View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
11:00 a.m. EDT
June 16, 2006

The Effects of Globalization on Inflation and Their Implications for Monetary Policy
Remarks by
Donald L. Kohn
Member
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
Federal Reserve Bank of Boston’s 51st Economic Conference
“Global Imbalances – As Giants Evolve”
Chatham, Massachusetts
June 16, 2006

Thank you for the opportunity to participate in this conference on global
imbalances, a topic of growing importance. Although I will touch on global imbalances,
I would like to focus on globalization’s potential influence on inflation and the associated
implications for monetary policy. It seems a natural focus for a policymaker at a central
bank, and, indeed, several of my colleagues on the Federal Open Market Committee
(FOMC) have also addressed this issue in recent months.1 As you would see from
reading their remarks, no consensus has yet emerged about how globalization has been
influencing recent inflation developments, and part of my intention today is to illustrate
some of the considerable challenges that are involved in attempting to identify the extent
to which the recent pickup in the pace of global economic integration has influenced
inflation dynamics in the United States.2
Of course, the trend toward greater international integration of product and
financial markets has been established for quite a while; the share of U.S. economic
activity involved in international trade (measured by nominal exports plus imports as a
share of nominal gross domestic product) has been rising since the early 1970s.
However, this trend has accelerated markedly over the past fifteen years or so. In
particular, the economies of eastern Europe became more integrated into the global
economy, and China, India, and some other East Asian market economies have emerged
as important players in the global trading system.

1

For example, Richard W. Fisher (2005), “Globalization and Monetary Policy,” Warren and Anita
Marshall Lecture in American Foreign Policy, Harvard University, November 3; and Janet L. Yellen
(2006), “Monetary Policy in a Global Environment,” speech delivered at The Euro and the Dollar in a
Globalized Economy Conference, University of California at Santa Cruz, May 27.
2
Deb Lindner and William Wascher, of the Board’s staff, contributed to these remarks. The
views expressed are my own and are not necessarily shared by my colleagues on the Board or the FOMC.

-2Although inflation is ultimately a monetary phenomenon, it seems natural to
expect, as others have argued, that these developments would have exerted some
downward pressure on inflation in the United States. The opening up of China and India,
in particular, represents a potentially huge increase in the global supply of mainly lowerskilled workers. And it is clear that the low cost of production in these and other
emerging economies has led to a geographic shift in production toward them--not just
from the United States but also from other formerly low-cost producers such as Mexico,
Korea, Singapore, and Taiwan. 3 Trade surpluses in China and in other East Asian
countries have increased sharply over the past decade, and from a U.S. perspective, the
ratio of imported goods to domestically produced goods has accelerated noticeably in
recent years.
However, the extent of the disinflationary effect of this shift in the pace of
globalization is less obvious. Many U.S. goods and most services are still produced
domestically with little competition from abroad. In addition, the significant expansion
of production in China and elsewhere has put substantial upward pressure on the prices of
oil and other commodities, many of which are imported for use as inputs to production in
the United States. Indeed, the effects of globalization on domestic inflation need not
even be negative, especially in today’s environment of strong global growth.
One challenge in assessing the effect of increased globalization is the lack of
research on this issue. At a research conference on modeling inflation held at the Federal
Reserve Board last fall, none of the papers even touched on issues related to

3

See, for example, International Monetary Fund (2005), “Mexico: Staff Report for the 2005
Article IV Consultation,” October 2005; and Alan G. Ahearne, John G. Fernald, Prakash Loungani, and
John W. Schindler (2003), “China and Emerging Asia: Comrades or Competitors?” International Finance
Discussion Paper 2003-789 (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, December).

-3globalization. And, although some new and interesting research is emerging from places
like the International Monetary Fund and the Bank for International Settlements, much of
this work is still quite preliminary. 4 Nevertheless, the existing research does highlight
several channels through which globalization might have helped to hold down domestic
inflation in recent years. These channels include the direct and indirect effects on
domestic inflation of lower import prices, a heightened sensitivity of domestic inflation to
foreign demand conditions (and perhaps less sensitivity to domestic demand conditions),
downward pressure on domestic wage growth, and upward pressure on domestic
productivity growth.5
In trying to clarify my own thinking about the likely magnitude of these effects, I
find that a useful starting point is a simple reduced-form equation that attempts to explain
movements in inflation and then to ask whether and how the statistical relationships
embedded in this equation have been affected by globalization. The equation is a
standard one in use at the Board and elsewhere. It relates core consumer price inflation-using, say, the index for core personal consumption expenditures (PCE) or the core
consumer price index (CPI)--to resource utilization, lagged inflation, changes in relative
prices of food and energy, and changes in relative import prices. Using this framework,
we can look for the effect of globalization in several ways. First, we can look for
influences that are directly controlled for in the model--notably the influence on domestic
inflation of changes in import prices. Second, we can look for evidence of globalization4

Thomas Helbling, Florence Jaumotte, and Martin Sommer (2006), “How Has Globalization
Affected Inflation?” IMF World Economic Outlook (Washington: IMF, April), chapter 3; Claudio Borio
and Andrew Filardo (2006), “Globalization and Inflation: New Cross-Country Evidence on the Global
Determinants of Domestic Inflation,” unpublished paper, Bank for International Settlements, March.
5
Ken Rogoff also argues that globalization has increased the incentives for central banks to keep
inflation low (Kenneth S. Rogoff, 2003, “Globalization and Global Disinflation,” in Monetary Policy and
Uncertainty: Adapting to a Changing Economy,” a symposium sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of
Kansas City, pp. 77-112.)

-4related structural change in the model by examining the stability of the parameter
estimates. Third, we can see whether we have omitted from the standard model any
variables that might be interpreted as representing changes in globalization. And, finally,
we can look for evidence of model errors that would be consistent with the hypothesis
that globalization has been restraining inflation. I will focus in particular on the past five
years or so, which, judging from the data on U.S. trade shares, is when the pace of
globalization appears to have picked up.
I will start with the import price channel--the hypothesis that increased
globalization has depressed import prices and thus domestic inflation. Importantly, the
estimated strength of this channel should capture not only the direct effects of import
prices on the cost of living in the United States but, also, at least a portion of the indirect
effects of actual and potential import competition on the prices of goods produced
domestically. In the reduced-form model that I’ve just described, the effects of import
prices on inflation show up quite clearly; furthermore, the estimated effects appear to
have increased over time, with the increase apparently stemming primarily from the
upward trend in the share of imported consumer goods in household spending.6
We can use the model to get a rough idea of how relative changes in import prices
have influenced domestic inflation by simulating how core consumer prices would have
behaved if relative import prices had instead remained constant. In particular, the
increase in core import prices since the mid-1990s has averaged about 1-1/2 percentage
points less per year than the increase in core consumer prices. According to the model
simulation, which also builds in the associated reduction in inflation expectations, the
6

As is standard in such models, we use a price measure for “core” imports, defined as imports of
goods excluding energy, computers, and semiconductors. When the change in relative import prices is
weighted by the import share, the coefficient in the model is fairly stable.

-5direct and indirect effects of this decline in the relative price of imports held down core
inflation by between 1/2 and 1 percentage point per year over this period, an estimated
effect that is substantially larger than it would have been in earlier decades. However,
much of the decline in import prices during this period was probably driven by
movements in exchange rates and the effects of technological change on goods prices
rather than by the growing integration of world markets.7
In addition, import prices have risen at about the same average pace as core
consumer prices over the past several years and thus no longer appear to be acting as a
significant restraint on inflation in the United States. This step-up in the rate of change of
import prices obviously reflects, to some extent, recent movements in the dollar,
especially its depreciation in 2004. However, it also reflects large increases in the prices
of a number of imported commodities, which have been attributed in part to the rapid
expansion of activity in China and other Asian countries.
A second hypothesis is that increases in global capacity have held down U.S.
inflation in recent years by limiting the ability of U.S. producers to raise prices in
response to increases in the domestic costs of production. At a basic level, the elevated
profit margins of U.S. producers over the past few years seem inconsistent with this
hypothesis. But it does raise a broader issue about the determinants of inflation--that is,
whether U.S. inflation is now less sensitive to domestic demand pressures and more
sensitive to foreign demand conditions than it was earlier. In the context of the inflation

7

Research at the Board examined the direct effects of Chinese exports on global import prices
from the mid-1990s to 2002 and found only a modest effect of U.S. import prices. Of course, it is possible
that China’s influence on import prices has grown in recent years as its trade share has expanded. Refer to
Steven B. Kamin, Mario Marazzi, and John W. Schindler (2004), “Is China ‘Exporting Deflation’?”
International Finance Discussion Paper 2004-791 (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, January).

-6model, we can examine this issue in two ways. First, we can look for evidence that the
coefficients on the domestic output or unemployment gaps have fallen over time.
Second, we can add a measure of foreign excess demand to the model to see whether it
helps to explain domestic inflation in recent years.
With regard to the first test, we do find evidence that the coefficient on the
unemployment gap has fallen in the United States. In particular, the coefficient from a
model estimated over the past twenty years appears to be about one-third lower than
when the model is run over a forty-year period. Of course, globalization is not the only
potential explanation for this result, and numerous other researchers have cited
persistently low inflation and the improved credibility of monetary policy as having
played a more important role. In fact, in rolling regressions, the timing of the decline in
the sensitivity of inflation to the unemployment gap appears to be too early to be
associated with the more recent acceleration in the pace of globalization.
This aspect of the globalization hypothesis would be bolstered if the decline in the
sensitivity of inflation to domestic demand was accompanied by an increased sensitivity
to foreign demand. Efforts to find such a link have met with mixed results, with some
researchers having found large effects and others having found no effect.8 Our own
analysis of this issue indicates that these results are sensitive to how the foreign output
gap is defined and to how the inflation model is specified, suggesting that any effect may
not be especially strong.

8

Borio and Filardo (2006) and Gamber and Hung (2001) found that foreign resource utilization
had sizable effects on U.S. inflation, while Tootell (1998) found little to no effect. Refer to Borio and
Filardo, ”Globalization and Inflation”; Edward N. Gamber and Juann H. Hung (2001), “Has the Rise in
Globalization Reduced U.S. Inflation in the 1990s?” Economic Inquiry, vol. 39 (January), pp. 58-73; and
Geoffrey M. B. Tootell (1998), “Globalization and U.S. Inflation,” Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, New
England Economic Review (July/August), pp. 21-33.

-7Similarly, the evidence that globalization has helped to restrain unit labor costs in
recent years is mixed. One hypothesis is that the increase in the supply of low-skilled
workers associated with the emergence of China and other East Asian countries as lowcost centers of production has put downward pressure on the growth of nominal wages in
the United States. However, a model of changes in aggregate labor compensation that is
similar in structure to the price-inflation model that I described earlier does not detect a
stable relationship between measures of globalization (for example, import price changes
or the BIS estimates of the foreign output gap) and aggregate wage dynamics in the
United States. That said, the recent changes in some, though not all, measures of
aggregate compensation seem to have been somewhat lower than such models would
have predicted. Of course, several purely domestic factors could help to account for any
shortfall, such as the aftereffects of the unusually sluggish recovery in job growth early in
this expansion or a possible downward drift in the nonaccelerating-inflation rate of
unemployment. But it also is a pattern that would be consistent with downward pressures
from an expansion in global labor supply. In support of this link, some cross-section
studies have found a relationship between industry wage growth and import penetration,
while the research on wage inequality tends to relate some of the relative decline in
wages of low-skilled workers to trade, although in both types of studies the effects are
generally relatively small. 9 Similarly, research from the Federal Reserve Bank of New

9

See, for example, Helbling, Jaumotte, and Sommer, ”How Has Globalization Affected
Inflation?”; and William R. Cline (1997), Trade and Income Distribution (Washington: Institute for
International Economics).

-8York shows a modest relationship between exchange rate fluctuations and wage growth,
with larger effects evident for the wages of lower-skilled workers.10
A second possibility is that globalization has restrained unit labor costs by raising
productivity. Increasing volumes of trade should bolster productivity as economies
concentrate their resources in those sectors in which they are relatively more efficient.
But I have seen little direct evidence on the extent to which globalization may have
boosted aggregate productivity growth in the United States in recent years. Nevertheless,
research at the Board finds that multinational corporations, which may have the greater
opportunities to realize efficiencies by shifting production locations, accounted for a
disproportionate share of aggregate productivity growth in the late 1990s.11 And some
microeconomic studies have found a relationship between global engagement and
productivity at the firm level.12 Thus, it seems possible that the persistently high growth
rates of multifactor productivity in recent years may partly be due to the productivityenhancing effects of globalization.
In this regard, I would note that a potential shortcoming of my approach to
assessing the effects of globalization on inflation is that these effects may be too recent to
be captured adequately by the data. That is, it may be too soon for globalization to have
generated statistically observable changes in the parameter estimates or structure of the
standard inflation model. Nonetheless, if the influence of globalization on inflation is as

10

Linda Goldberg and Joseph Tracy (2003), “Exchange Rates and Wages,” unpublished paper,
Federal Reserve Bank of New York.
11
Carol Corrado, Paul Lengermann, and Larry Slifman (2005), “The Contribution of MNCs to
U.S. Productivity Growth, 1977-2000,” unpublished paper, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System.
12
For example, Mark E. Doms and J. Bradford Jensen (1998), “Productivity, Skill, and Wage
Effects of Multinational Corporations in the United States,” in D. Woodward and D. Nigh, eds., Foreign
Ownership and the Consequences of Direct Investment in the United States: Beyond Us and Them
(Westport, Conn.: Quorum Books), pp. 49-68.

-9substantial as many claim, we might have expected the standard model to have had
difficulty in predicting recent inflation trends. For example, if recent increases in world
labor supply are restraining domestic unit labor costs to a significant degree or if there are
other important influences on inflation that are related to globalization but difficult to
quantify in the context of the standard model, we would expect to have seen sizable
model errors over the past several years.
Again, the evidence points to some limited influence of globalization on U.S.
inflation. If we use out-of-sample dynamic simulations of a model for core PCE price
inflation estimated from 1985 through the end of 2001, we find that, although the model
overpredicts inflation over the past several years, the errors average only 0.1 to 0.2
percentage point per year, considerably less than one might have expected given the
anecdotes in the popular press. In contrast, the forecast errors from a model of core CPI
inflation are larger (averaging roughly 1/2 to 1 percentage point per year since mid2001), perhaps suggestive of some influence from globalization.
What do I conclude from all of this evidence? My own assessment is that, quite
naturally, the greater integration of the U.S. economy into a rapidly evolving world
economy has affected the dynamics of inflation determination. Unfortunately, huge gaps
and puzzles remain in our analysis and empirical testing of various hypotheses related to
these effects. But, for the most part, the evidence seems to suggest that to date the effects
have been gradual and limited: a greater role for the direct and indirect effects of import
prices; possibly some damping of unit labor costs, though less so for prices from this
channel judging from high profit margins; and potentially a smaller effect of the domestic
output gap and a greater effect of foreign output gaps, but here too the evidence is far

- 10 from conclusive. In particular, the entry of China, India, and others into the global
trading system probably has exerted a modest disinflationary force on prices in the
United States in recent years.
Moreover, we should recognize that these disinflationary effects could dissipate
or even be reversed in coming years. They reflect, at least in part, the global imbalances
that are the subject of this conference, rather than just the integration of emerging-market
economies into the global trading system. For example, the fact that China and some
other emerging-market economies have resisted upward pressure on their exchange rates
and are running trade surpluses has undoubtedly contributed to their disinflationary
effects on the rest of the world. The prices of their exports are lower than they would be
if market forces were given greater scope in foreign exchange markets, and they are
supplying more goods and services to the rest of the world than they themselves are
demanding. These imbalances are not likely to be sustained indefinitely. The elevated
rates of national saving in these economies--and, in some, relatively restrained rates of
investment--are not likely to persist in the face of ongoing improvements in the
functioning of their financial markets, increases in the depth of their product markets, and
fuller development of economic safety nets. As individuals in these countries are
increasingly drawn to investing at home and consuming more of their wealth and as their
real wages catch up to past productivity gains, the upward pressures on their currencies
will intensify, their demand will come into better alignment with their capacity to
produce, cost advantages will decline, and these economies will exert less, if any,
downward pressure on inflation in the United States.

- 11 This observation brings me to my final point, which is about monetary policy.
Clearly, the greater integration of the world’s economies does leave the United States
more open to influences from abroad. In one sense, a more open economy may be more
forgiving as shortfalls or excesses in demand are partly absorbed by other countries
through adjustments of our imports and exports. And, to the extent that the United States
can draw upon world capacity, the inflationary effect of an increase in aggregate demand
might be damped for a time. But we are also subject to inflationary forces from abroad,
including those that might accompany a shift to a more sustainable pattern of global
spending and production, or those that might emanate from rising cost and price
pressures. Moreover, a smaller response of inflation to domestic demand also implies
that reducing inflation once it rose could be difficult and costly. And, from another
perspective, integrated financial markets can exert powerful feedback, which may be less
forgiving of any perceived policy error. For example, if financial market participants
thought that the FOMC was not dedicated to maintaining long-run price stability--a
notion that I can assure you is not correct--they would be less willing to hold dollardenominated assets, and the resulting decline in the dollar would tend to add to
inflationary pressures. Clearly, policymakers need to factor into their decisions the
implications of globalization for the dynamics of the determination of inflation and
output.
In the end, however, policymakers here and abroad cannot lose sight of a
fundamental truth: In a world of separate currencies that can fluctuate against each other
over time, each country’s central bank determines its inflation rate. If the FOMC were to
allow the U.S. economy to run beyond its sustainable potential for some time, inflation

- 12 would eventually rise. And, this pickup would become self-perpetuating if it became
embedded in inflation expectations. Thus, while a better understanding of the
implications of globalization will aid in our understanding of inflation dynamics, it is also
clear that such developments do not relieve central banks of their responsibility for
maintaining price and economic stability.