View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Central Bank Talk: Does It Matter and Why?*

Donald L. Kohn
and
Brian P. Sack

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
Washington, DC 20551

Abstract
Statements released by the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC)
and congressional testimony by Chairman Greenspan are found to
significantly affect market interest rates, indicating that central bank
"talk" conveys important information to market participants. These
effects arise not only because the statements provide information about
the near-term policy inclinations of the FOMC but also because the
statements convey information about the outlook for the economy. By
contrast, statements raising questions about asset valuations typically
have not generated a significant response of those asset prices.

May 23,2003

* The opinions expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of
other members of the Federal Reserve Board or its staff. We thank Vincent Reinhart, Athanasios
Orphanides, and participants of a Federal Reserve Board research group for comments. Jeffrey Slone
provided exceptional research assistance.

1. Introduction

Central banks around the world have become considerably more transparent over
the past decade. A key element of this increased transparency has been more extensive
efforts by central banks to communicate their views about the economic outlook, the
important elements shaping that outlook, and the possible consequences for monetary
policy.
Chuck Freedman has played a leading role in highlighting the potential benefits of
this type of communication and realizing them in practice (see, for example, Freedman
(1996,2002)). He has stressed the value of transparency for improving the public's
understanding and support of monetary policy and the democratic accountability of the
central bank. In addition, he has emphasized that transparency can enhance the
effectiveness of policy by fostering behavior in wages and prices and in financial markets
that should help the central bank achieve its objectives of stabilizing prices and damping
fluctuations in economic activity. Chuck has not just theorized about transparency-he
has actively promoted it in his work at the Bank of Canada and in his collaboration with
central bankers around the world. In his writings and conversations, Chuck stimulates
the debate by probing and questioning practices in Canada and in other countries-what
works and what doesn't, what helps clarify and what might confuse, and in what ways
transparency helps economies perform better. In was in this spirit that we undertook the
research for this paper.
Of course, the potential benefits of central bank "talk" will only be realized if
private agents pay attention to what the central bank has to say. It is not obvious, a priori,
in what ways statements by the central bank have a role in shaping the expectations of
investors and other private agents. Investors presumably read statements for information
about the near-term policy inclinations of the central bank-an area in which the central
bank will know more than the private sector and can have new information to impart.
Statements might also convey shifts in the central bank's views of the economic outlook
and the associated risks. But whether central bank statements also influence investors'
own expectations for the economy or asset valuations is not so clear. After all, the
economic information available to the central bank is typically available to the public as
well. Nevertheless, central bank statements may lead investors to update their own

1

expectations to the extent that they perceive the central bank as being effective at
assessing and forecasting economic conditions or asset prices. Overall, the extent to
which central bank statements provide information to private agents is a question that
must be answered empirically.
This paper addresses this topic by looking for effects from three types of
communication by the Federal Reserve since the beginning of 1989-statements released
by the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), congressional testimony by Chairman
Greenspan, and speeches given by Chairman Greenspan. We first investigate whether
these forms of central bank talk have had identifiable effects on various financial
variables, independent of the effects of policy actions that coincided with them. The
results indicate that FOMC statements and congressional testimony by Chairman
Greenspan have had a considerable influence on short- and intermediate-term interest
rates.
We then turn to determining the underlying reasons for these effects. The most
obvious explanation is that the statements may be seen as partly revealing the near-term
policy inclinations of the FOMe. We attempt to determine whether, in addition, some of
the effects arise because the statements convey information about the economic outlook.
Lastly, we consider whether a smaller set of statements in which Chairman Greenspan
raised questions about the valuations of particular assets caused those asset prices to
adjust.
This work is a first step in a research program to provide central banks with useful
evidence on what kinds of "talk" are most successful for realizing the potential benefits
of transparency. Our findings raise a number of issues regarding the use of statements by
central banks. Among those, we consider whether statements provide the central bank
with an additional policy instrument that has a degree of independence from its actions.
In addition, we discuss whether the effects of statements depend on the type of statement,

including whether investors focus on simple balance-of-risk assessments to a greater
extent than the more detailed language of other statements. Lastly, our results speak to
the issue of whether central banks can "talk down" (or "talk up") particular asset prices
that they feel may be incorrectly valued.

2

2. Three Types of Communication by the FOMC
The Federal Reserve, like other central banks around the world, communicates
with the public through a variety of channels. In this paper, we focus on three types of
central bank "talk" that we believe to be influential: FOMC statements released
immediately following policy meetings or intermeeting policy actions, congressional
testimony by Chairman Greenspan, and major speeches by Chairman Greenspan. In this
section we describe each of these in more detail. For most of the analysis that follows,
we consider Federal Reserve communication that took place between January 3, 1989,
and April 7,2003.

FOMe Statements

Policy statements that accompany FOMC actions or meetings are an important
form of communication by the FOMC, given that they are released frequently and that
they receive intense scrutiny by market participants. Of course, the timing and content of
these statements have changed over time, as described in Table 1. From January 1989 to
December 1993, the FOMC typically relied on open market operations, rather than
statement, to signal shifts in the stance of monetary policy. On most occasions over this
period, market participants were able to identify policy changes in a timely manner, but
they were not provided with any rationale for those changes. The exceptions were
changes in the federal funds rate that accompanied changes in the discount rate. In those
instances, the Federal Reserve Board would release a press release with a short rationale
for the discount rate change, which presumably also explained the federal funds rate
change. 1
From February 1994 to November 1998, the FOMC began releasing statements
that accompanied changes in the federal funds rate. 2 Those statements offered a brief
description of the rationale for the policy action. The statements did not, however,
include an explicit assessment of the risks going forward. Market participants could learn
about the near-term policy inclination of the FOMC, or the so-called "policy tilt," by

1 In this paper we use the term FOMe statements loosely, since they include statements that were issued by
the Federal Reserve Board with discount rate changes; our sample contains eight such statements.
2 Those statements began to explicitly reference the federal funds rate only in July 1995. Even before then,
though, the level of the funds rate target was well known.

3

reading the minutes that were released after the subsequent FOMC meeting, but those
minutes were typically viewed as being too stale to provide much significant information.
At its December 1998 meeting, the FOMC implemented an important change in
its disclosure practices. In addition to releasing statements accompanying policy actions,
the FOMC decided to release statements when "it wanted to communicate to the public a
major shift in its views about the balance of risks or the likely direction of future policy."
It first did so at the May 1999 FOMC meeting, when it announced a policy tilt toward

tightening, and it subsequently released a statement indicating its policy tilt at every
policy meeting over the remainder of the year.
FOMC disclosure policy changed again in January 2000, when the Committee
announced that a statement would be released after every FOMC meeting and would
always include an assessment of the "balance of risks." This balance-of-risks assessment
involved new language that was linked more closely to the Committee's macroeconomic
objectives than to the near-term direction of policy. More specifically, the statement
would indicate whether the risks to the outlook for the economy over the "foreseeable
future" were weighted toward "heightened inflation pressures" or "economic weakness"
or whether those risks were balanced. This policy remained into effect until March 2003,
when the Committee released a statement that refrained from making an assessment of
the balance of risks. At the subsequent meeting, in May 2003 (which falls after the end
of our sample), the Committee again altered its risk assessment to allow the specification
of two-sided risks to both inflation and economic growth.
Our sample includes 114 FOMC meetings and sixty-two changes in the federal
funds rate-twenty-eight of which were intermeeting moves. Grouping FOMC meetings
with intermeeting actions gives us 142 "FOMC decision" days. In total, statements were
released on fifty-six of those FOMC decision days. The amount of information provided
in these statements surely varied over the sample, but no trend was significant enough to
take into consideration, and so we do not make distinctions across these days in the
analysis below?

Our sample includes two statements (March 1994 and April 1994) that conveyed no information beyond
the change in the federal funds rate. Our results are strengthened slightly if we exclude those statements.

3

4

Testimony by Chairman Greenspan
The second form of communication that we consider is congressional testimony
by Chairman Greenspan. The Chairman has testified on a variety of topics in front of
many congressional committees. We will focus on a subset of his testimonies in which
he focused on current economic conditions, the economic outlook, and monetary policy.
The testimonies that seem to receive the most attention are those that accompany each
semiannual Monetary Policy Report to the Congress. Those testimonies focus explicitly
on the state of the economy and, along with the Chairman's answers to questions posed
by the members of the committee before which he appears, receive considerable scrutiny
by market participants. 4 We also consider testimony by Chairman Greenspan before the
J oint Economic Committee and the Senate or House budget committees. Those
testimonies typically take place several times a year and also receive considerable
attention in the financial press, in part because they, too, often discuss current economic
issues. Our sample includes sixty-six testimonies by Chairman Greenspan, of which
twenty-nine accompanied the Monetary Policy Report.

Speeches by Chairman Greenspan
The third type of communication we consider is speeches by Chairman
Greenspan. The Chairman speaks to a variety of audiences and on a large number of
topics. We consider all of his speeches from June 1996 to the end of our sample. 5 Over
that period, Chairman Greenspan gave 123 speeches, or an average of about eighteen per
year. We found no apparent trend in the annual number of speeches that he has given.
Of course, other members of the FOMC give speeches that also convey important
information to market participants, but here we limit our focus to those by Chairman
Greenspan.

This testimony was previously known as the Humphrey-Hawkins testimony because it was required by
the Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978 (sponsored by Senator Hubert Humphrey and
Representative Augustus Hawkins), which has since expired. In 2000, the Congress reinstated a
requirement to provide a report and testimony. The requirement includes two days of testimony. Since the
second day often follows soon after the first and to a large extent contains the same material, we include
only the first day of testimony in our sample.
S The dates of the Chairman's speeches were obtained from the Federal Reserve's public web site,
www.federalreserve.gov. The list of dates is available from the authors.
4

5

3. Does Central Bank Talk Matter?
Our first objective is to determine whether the three types of central bank
communication described in the previous section have conveyed relevant information
about the economy and asset prices to investors and other private agents. To address this
question, we investigate whether Federal Reserve communication (a term we will use to
encompass all three types of communication) has had a significant effect on financial
market variables from January 3, 1989, to April 7, 2003. The financial variables we
consider are the federal funds futures rate expiring three months ahead, eurodollar futures
rates expiring two and four quarters ahead, two- and ten-year Treasury yields, one-year
Treasury forward rates ending one to four years ahead, the S&P 500 index, and the
foreign exchange value of the dollar. 6
The three types of communication considered provide us with a relatively large
set of dates to investigate the effects of central bank talk. As described above, our sample
includes fifty-six days on which the FOMC released a statement with its policy decision,
sixty-six days of testimony by Chairman Greenspan, and 123 days (since 1996) on which
the Chairman gave speeches. We begin by focusing on the effects of FOMC statements.

Effects of FOMe Policy Statements
The primary difficulty in assessing whether FOMC statements have an effect on
financial variables is that no clear way exists to quantify those statements. 7 Considering
this difficulty, we focus on the volatility of the financial variables on days of FOMC
statements. The basic idea is that if policy statements have an effect on the financial
variables, then the volatility of those variables should be higher on the days of policy
statements than it otherwise would be. 8 By focusing on volatility, we can determine

6 The federal funds and eurodollar futures rates are from the Chicago Board of Trade and the Chicago
Mercantile Exchange respectively; the Treasury yields are par off-the-run yields from a yield curve
estimated at the Federal Reserve Board; the Treasury forward rates are also derived from that yield curve;
the S&P index is taken from Bloomberg; and the dollar is a trade-weighted index against major U.S.
trading partners calculated by the Federal Reserve Board.
7 Demiralp and Gtirkaynak (2003) attempt to quantify FOMC statements by conducting a survey.
Specifically, they randomly arrange the statements and ask respondents to evaluate the likelihood of a
policy action at the subsequent meeting based on the statement. Of course, this dimension is only one of
several along which the statements could be quantified.
8 This idea is also pursued by Bomfim and Reinhart (2000), who investigate whether the volatility of
various financial variables on FOMC days has increased since 1994, when the FOMC began releasing

6

whether statements had a significant effect on the financial variables without having to
assign a sign or magnitude to the statements.
A complication arises because FOMe statements have always accompanied a
decision about the setting of the federal funds rate. To control for the effects of
contemporaneous policy actions, we allow each financial variable to respond to the
unexpected component of monetary policy decisions. The unexpected component of
policy decisions, denoted l11fu, is determined from the change in the current month's
federal funds futures contract, as described in more detail in Kuttner (2001):

I11fU

= D I(D -

d) . l11fl ,

(1)

where D is the total number of days in the month, d is the day of the month of the FOMe
decision, and l11fl is the change in the futures rate on the day of the policy decision.
This measure is computed for all days with FOMe meetings and intermeeting actions
over our sample, and it is set to zero for all other days.9
Of course, the financial variables considered may also be significantly affected by
a number of other factors, including macroeconomic data releases. Some of those data
releases took place on the days of monetary policy surprises, thus affecting the volatility
of the financial variables on those days. This consideration may be particularly relevant
for the period before 1994, when a number of FOMe actions took place between
meetings and, often, directly in response to data releases. We address this issue by
allowing the financial variables to also respond to the surprise component of a number of
data releases, in which the surprise is computed as the realized value less the expected
value from a survey conducted by Money Market Services. 10 We denote the ith

statements. They do not find a significant change. However, unlike the analysis below, theirs does not
focus specifically on FOMe days that contained statements, which may account for the differences in our
findings.
9 We exclude the policy easing on the morning of September 17, 2001, because of the disruption in
financial markets around that period.
10 The expected values are the median responses from the most recent Money Market Services survey,
which is typically conducted the Friday before each data release. Some of the macroeconomic surprise
variables begin later in the sample because of availability of the survey data. We set all the surprises to
zero for the three-month period beginning on September 11, 2001, when many of the data releases were
distorted in the aftermath of the terrorist attacks.

7

macroeconomic data surprise

mac~

, which is set to zero for all days that did not involve

that data release.
Following the common event-study approach, we allow the daily change in each
financial variable, L1y, to respond linearly to the macroeconomic data surprises and to the
unexpected component of FOMC policy decisions, as follows:

n

L1YI

= 130 + 131 . L1ff/ + I,,13i . mac~ +1]1'

(2)

i=2

In determining the set of data releases, we include all of those that were found to have a

significant effect on the three-month-ahead federal funds futures contract. This
procedure yields a set of thirteen relevant macroeconomic surprises, which we maintain
for all the financial variables. As an example of the results, Table 2 reports the regression
coefficients for the three-month-ahead federal funds futures rate and the one- to two-year
ahead Treasury forward rate. (In all the results that follow, interest rate changes are
measured in basis points, and changes in equity prices and the exchange rate are
measured in percentage points.)
The error term from equation (1), 1], captures any other factors affecting the
financial variable, including the effects of policy statements. As described above, we are
concerned with whether the volatility of this error term increases on the days of FOMC
statements, which would indicate that those statements contained information that had a
significant effect on the financial variable. Because the specification controls for the
direct effect of the policy surprise in equation (1), the results determine whether
statements have any effect beyond the contemporaneous policy decisions. By
construction, the effect of the statements is orthogonal to the unexpected policy change,
and so any portion of the statement that is correlated with policy actions will instead be
captured by the coefficient

131. 11

Thus, the results may, if anything, understate the

effects of statements.

11 This observation applies to all existing event-study papers as well. However, Bomfim and Reinhart
(2000) find that the response coefficient did not change under the FOMe's new disclosure policy that
began in 1994, suggesting that the correlation is limited.

8

The results are reported in Table 3. The first column shows the variances of the
error term for each financial variable on all non-FOMe days in the sample-that is, days
that did not involve policy actions, meetings, or any of the three types of Federal Reserve
communication. These values represent the typical magnitude of the movements that
arise from all the factors not included in our regressions, such as additional information
about the macroeconomic outlook, shifts in investors' risk preferences, and changes in
the value of liquidity. These factors would be expected to be present on the days of
FOMe statements as well, but the impact of the statement should boost the volatility of
the financial variable above the level that would otherwise have prevailed.
With that in mind, we estimate whether the volatility of the financial variables on
days of FOMe statements increases significantly relative to the level observed over the
week preceding each statement. 12 As reported in the second column of the table, the
variances of many of the financial variables-particularly shorter-term interest ratesincrease significantly and by a large amount on days of FOMe statements. 13
Of course, it could be the case that the volatility of the error term for these
variables tends to be elevated on all days of FOMe policy decisions, regardless of
whether a statement was released or not. To allow for this possibility, we estimate the
shift in volatility on FOMe decision days that did not involve the release of statements.
As indicated in the third column, volatility does not shift on those days, implying that the
systematic increase in volatility reported in the second column is associated with
statements. 14
The most direct measure of the effect of statements is the difference between the
shift in volatility observed on days of FOMe statements and that observed on FOMe
days without statements. Under this measure, as reported in the last column, statements
12 We could have instead compared the volatility on all statement days to that on non-FOMC days.
However, the above procedure better controls for patterns of volatility over the sample. For example,
equity prices are systematically more volatile in the last several years of the sample, when more statements
also happened to be released.
13 We perform this test by regressing the squared residual on a constant, a dummy variable indicating the
week before the policy statement, and a dummy variable indicating the policy statement day. We obtain
similar conclusions using a GARCH-based framework that follows the work of Andersen and Bollerslev
(1997). Those results are available from the authors upon request.
14 The significant negative coefficient on the federal funds futures rate seems to be driven by events in
1989, when that contract likely was not very liquid. If we begin the estimation in 1990, the shift in the

9

have a sizable and very significant effect on near-term interest rates, including federal
funds and eurodollar futures rates, the two-year Treasury yield, and Treasury forward
rates out to two years. One might expect the rates on those instruments in particular to be
the most sensitive to policy statements, given that they are heavily influenced by the
expected path of monetary policy. (In section 4, we investigate in detail the reasons for
the significant effects.) By contrast, FOMC statements do not appear to have a
significant effect on the other financial variables considered, including ten-year Treasury
yields, Treasury forward rates beyond two years, equity prices, and the foreign exchange
value of the dollar-assets for which the effects of near-term monetary policy
expectations may be smaller relative to other influences.
To gauge the importance of these effects, we compare the increase in the variance
of a given instrument attributed to the statement to that induced directly by the realized
monetary policy decision. As reported in the first column of Table 4, unexpected policy
actions have a significant effect on many of the financial variables considered. Federal
funds and eurodollar futures rates move in the direction of the policy surprise, with the
effect moderating as the contract horizon extends out to one year. Similarly, the two-year
Treasury yield and forward rates out to two years respond significantly in the direction of
the policy surprise, while the ten-year Treasury yield and forward rates at longer horizons
respond less strongly. Lastly, equity prices fall in response to a tightening surprise, and
the dollar appreciates. Collectively, these results are qualitatively consistent with those
found in the event-study literature. 15
These estimated responses, along with the variance of the policy surprises
observed over our sample (164 basis points), are used to compute the variances of the
financial variables attributed to their direct response to policy actions. For the threemonth-ahead federal funds futures rate, the direct response to the policy action accounts
for most of the increase in the variance on FOMC days (see the last three columns of
table 4). However, as the period covered by the instrument moves farther ahead, interest

variance on non-statement FOMe days becomes insignificant, while that on statement days remains
positive and strongly significant.
15 Among others, see Bomfim (2003), Kuttner (2001), Rigobon and Sack (2002), and Bernanke and Kuttner
(2003). The response of longer-term interest rates estimated in the present paper is smaller than that
reported in Kuttner (2001). The difference appears to arise because we extend the sample from his ending
date, June 6,2000, to the end of our sample, April 7, 2003.

10

rates are driven to a greater extent by the policy statement. Indeed, at horizons beyond
one year, the response of the Treasury forward rate is driven more by what the FOMC
says than by what it does. In this regard, statements appear to be an important component
of the policy implemented by the FOMe.
One aspect of FOMC statements that receives considerable attention is the
balance-of-risks statement. In light of that attention, we try to determine how much of
the information from policy statements comes from the inclusion of the balance-of-risks
assessment. To do so, we compare the shift in the variances induced by policy statements
that include a balance-of-risks assessment to that induced by statements without a risk
assessment. All statements since 1999 (with the exception of March 2003) have included
some type of risk assessment, and so the difference is determined by comparing the
effects of statements from the 1999-2003 period to those from the 1994-98 period. The
results, which are not shown, indicate no significant difference in the shift in the
variances of the financial variables. That is, statements that did not contain an
assessment of the balance of risks seem to have had an effect on financial variables that
was as large as ones that did contain such an assessment.
This result may be surprising to those who closely watch the market response to
FOMC decisions, because market participants seem to focus quite intently on the
balance-of-risks component of the statement. On some occasions, statements that did not
contain an explicit risk assessment were read by market participants as containing this
type of information. An example is the statement released with the FOMC policy action
in August 1994. Although the FOMC tightened 14 basis points more than expected, the
accompanying statement suggested that no additional policy actions would immediately
follow. This seemingly "neutral" risk assessment sparked a rally in equity markets and a
decline in Treasury yields. But even statements without such an obvious tilt appear to
have generated a considerable response in financial markets.

Effects of Testimonies and Speeches
To measure the effects of the other forms of central bank talk consideredtestimonies and speeches by Chairman Greenspan-we rely on the same methodology.
One difference from the above results is that these forms of communication are typically

11

not accompanied by policy action, and so controlling for the unexpected component of

current policy decisions becomes less important. Nevertheless, given that the model is
estimated over all days in the sample, we continue to control for unexpected policy
actions and economic data surprises. More specifically, we estimate equation (2) as
above and investigate whether the variance of the error term increases on days of
Chairman Greenspan's testimonies to Congress or on days of his speeches.
The results are presented in Table 5. As a reference for comparison, the first
column repeats the results using FOMC statements (from Table 3). As was the case for
FOMC statements, Chairman Greenspan's testimonies to the Congress have had a
significant effect on many of the variables considered, including federal funds and
eurodollar futures rates, the two-year Treasury yield, and Treasury forward rates. In fact,
the estimated increases in the variances of those variables are larger and more significant
for the Chairman's testimonies than they are for FOMC statements. Moreover, the
effects of the Chairman's testimonies extend much farther out the yield curve, with a
significant response found even for the ten-year Treasury yield.
The finding that the Chairman's testimonies have a significant effect on near-term
interest rates is perhaps not surprising, because market participants would presumably
focus on his comments for the same information contained in FOMC policy statements.
However, the fact that significant effects are realized on much longer-term instruments
provides a hint that the testimonies contain somewhat different information than that
found in FOMC statements-a topic we consider in detail in the next section.
The results are much weaker for Chairman Greenspan's speeches. Indeed, we do
not find significant effects on any of the financial variables in this case. The effects of
some of his speeches, however, are likely diluted by the inclusion of other speeches that
were not viewed as containing relevant information. Indeed, the Chairman gives
speeches on a wide range of topics, and the extent to which those speeches touch on the
current economic environment varies considerably. Judging from the effects of his
testimonies, we believe that speeches that address the current or prospective economic
environment are likely to generate a significant market response. Our approach probably
includes enough instances in which he did not address those topics to obscure the effects
of speeches that did.

12

4. Why Does Talk Matter?
The previous section provided statistical evidence that statements by the FOMC
and congressional testimony by Chairman Greenspan have had significant effects on a
number of financial variables, particularly interest rates that span relatively short
horizons. This section takes up the more difficult task of assessing why these forms of
communication have elicited those responses. Most Federal Reserve communication
probably contains some information about both the economic outlook and the expected
near-term path of monetary policy. We attempt to distinguish the effects of these two
components in the first subsection. A much smaller set of statements has addressed a
different topic-the possibility that financial assets were improperly valued. We discuss
those statements and their effects in the second subsection.

Statements about Monetary Policy and the Economy

The significant influence of FOMC statements and testimony by Chairman
Greenspan on short-term interest rates presumably reflects their effects on investors'
expectations for the near-term path of the federal funds rate. These revisions to expected
policy could, to a large extent, be independent of any new information on the economy.
Indeed, FOMC decisions involve considerable judgment and flexibility on the part of the
Committee, and thus policy actions at any given time may be difficult to predict, even
when investors have access to the same data as the Committee. With that in mind,
investors clearly read statements for information about the near-term policy inclinations
of the FOMC, even for a given state of the economy.
However, a portion of the revision to the expected path of monetary policy also
likely reflects the fact that statements convey information about the FOMC's views of
economic conditions. This information takes many forms. Some may pertain to aspects
of the long-run behavior of the economy, including both those that are out of the
influence of the FOMC (such as structural productivity growth) and those that are under
its complete control (such as the desired inflation rate in the long run). The press
coverage, however, leads us to believe that the preponderance of the information gotten
from statements relates to the strength of aggregate demand and inflationary pressures

13

over the next year or two. To simplify our analysis, we limit our focus to this type of
information about the economy.
In the following exercise, we attempt to parse movements in interest rates with
relatively short horizons into the two components just described-one capturing
perceived changes in the near-term policy inclinations of the FOMC (independent of the
near-term economic outlook) and one capturing perceived changes in the FOMC's view
of the economic outlook (and the associated policy response). 16 We will refer to these as
the "policy inclination" component and the "economic outlook" component respectively.
To distinguish these two components, we rely on the following observation: Even
if the two components have the same effect on near-term policy expectations, they would
presumably have very different effects on other asset prices. Consider, for example, a
statement indicating that a policy easing is likely, which generates a response of nearterm policy expectations of a particular magnitude (reflected in the three-month-ahead
federal funds futures rate). If the shift in policy expectations were viewed as a response
to unexpected economic weakness, it might lead to a sizable decline in intermediatehorizon forward rates, as investors would anticipate a drawn-out policy response to the
weaker economic conditions. By contrast, if the shift in policy expectations were seen as
reflecting only the near-term predilection of the FOMC, it would presumably have a
much smaller effect on forward rates, as the movement in the federal funds rate would be
expected to be transitory.
As the example suggests, the effects of FOMC statements can be separated into
these two unobserved components by looking beyond their effect on short-term interest
rates and considering the responses of other financial variables-notably forward rates at
longer horizons. More specifically, in addition to the response of the three-month-ahead
federal funds futures rate, we will consider the response of the Treasury forward rate
covering the period from one to two years ahead. Of course, we could have chosen a
number of other financial variables to use in the decomposition. However, this forward
rate has the advantage of having a significant overall response to policy statements (Table
3) while still having very different responses to the two components considered.

16

As discussed below, we focus on interest rates with relatively short horizons because the effects of

FOMe statements seem to be limited to rates on instruments with maturities of two years or less (Table 3).

14

On days of FOMe meetings and actions, we assume that the change in the two
interest rates, denoted f).ff3 and f)..fwdl, are determined by three unobservable factors,

TJ Pol , TJ econ , and TJ x , according to the following system of equations:

(3)

The first two factors, TJ Pol and TJecon , are the policy inclination and economic outlook
factors, respectively, which are present only on days of FOMe decisions or statements.
The interest rates are also affected by other news, which we capture with an "other"
factor, TJ x , which is present on all days over the sample. I7 The three shocks are assumed
to be orthogonal to one another.
Our earlier results (Table 4) provide estimates of the increase in the variances of
the two interest rates in response to FOMe actions and statements. We can also estimate
the shift in the covariance between them using the same approach. Given the assumed
structure in equation set (3), the shifts in these second moments of the two interest rates
must be fully explained by the two policy-related factors, TJ Pol and TJecon. The effects of
these two factors on the near-term futures rate have been normalized to unity, and the
effects on the Treasury forward rate are given by the parameters a and /3. Thus, we have
four variables (the two impact parameters and the variances of the two factors) to be
estimated from three pieces of information (the shifts in the variances of the two interest
rates and in their covariance). Without any additional information, the problem is not
identified.
We can achieve identification if we can determine the relative responses of the
two interest rates to either the policy inclination component or the economic outlook
component-that is, either the a or /3 parameter. Obtaining a measure of the former is
difficult, as it would require finding unexpected policy actions that are clearly unrelated

17

Realistically, the factor

TJx

is multidimensional. This modification would not affect our results.

15

to the state of the economy. However, an estimate of the latter can be derived on the
basis of the response of asset prices to releases of macroeconomic data. These releases
obviously do not contain any information about independent shifts in the FOMe's policy
inclinations, but they clearly provide information about the economic outlookparticularly about the strength of aggregate demand or the extent of inflationary pressures
that might be expected over the intermediate term.
Recall that in the results above, we estimated the response of the financial
variables to a set of macroeconomic data releases. The results for the federal funds
futures rate and the Treasury forward rate were shown in Table 2. The regression
estimates can be used to determine the movements in those rates predicted by the actual
data releases realized over our sample. This exercise indicates that macroeconomic
shocks collectively have generated a response of the Treasury forward rate that is, on
average, 1.70 times larger than the response of the near-term futures rate. This pattern
likely reflects the fact that monetary policy displays some gradualism, which damps the
expected response of policy in the immediate future. Moreover, this pattern is observed
in response to many different types of data releases, including ones that are primarily
indicative of the strength of aggregate demand and ones that are primarily indicative of
. fl .
18
III atlOn prospects.
We use the relative response of the interest rates to macroeconomic news to pin
down the parameter /3, which is set to 1.70. By calibrating /3 this way, the factor

TJecon

captures a component of policy-related effects that generates relative movements in the
two interest rates identical to those found, on average, in response to macroeconomic
data. We therefore interpret this factor as reflecting changes in investors' perceptions of
the FOMe's outlook for the economy. That is, we assume that when investors revise
their policy expectations in response to a perceived shift in the FOMe's economic
outlook, they build in expectations of a gradual policy response identical to that observed
when data releases cause a change in the economic outlook. 19 Investors might also
18 We find that the response of the forward rate relative to the near-term futures rate is 1.69 for a set of data
releases containing only indicators of the near-term strength of aggregate demand, and 1.88 for a set of data
releases containing only direct indicators of inflation. In fact, for every single data release considered, the
response of the forward rate is larger in magnitude than that of the near-term futures rate.
19 The relative importance of changes in the outlook for the strength of aggregate demand and for
inflationary pressures is determined by the typical magnitudes of the surprises in the macroeconomic data.

16

update their own perceptions about the economic outlook in response to the FOMC
statement, a topic that we will discuss more in section 5.
The factor TJ Pol then captures the other component of policy-related effects-the
near-term policy inclination of the FOMe. The effect of the policy inclination factor, a,
will be estimated from the observed behavior of the two market interest rates on days of
policy actions or statements. With 13 known, it can be shown that the parameter a equals
a

= 13 I(x -1), where
dVar(!!..fwd1) -

13 2 • dVar(!!.ff3)

x = -----''----'------....::..::...--dVar(!!..fwd1) -

13 .dCov(!!.ff3, !!..fwd1)

(4)

In equation (4), dVar(!!.ff3) and dVar(!!..fwd1) denote the increases in the variances of

the two interest rates in response to policy actions or statements, and dCov(!!.ff 3, !!..fwd1)
denotes the shift in the covariance between them.
We begin by applying this approach to the days of FOMC policy decisions. The
increase in the variances of the interest rates on those days comes from two sources-the
direct effect of policy actions and the effect of FOMC statements (Table 3). We apply
the decomposition to the total policy-related effects, or the sum of these components.
The estimate of parameter ais 0.34, a value indicating that revisions to policy
expectations associated with the near-term policy inclinations of the FOMC generate a
smaller response of the year-ahead forward rate. This pattern is consistent with a
perception among investors that such shifts in policy are transitory in nature, which
perhaps is not surprising given that those inclinations are independent of macroeconomic
developments. Note also that the pattern differs considerably from that associated with
shifts in the economic outlook, which have a larger effect at longer horizons.
One can also solve for the variances of the two unobserved components, which
determine their relative importance. Recall that the relative effects of the economic
outlook factor have been imposed on the exercise, while those of the policy inclinations
factor have been estimated. Thus, we are effectively asking whether any element of the
effect of FOMC statements appears identical to the effect of macroeconomic data

17

releases. If FOMC statements do not contain such an element, the exercise would simply
set the variance of the economic outlook factor to zero.
Table 6 reports the variance decomposition of the two interest rates. 20 We first
focus on the policy-related effects on days of FOMC decisions (the first three columns).
The table repeats the total effects of policy actions and statements on the variances of the
two instruments (shown earlier in Table 4) and then breaks down those effects into the
two components discussed above. The results indicate that policy actions are mostly
associated with the near-term policy inclinations of the FOMC; those actions have most
of their effects on near-term interest rates and smaller effects on longer-term rates-a
pattern similar to that of the policy inclination factor. By contrast, the effects of policy
statements are importantly driven by the economic outlook factor, which accounts for a
sizable portion of the effect on the futures rate and nearly all of the effect on the forward
rate. Looking at the effects of policy actions and statements together, we find that the
effects on the near-term futures rate predominantly reflect the policy inclinations of the
FOMC, which is not surprising given that the futures rate is mostly determined by policy
actions. The total policy-related effects on the forward rate are instead primarily
associated with the economic outlook factor, reflecting the importance of policy
statements in determining that rate.
Lastly, we apply the same decomposition to the effect of Chairman Greenspan's
congressional testimony. In doing so, we maintain the value of the parameter a so that
we can interpret the factors in the same manner?l (We do not consider the Chairman's
speeches, since those were not found to generate a significant increase in the variances of
the interest rates.) The results show that the factor associated with the economic outlook
completely dominates-it accounts for more than the total increase in the variance of
both the futures rate and the Treasury forward rate.
In our view, it is unlikely that these testimonies do not contain any perceived hints

of the near-term policy inclinations of the FOMe. However, we do find it plausible that
20 For the near-term futures rate, the proportions are determined directly by the relative variances of the
unobserved components, given that the loadings on each factor are normalized to 1. For the year-ahead
forward rate, the variance induced by each factor is given by its squared loading multiplied by the variance
of the factor.
21 If we re-estimate the parameter a, we get a value close to zero. But because the exercise assigns very
little explanatory power to the policy inclination factor, this parameter may not be estimated very precisely.

18

relative to FOMC statements, the Chairman's testimony tends to focus more extensively
on the intermediate-term outlook for the economy than on the immediate policy
inclination of the FOMe. After all, many of the testimonies, including the semiannual
testimony that accompanies the Monetary Policy Report to the Congress, are explicitly
intended to update the Congress on economic conditions.
The testimonies also touch more frequently on longer-term issues for the
economy, such as structural changes to productivity growth and fiscal policy?2 In that
case, the market response might involve a factor associated with even more persistent
interest rate responses, which the decomposition is forced to group into the economic
outlook component. Given this consideration, the precise results from the decomposition
should be taken cautiously. Nevertheless, one conclusion clearly emerges from the
analysis: The Chairman's testimonies strongly affect market interest rates in a manner
that looks quite different from the effects associated only with perceived changes in nearterm policy expectations.

Statements about Asset Valuations
Less frequently, Chairman Greenspan has made statements that fall into a distinct
category-those that raise questions about the valuation of particular financial assets.
Reviewing speeches and testimonies of the Chairman since the mid-1990s, we found ten
occasions when the Chairman either directly or indirectly warned that equity valuations
were potentially too high, and six occasions when he warned that credit spreads were
potentially too narrow or bank lending terms too generous?3 Our list is not necessarily
comprehensive, although we consulted a fairly large number of documents in our search.
Because the occurrence of such comments is less frequent than statements about
the economy or future policy, we will not employ the methodology used above. Instead,
we simply look at the behavior of those asset prices on the dates of the Chairman's
comments and compare it in each case to the average volatility that had been realized
over the preceding month.
Indeed, we found earlier (Table 5) that longer-term interest rates show some reaction to the Chairman's
testimony but none to FOMC statements.

22

19

The results, shown in Table 7, indicate that these asset prices did not respond in a
consistent way to the Chairman's comments. Of the ten comments on equity valuation,
equity prices moved notably lower on only two occasions-in July 1998 and October
1999. In each of these instances, market participants clearly took note of the Chairman's
comments on valuation, but the decline in equity prices probably cannot be entirely
attributed to those comments. Indeed, in the first instance market participants were also
disappointed that the Chairman did not hint at an imminent cut in the federal funds rate,
while the second instance coincided with a surprisingly sharp jump in the producer price
index. Moreover, the movements in equity prices on all the other days listed are within
the range of two standard deviations of the changes observed over the month preceding
each date (or are outside the range with the opposite sign). For example, the well-known
"irrational exuberance" speech in December 1996 pushed down equity prices, but not by
an unusually large amount.
A similar story emerges for credit spreads. The table shows the response of the
spread between the yield on high-yield bonds and the yield on a comparable Treasury
security, although one should recognize that the Chairman's comments have covered a
much wider range of credit instruments. The yield spread widened significantly on two
of the six dates shown. However, market commentary on those days focused very little
on the Chairman's comments about valuation. Moreover, on two of the other days listed,
the yield spread instead narrowed significantly.
Overall, we conclude that market participants have not reacted strongly to the
Chairman's comments about asset valuations. One possible explanation is that the
statements have not been all that forceful and have in some cases been very indirect.
However, we feel that the more likely explanation is that market participants simply
choose not to strongly update their beliefs about the appropriate valuation of assets based
on the Chairman's comments.

23 We also found one date, March 8, 1995, on which the Chairman commented on the value of the dollar.
However, this is the only occurrence of such a statement over our sample, and we do not include it in the

20

5. Implications for Central Bankers
Previous research has demonstrated that monetary policy actions affect the shape
of the yield curve, and simple observation of financial market behavior indicates that
central bank talk is also important in that regard. This paper has provided evidence on
the extent to which central bank talk matters and on the channels through which it
operates. In this section, we summarize our results and offer some thoughts on related
issues. In doing so, we draw not only on the findings but also on our experience in the
policymaking process at the Federal Reserve.
Our most important finding is that the forms of central bank communication
considered appear to convey relevant information to investors and private agents. Indeed,
the statements that accompany FOMC decisions have had significant effects on the shortand intermediate-term portion of the yield curve and on futures rates at those horizons.
According to our estimates, interest rates with very short horizons respond more to what
the central bank does (the unexpected portion of its policy decisions) than to what it says.
However, at horizons one to two years ahead, FOMC statements account for at least as
much of the movements in interest rates as the policy actions themselves. In addition,
congressional testimony of Chairman Greenspan appears to have had even larger effects
that extend to instruments with longer maturities.
Thus, understanding the effects of statements and determining the manner in
which they could be used should be a topic of foremost interest to central banks. We
have identified two different components of Federal Reserve communication that cause
market interest rates to respond. First, investors presumably read statements for hints
about the near-term policy tactics and intentions of the FOMC, without necessarily
updating their view of the economy or their understanding of the central bank's view of
the economy. We've labeled this component the "policy inclination" of the FOMe.
Second, talk is also a way the Federal Reserve signals a revision to its assessment of the
economic outlook. That revision affects rates further out the yield curve because the
central bank is likely to act on its new outlook-and if it tends to react to such revisions
gradually, the change in intermediate-term rates will tend to be greater than the change in
short-term rates. We've labeled this second avenue the "economic outlook" component.
analysis.

21

We argue that these components may be present in the effects of policy actions as well.
That is, unexpected decisions by the FOMe may cause investors to reassess their views
on the economy in addition to their perceptions of the near-term policy inclinations of the
central bank.
Our decomposition suggests that the effects of FOMe statements arise to a large
extent by conveying information about the economic outlook, while the effects of policy
actions are transmitted primarily by altering perceptions of the FOMe's near-term
inclinations. This pattern has implications for the determinants of interest rates with
different horizons. Movements in very near term interest rates are largely in response to
policy actions and thus are primarily determined by the policy inclination factor. By
contrast, movements in rates at the one- to two-year horizon, which are heavily
influenced by policy statements, are driven to a large extent by changing perceptions of
the FOMe's economic outlook.
The interpretation of the "economic outlook" component raises an important
issue-the extent to which investors update their own views in response to the
information conveyed about the central bank's economic outlook. It is not entirely clear
why a perceived shift in the FOMe's forecast, signaled through words or actions, would
trigger a significant revision in the same direction to the economic forecasts of private
agents. The Federal Reserve has little, if any, information that is not available to the
market. 24 However, private agents may still lend special credence to the economic
pronouncements of the Federal Reserve and other central banks, particularly if the central
bank has established credibility as an effective forecaster of the economy.
The Federal Reserve has been broadly correct on the direction of the economy
and prices over the past two decades, on occasion spotting trends and developments
before they were evident to market participants, and this record has enhanced its
reputation and credibility. Indeed, Romer and Romer (2000) provide statistical evidence
that the Federal Reserve staff forecasts for output and inflation have been more accurate
than private sector forecasts over the past several decades. As discussed in that paper, the
impressive forecasting performance of the Federal Reserve may reflect the fact that it

Although central banks can get information from the exercise of their bank supervisory or market
stability functions, this information is critical primarily in crisis situations.

24

22

devotes considerable resources to analyzing and predicting the course of the U.S.
economy-much more than any other single entity. As a result, at least a part of the
identified effects of the economic outlook component likely reflects revisions to private
forecasts of the economy.
Another reason to infer some updating of private forecasts is the magnitude of the
change in the forward rate one to two years ahead. This rate presumably would not move
as much if market participants thought the central bank was wrong in its assessment,
because they would expect the Federal Reserve to at least partly learn about its error
within a year or two. Instead, this component involves exactly the same term structure
movement as found in response to macroeconomic data releases (which obviously
contain actual economic news rather than perceived FOMe mistakes). Based on these
arguments, it seems likely that investors do at least partly update their own views on the
economic outlook when the FOMe's outlook changes.
Of course, the effects of central bank statements are more complicated than
assumed in this simple decomposition. We believe that the two factors identified are
important components, but we also recognize that statements convey other relevant
information at times. One possibility in countries without explicit inflation targets is that
statements may provide information about the long-run inflation target of the central
bank, information that could have an impact on interest rates with longer maturities?5
Our results did not indicate a systematic response of long-term interest rates to all FOMe
statements taken together. However, the results do not rule out the possibility that market
participants have on several occasions made this type of inference from FOMe
statements. A second complication involves supply shocks, which have played a very
important role in Federal Reserve policy and statements over the past decade. A credible
central bank statement that the level or growth rate of potential output was higher than
markets or the central bank had previously anticipated could have very different
implications for the term structure than one that focused only on the prospects for the
economy over the intermediate term.

25 The statements could also contain information on the relative weights that the central bank places on its
output and inflation objectives. In line with this idea, Ellingsen and SOderstrom (2003) attempt to
decompose monetary policy surprises into those associated with responses to the economy and those
associated with changes in central bank preferences.

23

The decomposition is forced to attribute all of the potential types of information
to one of the two possible factors. As a result, our interpretations of those factors are
somewhat imprecise and should be viewed as only suggestive. Nevertheless, the
decomposition results clearly demonstrate an important characteristic of central bank
statements-that they convey information beyond just the near-term policy inclinations
of the FOMC.
The observation that statements have significant effects on market interest rates
raises the question of whether releasing statements provides the central bank with an
additional policy instrument. In some sense it does, but if so, it is an instrument whose
use is very constrained. The central bank may have some discretion over whether to put
out a statement or not, but it does not have complete discretion over its content-the
statement is constrained to provide an honest assessment of the central bank's outlook for
the economy.
In some circumstances, the temptation for the central bank to shade its

assessments can arise from the very credibility of central bank forecasts. For example, a
central bank that wants to indicate an imminent easing through a statement may be
concerned that the statement will signal to investors that the economy is weak, thereby
damping or even reversing any stimulative effect, say by depressing spending or reducing
equity prices. We do not deny that such situations arise, but neither do we believe that
they present overwhelming difficulties. After all, the statement provides only one piece
of a broad array of information that investors and private agents use in formulating their
views and in making economic decisions. To the extent it does have an effect, the
statement on average should move investors' forecasts closer to the appropriate level.
Because this adjustment would have taken place eventually, the effect of the statement is
just one of timing.
Moreover, central bank statements can be very helpful in particular
circumstances. They can be used to prevent investors from misinterpreting and
overreacting to policy actions, and they can provide corrective information when the
central bank believes that investors are unduly pessimistic or optimistic about the
economic outlook. In regard to the first circumstance, statements can help market
participants differentiate policy actions that respond to a major change in the economic

24

outlook-and therefore might well be followed by others in the same direction-from
those in which the outlook was basically satisfactory but through which the central bank
was seeking greater insurance against a particular outcome. Shaping accurate
expectations about the economy and policy inclinations might be especially important
when the nominal policy rate is very low and the central bank remains concerned about
inadequate demand. In those circumstances, policy cannot as readily adjust through
conventional actions to compensate for market perceptions that don't appropriately
reflect the expectations and the intended strategy of the central bank.
Our results also suggest some interesting conclusions about the types of central
bank statements that influence markets. One finding is that FOMC statements that
contained a balance-of-risks assessment did not generate a larger market response than
did statements without one. This result is somewhat surprising, given that market
commentary seems to focus so much on the risk assessment. Although the risk
assessment attracts a great deal of attention when it is included, it does not appear to be a
necessary ingredient for conveying relevant information to market participants. That is,
market participants do pay attention to the more extensive language that describes the
economic outlook. This conclusion is supported by the sizable effect of Chairman
Greenspan's congressional testimonies, which of course do not convey an explicit
balance-of-risks assessment. Indeed, the effects of those testimonies are found to be
larger and more significant (particularly at longer maturities) than the effects of FOMC
statements, indicating that market participants find useful information in the more
detailed discussions of the state of the economy and the outlook.
We would argue that providing more detailed language has considerable
advantages over a simple, discrete categorization of the risks. A detailed statement,
speech, or testimony can provide a more accurate description of the outlook for the
economy, one that can better describe the various risks, describe how potential outcomes
may be conditional on particular events, and provide the appropriate amount of nuance
and caution regarding the central bank's views. Some of that information unavoidably
gets lost when the central bank tries to describe those views with a simple summary, like
a balance of risks assessment, a point forecast, or a brief statement. The summary can be
given excessive weight by market participants who, in some circumstances, will not

25

recognize the conditionality of the central bank's outlook and its unwillingness to commit
itself to a particular course of action in an uncertain world?6 We recognize, however,
that it may be difficult to get a committee with diverse views to agree on a detailed
statement. In that regard, a short statement that categorizes the outlook, such as the
balance-of-risks assessment, may provide useful information.
We find tentative evidence that one kind of central bank talk didn't matter at alldiscussions of asset price valuations. Indeed, a small set of Chairman Greenspan's
speeches and testimonies that questioned the valuation of particular assets generally had
no identifiable effect on the prices of those assets, suggesting that investors typically do
not update their views about appropriate valuations in response to those comments. This
finding is relevant to the argument, put forward by some, that the Federal Reserve could
have damped the apparent stock market bubble of the late 1990s without actually
adjusting monetary policy itself. According to these results, it would have been difficult,
if not impossible, for the central bank to "talk down" the market, implying that the
FOMC could have influenced stock prices only by using instruments that would have had
broader consequences for the economy.
This last finding is also consistent with the overall conclusion of studies of
foreign exchange market intervention and changes in margin requirements-two
longstanding techniques that central banks have used to signal their assessment that asset
prices had strayed from fundamentals. Those studies generally show that these efforts to
influence asset prices are ineffectual unless they are expected to be backed up by changes
in the stance of monetary policy. Apparently investors have not taken the Chairman's
comments on equity valuations as a signal that policy will be adjusted directly in
response. Indeed, asset prices per se are not in the legislative mandate of the Federal
Reserve except to the extent that they affect macroeconomic stability, and hence the
FOMC typically pays attention to asset prices only in the context of the economic
outlook.
The impotence of the central bank to affect asset valuations contrasts sharply with
the considerable effects of its statements on investors' expectations for monetary policy
The experiences of the Bank of Canada and the Reserve Bank of New Zealand with predicted paths for
monetary conditions indexes that were read too literally by markets also illustrates the difficulties involved

26

26

and their views about the economic outlook. Investors may simply perceive that the
FOMC is much better informed about the near-term track for the economy and monetary
policy than it is about the fair valuation of assets. After all, the FOMC has inside
information about the potential course of monetary policy, and it might also be perceived
as being an effective forecaster of near-term economic conditions. By contrast, many
studies indicate that, in predicting asset prices, it is hard to beat what is already priced
into the market, and Chairman Greenspan himself has publicly questioned whether a
central bank can determine the proper valuation of assets better than the market does. As
a consequence, it is not surprising that investors appear to have ignored warnings form
the Federal Reserve about the level of equity prices.

6. Avenues for Future Research
Overall, investors seem to be quite attentive to central bank statements. Our
results provide some tentative evidence on the nature of the effects of central bank talk.
From a practitioner's standpoint, this is an important topic that warrants extensive
research-the better we understand these effects, the better central banks will be able to
structure their public pronouncements to achieve the benefits of transparency.
We believe that inflation-targeting countries provide some natural experiments on
the differential effects of various kinds of talk. Inflation targeting is typically
accompanied by an emphasis on the release of timely information about the views of the
central bank, and that information often varies fairly widely in terms of detail and
content. The Bank of England, for example, releases several relevant statements,
including a statement from the Monetary Policy Committee, the minutes from its
meetings within the intermeeting period, and an inflation report. An investigation of the
extent to which these different statements affect financial markets, and whether they
seem to convey different types of information, would be of particular interest.
In addition, we have not addressed a topic that is obviously critical to the potential

benefits of central bank statements: whether central banks typically achieve the desired
effect of their statements. Historical experience suggests that it is sometimes difficult to

in relatively simple statements about the future.

27

determine how market participants will interpret a given statement or whether they will
put greater emphasis on particular passages than the central bank intended.
Another consideration is that there may be important interactions between central
bank statements and policy actions. The analysis above focused on statement effects that
were, by assumption, independent of policy actions. It could be the case, for example,
that it is easier to reinforce the effects of a policy action with a statement in the same
direction than it is to convey a message in the opposite direction. Such interactions are
an interesting topic for further research.

7. Conclusions
Central banks will and should be judged on results-whether they achieve price
stability and effectively stabilize economic activity around its potential. Monetary policy
actions are without a doubt the essential ingredient for these results. But we also know
that expectations-about both policy actions and economic conditions-playa central
role in determining economic performance. Our results suggest that central bank
statements, in addition to actions, importantly shape those expectations and thus should
be viewed as a vital component of the monetary policy process.
We find that a portion of the effects of statements-what we call the policy
inclination component-resembles the effects of realized policy actions with some
difference in timing. That is, the policy inclination component generates expectations of
a transitory rate change that more or less match those observed in response to unexpected
policy actions. Thus, statements and policy actions can serve as effective substitutes for
one another, at least in the short run. Indeed, a credible central bank can probably
achieve nearly the same result by implementing a policy action or by promising to
implement that action at the next meeting.
If this policy inclination component was the only source of information present,
releasing statements would probably offer little improvement in social welfare, because
the statements would have only minor effects on the timing of policy effects. However,
our results suggest that statements also contain a component-what we call the economic
outlook component-that looks very different from policy actions. This component
allows statements to serve an additional function-conveying changes in views about the

28

economic outlook-that may be crucial to their welfare benefits. Indeed, it is probably
this information that is the key to achieving much of the benefits of transparency, in that
it allows private agents to better anticipate the course of policy and the economy and, as a
consequence, to behave in a manner that reinforces the effectiveness of policy in
achieving its objectives.
It stands to reason that efforts to improve transparency should be focused on this

second component-elucidating the important elements in the outlook. This is not an
easy task. The economy is complex and evolving in its structure, and it is constantly
subject to unexpected developments. As a consequence, we argue that more detailed
statements have advantages over simple summary statements, which are likely to be
incomplete and potentially misleading. However, this argument may have practical
limitations. One issue is that policy is made by a committee in most countries, a process
that has the advantage of bringing a diversity of views to the policy process but that may
pose challenges to agreement on a detailed statement. Despite this and other challenges,
central banks must continue to extend and improve their use of statements, preferably
with the assistance of additional research in this area. Advances along these lines should
reinforce good monetary policy and enhance social welfare.
While we urge continued efforts to improve central bank statements about the
economic outlook, we find that other types of talk-particularly statements about asset
valuations-are less important. In general, central bank talk appears to be most
influential (and hence potentially effective) when it focuses on issues about which the
central bank is directly concerned and may have relevant information to convey.

29

8. References
Andersen, T. and T. Bollerslev (1997), "Intraday Periodicity and Volatility Persistence in
Financial Markets," Journal of Empirical Finance 4, 115-158.
Bemanke, Ben S. and Kenneth N. Kuttner (2003), "What Explains the Stock Market's
Reaction to Federal Reserve Policy? ," Mimeo, Federal Reserve Board.
Bomfim, Antulio N. (2003), "Pre-Announcement Effects, News Effects, and Volatility:
Monetary Policy and the Stock Market," Journal of Banking and Finance 27, 133-151.
Bomfim, Antulio N. and Vincent R. Reinhart (2000), "Making News: Financial Market
Effects of Federal Reserve Disclosure Practices," Finance and Economics Discussion
Series working paper no. 2000-14, Federal Reserve Board.
Demiralp, Selva and Refet Glirkaynak (2003), "Monetary Policy Shocks from an Interest
Rate Path Perspective," Mimeo, Federal Reserve Board.
Ellingsen, Tore and Ulf Soderstrom, "Monetary Policy and the Bond Market," Mimeo,
Stockholm School of Economics.
Freedman, Charles (1996), "What Operating Procedures Should Be Adopted to Maintain
Price Stability?-Practical Issues," in Achieving Price Stability (Kansas City: Federal
Reserve Bank of Kansas City), 241-285.
Freedman, Charles (2000), "The Value of Transparency in Conducting Monetary Policy,"
Federal Reserve Bank of Saint Louis Review 84, 155-160.
Kuttner, Kenneth N. (2001), "Monetary Policy Surprises and Interest Rates: Evidence
from the Fed Funds Futures Market," Journal of Monetary Economics 47,523-544.
Jones, Charles M., Owen Lamont, and Robin L. Lumsdaine (1998), "Macroeconomic
News and Bond Market Volatility," Journal of Financial Economics 47,315-337.
Rigobon, Roberto and Brian Sack (2002), "The Impact of Monetary Policy on Asset
Prices," NBER Working Paper no. 8794.
Romer, Christina D. and David H. Romer (2002), "Federal Reserve Information and the
Behavior of Interest Rates," American Economic Review 90, 429-457.

30

Table 1
History of FOMe Policy Statements
Dates

Statements Released On:

Risk Assessment:

1/3/89 1 to 12/21/93

Changes in the discount rate

None

2/4/94 to 11117/98

Changes in the federal funds rate

None

12/22/98 2 to 12/21/99

Changes in the federal funds rate
or "major shifts" in the outlook

Included
(Policy Tilt)

1119/00 - presene

All meetings (and intermeeting
changes in the federal funds rate)

Included
(Balance of Risks)

"""""""""'j"""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""

This is the start of our sample.
This change was decided at the 12/22/98 meeting but was not disclosed until the minutes
from that meeting were released on 2/4/99.
3The exception in this period was 3/18/03, when the FOMe released a statement that
did not include a balance of risks assessment.
2

31

Table 2
Effects of Monetary Policy and Economic Data Surprises
on Interest Rates
Federal Funds
Treasury
Futures Rate
Forward Rate
(Three months
(One to two
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .~.~.~~.4:L. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .y..~~.':.~:..~!!:.~~~L. . . . ..
Monetary Policy Surprises

0.62 (12.68)

0.26 (2.60)

Economic Data Surprises (normalized by their standard deviation):
Capacity Utilization
Consumer Confidence
Core CPI
Durable Goods Orders
Employment Cost Index
Advance GDP
Initial Claims
ISM (NAPM)
Nonfarm Payrolls
New Homes
Core PPI
Retail Sales
Unemployment Rate

1.0
1.3
1.2
1.3
2.4
2.0
-0.3
2.1
3.9
0.9
0.7
1.4
-1.6

(4.73)
(3.59)
(3.88)
(3.66)
(5.11)
(2.94)
(2.01)
(6.57)
(8.58)
(4.12)
(2.60)
(3.98)
(3.60)

2.6
3.0
2.4
2.4
4.8
6.5
-0.7
4.8
5.8
1.5
0.8
1.8
-2.3

(4.90)
(5.23)
(3.70)
(4.00)
(4.13)
(2.17)
(2.27)
(8.01)
(7.02)
(2.91)
(1.33)
(2.47)
(3.23)

Table shows the results from a regression of the daily changes in each interest rate on the surprise
components of monetary policy actions and economic data releases over the sample January 4, 1989
to April 7, 2003. Absolute t-statistics are shown in parentheses. Macroeconomic surprises are measured
using the median expectation from a survey conducted by Money Market Services the Friday before
each release. Monetary policy surprises are computed from federal funds futures rates.

32

Table 3
Effects of Policy Statements
n

L1Yt

= 130 + 131' Nft + I,,13i . mac~ +1]t
U

i=2

Var(1]) on
Non-FOMe
Days

Increase in Var(1]) on:
FOMe with FOMe wlo
Statements
Statements

Effect of
Statements

. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . t!2. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .t~2. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .t~2. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . t~2. =. .t~2. . . . . .
Federal Funds Futures:
3 months ahead

12.8

13.7**

-10.4**

24.1 ***

Eurodollar Futures:
2 quarters ahead

32.9

44.5**

-4.3

48.7**

4 quarters ahead

49.9

69.6***

5.2

64.5**

31.1

31.2**

-6.4

37.5**

31.3

18.8

2.4

16.4

23.0

23.7**

-5.3

28.9**

1 to 2 years ahead

48.0

41.3*

-8.5

49.7**

2 to 3 years ahead

49.5

46.8*

3.1

43.7

3 to 4 years ahead

46.3

38.3

9.7

28.7

S&P 500

1.07

-0.04

-0.05

0.01

Dollar

0.16

-0.03

-0.02

-0.01

Treasury Yields:
2-year
lO-year

Treasury Forward Rates:
o to 1 years ahead

~;tri~di~;t~~"~ig;ifi~;;~~";t'th~"1%"i~;~I"n";t"th~"5'%"1~~~I"-;;d"r;t"th~"10%"1~~~r'''N~;~FOMC''d;y~
are all of those in the sample on which there was no FOMC meeting or policy action, and no statement
by the FOMC, or testimony or speech by Chairman Greenspan. Increases in the variance of the error
term are measured relative to that observed over the week preceding the FOMC decision. All interest
rate changes are measured in basis points; changes in stock prices and the dollar are measured in
percentage points.

33

Table 4
Comparison of the Effects of Policy Actions and Statements
n

L1Yt

= 130 + 131' Nft + I,,13i . mac~ +1]t
U

i=1

Impact of
Policy
Surprises

--- Variance of L1y due to: --Policy
Policy
Total PolicyActions
Statements
Related

(131 )

(1)

(2)

(1) + (2)

Federal Funds Futures:
3 months ahead

0.62 (12.15)

63.9

24.1

88.0

Eurodollar Futures:
2 quarters ahead

0.59 (6.37)

53.3

48.7

102.0

4 quarters ahead

0.41 (3.60)

25.0

64.5

89.5

0.35 (4.05)

20.1

37.5

57.6

0.10 (1.18)

1.6

16.4

18.0

0.44 (5.98)

31.8

28.9

60.7

1 to 2 years ahead

0.26 (2.51)

10.8

49.7

60.5

2 to 3 years ahead

0.14 (1.17)

3.2

43.7

46.9

3 to 4 years ahead

0.08 (0.65)

0.8

28.7

29.5

S&P 500

-4.19 (2.43)

0.23

0.01

0.24

Dollar

0.68 (1.83)

0.01

-0.01

0.00

Treasury Yields:
2-year
lO-year

Treasury Forward Rates:
o to 1 years ahead

First column shows absolute t-statistics (corrected for heteroskedasticity) in parentheses. Those
responses, along with the variance of the policy surprises observed over our sample (164 basis points),
are used to calculate the variance of i1y due to policy actions. All interest rate changes are measured in
basis points; changes in stock prices and the dollar are measured in percentage points.

34

Table 5
Comparison of the Effects of Different Types of Statements
n

L1Yt

= 130 + 131' Nft + I,,13i . mac~ +1]t
U

i=2

Increase in Var(1]) due to:
FOMe
Greenspan
Greenspan

.,,""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""".§.£~E~!!!flf!.E~:"""""""E~.~:Ef,!!9..!!:.'l""""""",,§l!~.f!.E!!~.~:""".".
Federal Funds Futures:
3 months ahead

24.1 ***

10.0**

1.0

Eurodollar Futures:
2 quarters ahead

48.7**

45.6**

7.4

4 quarters ahead

64.5**

101.7***

13.2

37.5**

41.4***

4.3

16.4

37.1 ***

3.9

28.9**

21.8**

2.1

1 to 2 years ahead

49.7**

69.3***

6.2

2 to 3 years ahead

43.7

57.8***

4.1

3 to 4 years ahead

28.7

45.2***

1.8

S&P 500

0.01

-0.10

-0.10

Dollar

-0.01

-0.05

-0.01

Treasury Yields:
2-year
lO-year

Treasury Forward Rates:
o to 1 years ahead

'''''''''i;-di~;t~~''~ig~ifi~-;;~~~'';t'';:h~'''i'%''i~~~'i';'''''''';t''th;'5'%"i~~~E';;d''''';t''th~'''i'O%''i;~~r''N~~~F'OMC
days are all of those in the sample on which there was no FOMC meeting or policy action, and no
statement by the FOMC, or testimony or speech by Chairman Greenspan. Increases in the
variance of the error term are measured relative to that observed over the week preceding the
FOMC decision.

35

Table 6
Decomposition of the Effects of Policy Actions and Statements
---- FOMe Decision Days ---Policy
Policy
Total Policy
Actions
Statements
Effects
(1)
(2)
(1) + (2)

Greenspan
Testimony

Federal Funds Futures (3 months ahead):
Total Effect on Variance
Of which:
Policy Inclination
Economic Outlook

63.9

24.1

88.0

10.0

62.7
1.3

7.2
16.9

69.8
18.1

-14.6
24.6

Treasury Forward Rates (1 to 2 years ahead):
Total Effect on Variance
Of which:
Policy Inclination
Economic Outlook

10.8

49.7

60.5

69.3

7.2
3.6

0.8
48.8

8.0
52.5

-1.7
71.0

36

Table 7
Effects of Statements about Asset Valuations

Standard
deviation over
. __________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________!z.1!:.~:~!!:.~.~:~:__cJ:.~y._ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ .£!...~Y..~qJ!:.~:__'!!:.~!!:!~__________
Date

Change from
previous

Event

S&P 500 (percent change):
12/06/96
02/26/97
07/22/97
02/24/98
07/21198
02/23/99
06/17/99
07/22/99
10/15/99
02/17/00

Speech, American Enterprise Inst.
Testimony on MPR to Congress
Testimony on MPR to Congress
Testimony on MPR to Congress
Monetary Policy Report
Testimony on MPR to Congress
Testimony before the JEC
Testimony on MPR to Congress
Speech, conference sponsored by
Office of Comptroller of Currency
Testimony on MPR to Congress

-0.642
-0.791
2.305
-0.730
-1.607**
-0.075
0.713
-1.328
-2.806**

0.576
0.869
1.067
0.705
0.646
1.436
1.199
0.907
1.217

0.043

1.322

7.1
5.6
-12.5
7.8**

7.4
3.2
4.1
2.9
4.0
4.9

Credit Risk Spread (basis point change):
02/22/95
07/18/96
02/26/97
07/22/97
02/24/98
06/17/99

Testimony on MPR to Congress
Monetary Policy Report
Testimony on MPR to Congress
Testimony on MPR to Congress
Testimony on MPR to Congress
Testimony before the JEC

-8.7
11.7**

""'"'"'i;di_;;;t~_;'th~t'th;'d~_;;li~_;'i_;;'~q-;;ity'p~i-;;;~"~;'th_;';id~;i;g"~f_;;~~dit'~p-;~~d~'-;~~"g;;;t~;'i-;;'~b~~i-;;t~'~-;}-;;~'th~;"""""""""""""""""""'"
two standard deviations of the movements observed in the preceding month. Speeches that were given after markets
closed are dated as the following business day.

37