in which demand for reserves becomes perfectly
elastic when short-term interest rates approach zero. But the portfolio behavior of banks might
shift as the economy and confidence recover, and we will need to watch and study this channel
carefully.
Another uncertainty deserving of additional examination involves the effect of large-scale
purchases of longer-term assets on inflation expectations. The more we buy, the more reserves
we will ultimately need to absorb, and the more assets we will ultimately need to dispose of
before the conduct of monetary policy, the behavior of interbank markets, and the Federal

- 15 Reserve’s balance sheet can return completely to normal. As a consequence, these types of
purchases can increase inflation expectations among some observers who may see a risk that we
will not reduce reserves and raise interest rates in a timely fashion. So far, longer-term inflation
expectations have generally been well anchored over the past few years of unusual Federal
Reserve actions. However, many unsettled issues remain regarding the linkage between central
bank actions and inflation expectations, and concerns about the effect of the size of our balance
sheet are often heard in financial market commentary.
Lesson from Conducting Monetary Policy in a Crisis
It is certainly too soon to fully assess all the lessons learned concerning the conduct of
monetary policy during the crisis, but a few observations seem worth noting even at this early
stage.
First, commitments to maintain interest rates at a given level must be properly
conditioned on the evolution of the economy. If they are to achieve their objectives, central
banks cannot make unconditional interest rate commitments based only on a time dimension.
The Bank of Canada has recently illustrated that need by revising its time commitment based on
changing circumstances. To further clarify that the “extended period” language is conditional on
the evolution of the economy, the FOMC emphasized in the November 2009 statement that its
expectation that the federal funds rate is likely to remain at an “exceptionally low” level for an
“extended period” depended on the outlook for resource utilization, inflation, and inflation
expectations following the anticipated trajectories.
Second, as I previously pointed out, firmly anchored inflation expectations are essential
to successful monetary policy at any time. That’s why central banks have not followed the
standard academic recommendation to set a higher inflation target--either temporarily or, as has

- 16 been recently suggested, over the longer run--to reduce the likelihood of hitting the zero lower
bound. Although I agree that hitting the zero bound presents challenges to monetary policy, I do
not believe central banks should raise their inflation targets. Central banks around the world
have been working for 30 years to get inflation down to levels where it can largely be ignored by
businesses and households when making decisions about the future. Moreover, inflation
expectations are well anchored at those low levels.
Increasing our inflation targets could result in more-variable inflation and worse
economic outcomes over time. Inflation expectations would necessarily have to become
unanchored as inflation moved up. I doubt households and businesses would immediately raise
their expectations to the new targets and that expectations would then be well anchored at the
new higher levels. Instead, I fear there could be a long learning process, just as when inflation
trended down over recent decades. Moreover, a higher inflation target might also mean that
inflation would be higher than can be ignored, and businesses and households may take inflation
more into account when writing contracts and making investments, increasing the odds that
otherwise transitory inflation would become more persistent.
For both these reasons, raising the longer-term objective for inflation could make
expectations more sensitive to recent realized inflation, to central bank actions, and to other
economic conditions. That greater sensitivity would reduce the ability of central banks to buffer
the economy from bad shocks. It could also lead to more-volatile inflation over the longer run
and therefore higher inflation risk premiums in nominal interest rates. It is notable that while the
theoretical economic arguments for raising inflation targets are well understood, no major central
bank has raised its target in response to the recent financial crisis.

- 17 Third, it appears that large-scale asset purchases at the zero bound do help to ease
financial conditions. Our best judgment is that longer-term yields were reduced as a result of our
asset purchases. The lower rates on mortgages helped households that could refinance and
supported demand to help stabilize the housing market. Moreover, low rates on corporate bonds
contributed to a wave of longer-term business financing that has strengthened the financial
condition of firms that could access securities markets and contributed to the turnaround in
business investment.
Fourth, central banks also need to be mindful of the potential effects on inflation
expectations of the expansion of their balance sheet. Most policymakers do not tend to put too
much stock in the very simple theories relating excess reserves to money and inflation that I
mentioned earlier. But we are aware that the size of our balance sheet is a potential source of
policy stimulus, and we need to be alert to the risk that households, businesses, and investors
could begin to expect higher inflation based partly on an expanded central bank balance sheet.
As always, the Federal Reserve monitors inflation developments and inflation expectations very
closely and any signs of a significant deterioration in the inflation outlook would be a matter of
concern to the FOMC.
Fifth, central banks need to have the tools to reverse unusual actions--to drain reserves
and raise interest rates--when the time comes. Confidence in those tools should help allay any
fears by the public that unusual actions will necessarily lead to inflation. And having or
developing those tools is essential to allow aggressive action to ease financial conditions as the
economy heads into recession. In the case of the Federal Reserve, our ability to pay interest on
excess reserves, which we received only in September 2008, is a very important tool that made
us more comfortable taking extraordinary steps when they were needed; it allows us to put

- 18 upward pressure on short-term interest rates even with very elevated levels of reserves. In
addition, we are developing new tools, including reverse repurchase agreements and term
deposits that will allow us to drain significant quantities of reserves when necessary.
Finally, let me close with some comments on a “lesson learned” that some observers have
emphasized--that long periods of low interest rates inevitably lead to financial imbalances, and
that the Federal Reserve should adjust its policy setting to avoid the buildup of such imbalances.
As I have indicated at other times, I don’t think we know enough at this point to answer with any
confidence the question of whether monetary policy should include financial stability along with
price stability and high employment in its objectives. Given the bluntness of monetary policy as
a tool for addressing developments that could lead to financial instability, given the side effects
of using policy for this purpose (including the likely increase in variability of inflation and
economic activity over the medium term), and given the need for timely policy action to realize
greater benefits than costs in leaning against potential speculative excesses, my preference at this
time is to use prudential regulation and supervision to strengthen the financial system and lean
against developing financial imbalances. I don’t minimize the difficulties of executing effective
macroprudential supervision, nor do I rule out using interest rate policy in circumstances in
which dangerous imbalances are building and prudential steps seem to be delayed or ineffective;
but I do think regulation can be better targeted to the developing problem and the balance of
costs and benefits from using these types of instruments are far more likely to be favorable than
from using monetary policy to achieve financial stability.
Conclusion
The most severe financial crisis since the Great Depression has caused suffering around
the world. It also has been a difficult learning experience for central bankers. Monetary

- 19 policymakers must ask whether the strategies and tools at their disposal need to be adapted to
fulfill their responsibilities for price and economic stability in modern financial markets. As
with the most interesting questions, the answers aren’t at all clear. But we should use our
experience to foster a constructive discussion of these critical questions, because addressing
these issues will enable central banks to more effectively promote financial stability and reduce
the odds of future crises.