View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

CREDIT FOR CONSUMERS

Address
by
Delos C. Johns
President! Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Before the
National I n s t a l m e n t C r e d i t Conference
Sponsored by the A m e r i c a n B a n k e r s Association
Jeffer son Hotel, St. L o u i s , M i s s o u r i
Monday m o r n i n g , M a r c h 2 1 , 1955.

CREDIT FOR CONSUMBRS
Many of us gathered here today find it difficult to reflect on the early
1920 f s without a momentary pang of nostalgia.

Yet I think we would not wish

to turn the calendar back if we could, for an undeniable fact of life in the early
twenties was this: the members of the family worked much harder at entertaining
themselves and at keeping the household going than they do in 1955.

Though

people of some means then commonly passed housework on to full-time domestic
servants, much drudgery remained nevertheless, and escape from the boredom
of repetitive chores was a challenge to the ingenuity of many.

But new, durable goods were already beginning to change living patterns.
By 1921 the first two great labor-saving household appliances, washing machines
and electric refrigerators, were gaining rapid acceptance.

A 1921 washing

machine was an ugly contraption, requiring almost as great expenditure of human
energy as the tub and washboard.

An electric refrigerator of the early twenties,

with its compressor installed in the basement, made a great noise, setting up
sympathetic vibrations in various parts of the house as it grumbled on and off.
On balance, however, both appliances reduced household toil, as did the electric
and gas ranges which by 1925 were quickly replacing kerosene cook stoves and
wood-and-coal-burning kitchen ranges.

Though pianos had long been installed

to further the family's cultural p r o g r e s s , they unfortunately required individual
playing skill.

Thus the player-piano and phonograph, when they were introduced,

vied for popular favor as providers of ready-made music.

The phonograph

was winning out until the realization at last came that radio had become
commercially feasible.

Radios, most of them still tuned with three dials, were

by 1925 fast becoming the center of the family's evening interest, but were not



- 2 -

yet always dependable sources of entertainment.

Households had always used durable goods, of coursej the 1920.8 simply
witnessed a change in their kind.

As the automobile revolutionized American

life and mechanization spread to the home, the share of furniture and furnishings
in consumer durables production fell off rapidly.

Automobiles and electrical

appliances not only replaced older durable goods, such as horse-drawn carriages
and iceboxes, but also brought about an increase in the share of consumers 1
expenditures going to durables.
expenditures were for durables.

By 1929 almost 12 per cent of personal consumption
Moreover, by that year the composition of

expenditures for different categories of durables was pretty well set.

For example,

in 1929 about one-fifth of outlays for durables went for the purchase of appliances,
a proportion which has remained quite stable into the present.

In spite of the

continual introduction of new and acceptable electrical devices, the share of these
goods in the total dollar expenditures of consumers has remained almost constant.
Typically, if an appliance gains consumer acceptance, sales will increase at a
rapid rate for several years and then level off or actually decline.

Thus the

fabulous s u c c e s s e s of mechanical refrigerators in the 1930's and home f r e e z e r s ,
automatic washers, television s e t s , and room air-conditioners in the postWorld War 11 period just about offset the leveling off or decline in demand for
previously established items such as radios and wringer-type washing machines.

How shall we evaluate the importance of durables in shaping the pattern of
consumer expenditures since 1929? Inspection of available data leads to two




- 3 ~

observations.

First, consumer durables sales are extremely sensitive to both

war and depression.

The purchase of durables is postponable, and during periods

of falling incomes the percentage drop in demand for consumer durables has been
about the same as the drop in demand for producer durables.

Wars, of course,

demand the same raw materials that go into consumer durables and thus cut into
their output.

Second, in every year beginning with 1947 consumer purchases of

durables have exceeded the 12 per cent level of total consumption expenditures
reached previously only in 1929.

During the 1940. s, despite wartime restrictions

and rapid growth in the population, per capita ownership of durables increased
at an annual rate greater than that of the twenties.

Today the average per capita

value of consumer durables in use (in 1929 dollars) i s at least half again as great
as it was in 1929.

We may conclude then that the trend since 1920 has been for households
to consume a higher proportion of their income in the form of durables, and it i s
quite possible that this tendency has increased since the end of World War 11.
(That trend, of c o u r s e , has been obscured at t i m e s by depression and war.) How
shall we account for this apparent shift in attitudes? A number of studies have
demonstrated what we have long known intuitively - that expenditures on durables
are closely correlated with income change.

As people become richer, they spend

a greater portion of their incomes on goods yielding s e r v i c e s that will relieve
work or monotony and increase personal and family prestige.

But we must look a little further.

The purchase of a durable good requires

a relatively large outlay at one time for a flow of s e r v i c e s over a period of future



- 4 -

time.

There is nothing to prevent families with sufficient incomes from saving

up to make the outlay, and some do.

But experience has shown that many, perhaps

a majority, of American consumers find it irksome to save the full purchase
price of major durables before buying.

Consumer credit is a device, though

not n e c e s s a r i l y the only one which could be used, that puts the desire of households
for capital equipment on a competitive basis with the desire for nondurables and
services.

As distinguished from convenience (charge account) credit, consumer

credit enables the consumer, at any moment of time, to increase his purchases
over and above what they would be if he depended upon his existing cash r e s o u r c e s .
Human character being what it i s , families must enforce saving on themselves
after committing themselves to a purchase contract.

Instalment credit i s not new; a century ago sewing machines, pianos,
some furniture, and books were sold

M

on time 11 .

During the first two decades of

the twentieth century, instalment credit gradually became more respectable, and
by 1920 even the most conservative merchants were offering easy payment plans.
It is estimated that by 1926 nearly two-thirds of the new cars and three-fourths
of the furniture were sold on a time-payment basis.

By 1929 instalment credit

was an accepted American institution.
During the 1930 f s the proportion of instalment sales to total sales ranged
between 50 and 60 per cent at furniture and household appliance stores.

About

60 per cent of all automobile sales were made on time during most of that decade,
and this ratio came to be accepted as normal.
s e e m s to bear out this estimate of normalcy.



Post-World War 11 experience
After household units spent the cash

~ 5 saved during the war for the specific purpose of buying durable goods when they should
become available, the percentages which obtained in the 1930's were approximately
equaled.

Consumer credit is obviously important to s e l l e r s of durables.
is important to us all.

Indeed, it

At the end of 1954 total consumer credit outstanding stood

at more than $30 billion and instalment credit at more than $22 1/2 billion, both
just under the all-time highs of a year previous.

Instalment debt amounted to

about 8 1/2 per cent of disposable income, again not far from a peak reached in
1953.

By themselves these figures are no cause for concern.

The income left

to most household units today after meeting the basic expenses of food, clothing,
and shelter i s much larger than before World War 11, and from this ''discretionary 11
income people may safely commit a larger portion for consumer durables.

Moreover,

the bulk of consumer debt is owed by people with generally good economic prospects, about two-thirds of it by middle-income families and by young married couples with
children.

Bankers and economists have nonetheless frequently expressed alarm over
swings in instalment credit, which is so c l o s e l y related to the purchase of consumer
durables.

For the past twenty-five years expenditures on consumer durables have

been of the same order of magnitude as g r o s s business expenditures for durables,
and the latter are notorious for their unstabilizing effects on the economy.

This

leads to the frequent asking of these questions: does not the institution of instalment
credit make possible greater expenditures on consumer durables in the expansion
phase of the cycle, and do not net repayments on instalment accounts have a
deflationary impact when incomes are falling?



- 6 -

There if no denying the fact that Instalment credit tends to concentrate
effective demand for durables in times of expanding business activity.

Nor can

it be denied that instalment credit introduces additional rigidity into consumer
budgets.

If on the upward phase of a cycle there is unemployment of resources,

injections of purchasing power via the instalment credit route stimulate activity
in the durable goods industry at a propitious time.

If on the other hand full

employment conditions prevail and consumers already have incomes sufficient
to enable them to take from the market what is produced, further injections of
purchasing power generate inflationary p r e s s u r e s .

During times of falling business

activity and declining incomes rigidities introduced by instalment credit into
consumer budgets have a pronounced deflationary impact.

Like mortgage payments,

property-tax payments, and insurance payments, payments on a car or furniture
constitute for a time at least an unavoidable charge on income.

Insofar as r e -

payments on instalment accounts exceed new credit extensions the effect on the
economy is depressing.
But such considerations need to be put in better perspective.

Relative to

total consumer outlays, expenditures on consumer durables are not large.

Wide

swings in consumer durables purchases may accent the business cycle but are
relatively unimportant when viewed against the stability of expenditures for
nondurables and s e r v i c e s , which presently constitute about 88 per cent of total
consumption expenditure.

Indeed, as one durable good after another becomes

generally accepted by consumers, resources are more and more drawn into the
service trades.

We have garages and filling stations because there are automobiles

and television service establishments because there are television sets.



The

- 7 -

experience of the groat depression teaches us that the demand for such s e r v i c e s
holds up very well during a deflationary period, especially as people make their
durables do for longer-than-normal periods.

In this we find some contracyclical

effect.

Nor does a comparison of consumer credit with other credit put the
former in a bad light so far as stability i s concerned.

During the deflation

years of 1930-1933, consumer credit moved downward at about the same rate as
did loans of all commercial banks and non-real estate farm credit, but at a
faster rate than did urban real-estate credit.

On the other hand, beginning in

mid-1933, consumer credit began a sharp upturn, well ahead of the other Beries.
During the relatively depressed 1930's consumer credit on balance appears to have
e x e r c i s e d a buoyant influence.
in consumer credit in 1938.

An exception was the relatively sharp but brief fall

In the postwar years the upward thrusts of the consumer

credit and instalment credit curves are not out of line with other s e r i e s .

It i s

not unreasonable to argue that in 1949 the upward change in both instalment and
urban mortgage credit, so far from being a source of instability, actually helped
to carry the economy over the threat of more s e v e r e depression.

Again, in the

r e c e s s i o n of 1953-1954, although instalment repayments slightly exceeded extensions
In some months, instalment credit s e e m s to have operated as a sustaining force
in the economy.

We may, I think, evaluate the significance of instalment credit to economic
stability as follows.

The rate of capital formation plays a large part in total

cyclical fluctuations in output, employment, and p r i c e s .



The share of consumer

- 8 -

durables in the rate of capital formation is comparable in character and size to
that of producer durables.

Insofar as the institution of consumer credit increases

fluctuations in the rate of consumer capital formation, it adds to the factors making
for instability.

But these factors, including the very fact that there are such

things as durable goods, outweigh the unstabilizing effect of the institution of
consumer credit itself.

The old notion that changes in consumer credit are important enough to
induce either an upswing or downswing in economic activity no longer has widespread
acceptance.

Nearly everyone would agree that changes in outstandings reinforce

economic fluctuations; but there would likewise be agreement that consumer credit
i s only one of several variables which help to determine the national income,
whereas fluctuations in the national income appear to be the dominant factor affecting
the volume of consumer credit outstanding.

In sum, many economists are taking a

progressively more moderate view of the proposition that consumer credit i s a
major factor in causing instability.
I do not want to leave you this morning without reflecting on the implications
of these conclusions for credit policy.

It has been argued that the general credit

instruments cannot be depended upon when it appears that instalment credit
outstandings are increasing too rapidly.

This proposition rested largely on the

assumption that lenders to consumers do not respond very rapidly or very strongly
either to credit stringency or to changes in the interest rate.

For this reason

it was assumed that consumer credit outstandings are not responsive to the
general instruments.



It was then but a step to the conclusion that selective control

- 9 of credit is a legitimates complement to the general instruments, that it can be
used to reinforce, to compensate, or at certain times to serve as a partial
substitute for the general instruments.

Several recent studies raise some doubt as to the validity of the argument
that there i s only a tenuous relationship between consumer credit outstanding
and the supply of credit in general.

Consumer credit may be more responsive to

the general instruments than we had thought.

Thus it s e e m s now that the following

propositions hold true:
(1) Interest costs definitely enter into the considerations of
both bank and nonbank lenders to consumers.
(2) Lenders to consumers do react to the rising costs and
reduced availability of credit in general.
(3) Nonbank lenders pass along the effects of rising costs and
reduced availability of credit by applying stricter credit
standards, by cutting lines to dealers, and by raiding rates.
(4) Banks do appear to lf ration M their r e s o u r c e s with respect to
consumer credit departments.
(5) Even though consumer borrowers may not be especially
affected by changes in interest c o s t s , they are responsive
to changes in credit standards, including t e r m s .
In making a judgment regarding the sensitivity of consumer credit to
general controls, one further point should be borne in mind.

The best estimate of

the percentage of consumer credit outstanding financed by banks both directly and




- 10 -

indirectly indicates a proportion of roughly three-fifths.

This suggests that

p r e s s u r e on banks via general credit controls can scarcely avoid the effect of
restricting consumer credit.

Credit lines to dealers and lenders are not only

likely to be tightened, but a tighter money policy also changes the economic climate
in which consumers make their decisions.
inhibits economic activity.

If it i s successful, a tight money policy

As this happens, the rate at which the national income

i n c r e a s e s will slacken, or the national income may actually begin to decrease.

We

have already remarked the correlation between changes in the level of the national
income and the level of consumer credit outstanding; it follows that actions which
reduce the rate of increase of the national income are likely to reduce the rate of
increase of instalment credit outstanding.

Events of the past two years seem to

substantiate this proposition.

The foregoing analysis suggests that when general credit policy can be free
and its implementation flexible there i s little, if any, need for selective regulation
of consumer credit.

But note that the conclusion i s qualified by the statement that

general credit policy be free and flexible, free to be easy or to be restrictive,
flexible as to application within that range.

And one further point needs mention here.

A theoretical c a s e can be made for the usefulness of a selective consumer credit
control in special circumstances, say in a period of rapid defense build-up
unaccompanied by materials allocation and price controls.

Such circumstances, in

my opinion, should not really be permitted to occur and hence the need for the
selective control should not occur.

However, none of us i s always wise and sometimes

all of us are unwise, and so it i s possible to be faced with such a set of circumstances.




- II We have come a long way in a short while.

Let mo bring this discussion

to a c:to»e.

There seems little question that the institution of instalment credit has
done much to make possible l a r g e - s c a l e output of consumer durables.

By

increasing the rate of consumer capital formation, instalment credit has contributed
to a r i s e in the American level of living and has stimulated the growth of the
national income.

But consumer credit i s a two-edged sword.

for you and against you.

It can cut both

In times when inflationary p r e s s u r e s are great or when

deflation is sharp and protracted, instalment credit may be just one more force
making for instability in the economy.

But we should not be surprised to find that

this is so, for the very nature of capitalism implies certain inherent sources of
instability.

In other words, instability is a part of the price we pay for the

enjoyment of goods which yield their s e r v i c e s over time.

The case for and the c a s e against selective regulation of consumer credit
i s becoming better understood.

The arguments for it no longer rest on an assumption

that without selective controls the monetary authority is substantially unable to
influence the rate of expansion of consumer credit.

It is now recognized that other

considerations are also involved, including profound concepts of non-discriminatory
monetary management in a free capitalistic economy.

There is much to be said

for the view that instead of intervening in particular markets it is the primary
business of the monetary authority to do what it can to create a salubrious monetary
and financial climate in which business decision makers like yourselves can compete
freely and vigorously.



00OO00