View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

SPEECHES

Monetary Policy Limits: Federal Reserve Actions and Tools
Dennis P. Lockhart
President and Chief Executive Officer
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta
Institute of Regulation & Risk, North Asia
Tokyo, Japan
May 21, 2012
Key points
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta President Dennis Lockhart says the past few years required resourcefulness by monetary authorities and brought forth unconventional
policy actions.
We are in a phase, Lockhart says, when sustained monetary accommodation is warranted to keep the U.S. economic recovery going.
Lockhart views communication as a policy tool and believes the FOMC should continue to improve its communications.
Lockhart does not believe economic circumstances at present warrant another round of large-scale asset purchases known as quantitative easing.

I want to thank the Institute of Regulation & Risk, North Asia for the opportunity to participate in the discussion here this evening. Coming here as a
Federal Reserve official rounds out my personal history of visits to Japan. I first traveled here as a tourist on my honeymoon. I later traveled back
several times as a private-sector banker. I am now here as a central banker and member of the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC). That
thought triggers my usual disclaimer—my remarks represent my personal views only. My views may not be shared by my Federal Reserve and
FOMC colleagues.
We're in a time of slow recovery in my country and recession or very weak growth along with serious fiscal and banking strains in Europe. So it's
appropriate that the organizers of this event have presented me with the following question: What more can be done? They have prefaced this
question with another: Are there limits to what monetary policy can accomplish?
Question of monetary policy limits
Let me first tackle this question of the limits of monetary policy.
The limits of monetary policy in curing the economic ills that beset advanced economies is a frequent topic these days. This is because—and I speak now more from a U.S.
perspective—a lot has been done, yet progress has been quite slow.
The policy interest rate has been at the zero bound since December 2008. We've aggressively expanded the scale of the Fed's balance sheet. Other central banks have
grown their balance sheets as well. In these circumstances, it's natural to ask if monetary policy has reached its practical limits in promoting recovery.
The limits of monetary policy might be considered from three angles. First, in very general terms, one might ask if there are inherent limits to what monetary policy can
achieve, and are these inherent limits now more obvious? By inherent limits I mean constraints on the scope of effectiveness of monetary policy in solving economic
problems in almost all circumstances. For example, as powerful as monetary policy can be, one might argue that it is powerless to cure deep structural problems such as
fiscal imbalances or trade imbalances resulting from a lack of competitiveness.
A second perspective on limits might reference statutory or self-imposed limits that central banks observe. These might encompass limits on how far the central bank can or
should go in addressing what are fiscal concerns. Monetary policymakers have tried to avoid interventions that put taxpayers at risk of loss. And central bankers have been
wary of trying to compensate for policy constraints in other domains of economic and social policy such as workforce development, tax policy, or currency policy.
And finally, the question of the limits of monetary policy could deal with the more immediate and pragmatic consideration of the real or expected effectiveness of current
policy and available policy options given the prevailing circumstances in the economy.
Each of these three perspectives has relevance in today's policy context in the United States, but it is this last dimension of the limits of policy that I want to explore in my
remarks this evening. The economic conditions of these past few years have required resourcefulness on the part of monetary authorities and evoked unconventional policy
actions. Central banks, the Fed included, may have to devise ways to respond to unique circumstances in the future. But for now—based on recent experience—policy
actions seem to fall under three headings. They are interest rate policies, balance sheet actions, and communications directed at markets and the public.
Employing three tool sets
The FOMC has employed all three tool sets to address the varied circumstances it faced over the last four years.
As you may remember, the Federal Reserve implemented a series of extraordinary emergency lending measures in the wake of the Lehman Brothers and AIG failures in
September 2008. By the end of that year, the target for the federal funds rate had been lowered to its effective lower bound range of 0 to 25 basis points.
Looking back, 2009 represented the year of transition from acute crisis to recovery. Over the course of 2009, the Federal Reserve wound down most of its emergency lending
facilities and transitioned to the current mode of conducting monetary policy operations. That approach relies substantially on balance sheet changes. The FOMC has been
unable to resort to its familiar short-term interest rate instrument to provide further stimulus to the economy.
The first stages of this new phase involved large-scale asset purchases. These large-scale asset purchase (LSAP) programs are popularly known as QE1 and QE2. This
terminology reflects a tendency of referring to policies that have a large impact on central bank balance sheets as "quantitative easing."

I believe that the motivations of the two policy actions were more distinct than the QE1 and QE2 labels suggest.
The first large-scale asset purchase program—so-called QE1—was put in motion by the FOMC in March 2009. The FOMC decided to purchase a total of $200 billion of
agency debt, $300 billion of Treasury securities, and $1.25 trillion of mortgage-backed securities issued by the federal housing agencies. Eventually the Fed completed all but
the direct agency purchases.
In my view, these purchase programs played an important role in the transition away from the emergency lending facilities created earlier in the crisis. The emergency credit
facilities worked well to stem the downward spiral of the immediate post-Lehman period. Financial markets began the process of repair during the first half of 2009 but were
still suffering from relatively serious liquidity pressures. The QE1 operation sustained the liquidity support that had been previously provided by lending through the
emergency facilities.
Because asset purchases largely replaced emergency loans made during the crisis, the net increase in the Fed's balance sheet was relatively modest. In this sense, the
quantitative easing label is misleading. The intent and effect of the policy was not to inject a new and sizable quantity of reserves into the economy. Rather, the effect was to
sustain liquidity in still struggling and fragile financial markets, particularly those related to residential real estate. For that reason, I prefer the term "credit easing" to describe
this policy action.
I view QE2 differently. The FOMC formally announced QE2 in November 2010, with its decision to purchase $600 billion in longer-term Treasury securities. However, the
policy was signaled in an important speech from Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke in August of that year. The circumstances at the time were dominated by a falling
trend in measured inflation, weakening inflation expectations, and rising probabilities of outright deflation. Each of these developments was effectively reversed as the
expectations for QE2 took root, expectations that were ultimately validated by FOMC action.
Unlike QE1, QE2 did materially expand the size of the Federal Reserve's balance sheet. In my view, this distinction is important. The intent and effect of the two rounds of
asset purchases were different. QE1 served to maintain liquidity at a time when financial markets were exceptionally unsettled. In contrast, QE2 was a more traditional
monetary action to preserve price stability.
The latest phase of policy actions involves further balance sheet operations and enhanced and expanded communication.
In August of last year, the FOMC replaced its existing forward guidance on interest rates. Prior to that date, the language indicated only that interest rates were likely to
remain at exceptionally low levels for an extended period. This language was replaced in August with more explicit guidance that spelled out the meaning of "extended
period." Specifically, at that time the FOMC indicated its expectation that economic conditions would warrant very low interest rates at least through mid-2013. Subsequently,
that guidance was updated to late 2014.
In September of last year, the FOMC announced its Maturity Extension Program (MEP), often referred to as "Operation Twist." By next month, this program will have
increased the Fed's holdings of longer-term securities by $600 billion matched by equivalent sales of shorter-term securities. At the same time the FOMC announced the
MEP, the committee stated its intention to maintain the size of its mortgage-backed securities (MBS) portfolio by reinvesting the proceeds of maturing MBS securities.
In terms of intent and effect, I think of the explicit forward guidance and the MEP in similar terms. We have entered a phase of the recovery in which sustained monetary
accommodation is warranted in order to preserve and advance what is still modest progress on employment and economic growth. Importantly, this modest progress is
occurring in the context of what, for me, is acceptable performance with respect to our price stability mandate. Actions that reinforce the maintenance of policy
accommodation are appropriate. It is through that lens that I view the MEP and explicit forward guidance on policy rates.
Let me summarize this brief tour of postcrisis monetary policy. I view the sequence of nontraditional monetary policy actions as tailored responses to the particular needs of
the economy and financial system at the time they were implemented. My conclusion is that by and large policy actions have been appropriate to the diagnosis of
circumstances at the time. And in my assessment they have worked pretty well.
Today's economy
Circumstances today in the United States call for continued measured efforts to quicken the pace of recovery and shrink unemployment, while keeping inflation controlled
and close to the FOMC's official target of 2 percent. Those efforts for the time being should fall in the realm of communications. Current economic data continue to be a mix
of positives and negatives. Consumer activity is continuing to grow, and manufacturing is expanding. At the same time, we've seen a recent slowdown in business
investment, and the pace of job creation has weakened.
My economic outlook calls for only modest growth over the next few years.
The modest recovery and associated slow job growth is keeping wage growth subdued and inflation expectations reasonably well-anchored. As a result, my outlook for
inflation remains steady at around 2 percent over the forecast horizon.
There are larger-than-normal risks to my outlook, however. Chief among them is the potential for broad spillover from Europe to the U.S. and global economy resulting from
financial system disruption as well as further economic slowdown.
For this reason in particular, I currently judge the risks to the U.S. outlook as tilted modestly to the downside.
Central bank communications
To repeat my earlier assertion, I think use of the tool of refined communication is an appropriate incremental policy action.
It's useful, I think, to conduct a thought experiment about central bank communication. Let's consider what constitutes perfect communication. I would argue that
communication approaches perfection when the broad, attentive public understands how the monetary authority is going to behave. Put differently, there would be nearperfect certainty about the monetary authority's reaction function under all circumstances.
In this imagined world, consumers, businesses, savers, and investors can make appropriate adjustments to their decisions and behaviors as each indication of the
economy's trajectory becomes known. They can do so because they have certainty about what the policy reality will be. In this world, communication promotes the efficient

functioning of financial markets. Risk premiums come down and rates are lower than they otherwise would have been. Both markets and individuals can be confident policy
surprises won't complicate outcomes. And with that confidence and certainty, the mutually reinforcing roles of economic agents and policymakers become tightly
synchronized in a causal loop.
In my view, working toward this end is the right undertaking of the FOMC at this moment, even if it is not fully achievable. The FOMC should continue to clarify its strategy for
the medium and long term so that the public can discern how the committee arrives at decisions. In that vein, effective communication that results in the public knowing the
extent of uncertainty policymakers face also helps.
Institutional constraints of central banks can have a significant influence on how far a central bank can go in perfecting communication. The FOMC, for example, is made up
currently of 12 voting members with another seven of the Reserve Bank presidents participating without a formal vote at any given point in time. The differences of
perspective around the table are substantial. I would argue that the FOMC was designed to achieve a consensus on the monetary policy decision if not the supporting
analysis. Put more simply, achieving consensus around a decision is a lot easier than arriving at a consensus forecast or a uniform position on how policy should react to
hypothetical future developments. Still, I believe the FOMC should continue to work on improving communication methods. At the moment, it is a work in progress.
In closing, I have reframed to some extent the original question of what more can be done around the point that policy actions must be matched to circumstances. The
challenge policymakers face is judging appropriateness of a tool for circumstances. As popular as it might be in some quarters to rule out further LSAPs (QE3, as it is
known), I do not think this option can be taken off the table. QE3 will work under the right circumstances. But I don't believe such circumstances prevail at this time.
Thank you.

Contact: Jean Tate 404-498-8035

RELATED LINKS: PDF version • Dennis Lockhart's biography • Speaker's Bureau • Atlanta Fed Speeches