View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
10:00 A.M., E.D.T.
April 28. 1992

Statement by
David W. Mullins, Jr.
Vice Chairman, Board of Governors
of the Federal Reserve System
Before the
Subcommittee on Domestic Monetary Policy
U.S. House of Representatives

April 28, 1992

Mr. Chairman, members of the Committee, thank you
for this opportunity to communicate the Board of Governors’
views on proposed legislation concerning the government
securities market.

The Joint Report on the Government

Securities Market suggested comprehensive administrative
changes, some already made and others proposed, that will
significantly increase openness in this market and sharply
limit the possibility of a repiay of recent events.

The

Board supports these changes, which are targeted to the
problems and opportunities identified to foster fair and
efficient markets.

In the Board’s view, this progress makes

it inadvisable to enact either H.R. 4450 or 3927.
This decision was made after carefully weighing
the costs and benefits of further change, as we see them at
this time, in accordance with our legislated role in the
oversight of financial markets.

In 1789, President

Washington and the first Congress charged the Department of
the Treasury with the responsibility of borrowing in the
name of the new republic.

In 1913, the drafters of the

Federal Reserve Act assigned the Federal Reserve District
Banks to serve as fiscal agents for the Treasury,
facilitating the nationwide distribution of the debt.
Later, in 1934, Congress created the Securities and Exchange
Commission to enforce securities laws that were targeted to
counter the considerable problems at hand in private
financial markets by nurturing fairness and openness.

While

-

2-

the Board works closely with the various agencies and has
general oversight responsibilities for the activities of the
District Banks, we have little direct regulatory authority
for the U.S. government securities market.
We think that this arrangement is wise and gives
the Board of Governors a unique perspective, allowing us to
examine important issues regarding this market from an
economy-wide perspective.

Freed of the specific

responsibilities of managing the debt, distributing
securities, or policing trading activity, we can evaluate
the consequences of proposed reform against broad public
policy standards.
Our overall evaluation of both pieces of
legislation started from a fundamental question:
the problems that need to be addressed?

what are

In the Board of

Governors’ view., the government securities market ably
performs ah important allocative role in the U.S. economy,
matching a voracious borrower, the federal government, with
investors across the nation and around the world.

The U.S.

government has been able to tap this market with record
issuance time and time again.

This market is deep and

liquid, routinely permitting participants to execute trades
of huge size with remarkable rapidity at paper-thin bid/ask
spreads.

Consequently, the market serves as an important

source of liquidity for individuals and financial
institutions.

-3-

The trading community commits large sums of risk
capital to provide these services in the pursuit of profits.
But there are economy-wide benefits as well.

The government

securities market has an impressive ability to digest news,
translating the daily barrage of economic releases and
political commentary efficiently into prices.

In doing so,

it provides real-time quotes on a host of issues that serve
as benchmarks for the pricing of non-government securities.
That responsiveness also serves monetary policy well, as it
gives us a reliable gauge of financial markets in general
and a liquid and efficient venue to conduct open market
operations.
However, we sit here today as the result of
identifiable problems with the market.

The problems that

have come to light so far--evidence of lying in the issuance
of government securities and episodes of price distortions,
perhaps related to attempts to manipulate the market-clearly signalled the need to act.
of us.

And we have acted, all

The Joint Report provides a blueprint for the

thoughtful and comprehensive renovation of this market.
Taken together, these changes open the government securities
market, significantly altering the way that business is
conducted.

They enhance our surveillance in the primary and

secondary markets, establish more systematic lines of
communication among the agencies, promise to broaden direct
participation at auctions, and, by warning that there will

-

4-

be active Treasury supply management to shave outsized
profit owing to price anomalies, put market participants on
notice that there is no tolerance for manipulative acts.
Frankly, a failure of the primary market to keep pace with
the technical advance in the secondary market likely
contributed to the problems that were identified.

We still

rely on slips of paper and ballot boxes around the country
to place government debt, while secondary market traders sit
before banks of computers, able to transact in size on a
word or a few keystrokes.

We must automate and we must do

it quickly.
Moreover, as endorsed in the Joint Report,
alternative auction designs may help to channel the force of
competition in our favor.

One such alternative, a single­

priced and open auction, holds the promise of enhancing
participation in the auction and exposing attempts to
manipulate the market, thereby narrowing the possibility of
manipulation and producing lower Treasury borrowing costs.
H.R. 4450

With this common ground, it is clear that the Board
shares many of the objectives of H.R. 4450.

This proposed

legislation calls for the broad reconstruction of the
auction process, instructing the Board of Governors to
direct automation in a way that increases public access, to
conduct experiments with single-priced awards, to attempt
additional experiments with a tap issuance technique, and to

-

5-

produce a study of the results for Congress within two
years.

Additionally, H.R. 4450 would require that any

advisory committee established to advise the Board or the
Secretary of the Treasury or any Federal Reserve Bank on the
marketing or sale of Treasury securities include as large a
number of members as is feasible and hold open meetings.
We agree that automation of and experimentation
with selling techniques potentially could serve the Treasury
and the U.S. taxpayer well.

However, we do not believe that

H.R. 4450 is the means to effect that change.

Following the

Joint Report blueprint, the Treasury is in the process of a
rigorous examination of auction reform with academic
experts, market participants, and others to design a new
system and frame an experiment that will test it fairly.
Indeed, we are giving the Treasury all the aid we can,
jointly sponsoring a conference in early June to bring
together interested parties to examine these issues in
detail.
I believe that the Joint Report motivated the
careful examination of innovative techniques for selling
securities and combatting manipulation.

The Board would

prefer to see this process run its course.

Legislating

experiments now would be premature, perhaps forcing the
Treasury to implement procedures that were inefficient or
which created undesirable incentives, to the detriment of
overall funding costs.

If, at a later date. Congress deemed

-

6-

that the Treasury's experiment was poorly designed or did
not give adequate consideration to alternative auction
techniques, then the matter could be revisited.

We feel it

is unwise to attempt to legislate the path that progress
should take.

The Board fully intends to take an activé

consulting role in this process and would welcome an
invitation to return here to keep the Committee fully
informed.
The same argument applies with greater force to the
provision of H.R. 4450 requiring an experiment with tap
issuance.

Any means of broadening participation in the

auction should be the subject of rigorous analysis and
consideration.

It is not clear that legislated mandates are

either necessary or useful.

For example, in a tap issuance,

the Treasury would have to set prices.

Moving away from

letting markets set prices in an auction presents new
problems in establishing and changing the prices at which
the securities would be sold in order to manage the
Treasury’s cash flow.

As these are complex issues and

mistakes in even a modest experiment are potentially very
costly, the focus should be on doing what is best for
taxpayers rather than meeting rigid legislative mandates and
deadlines.
While we appreciate that H.R. 4450 would grant the
Board significant responsibilities in reforming the auction,
we are concerned that this would confuse and potentially '

-

7-

disrupt the longstanding relationship among the Treasury,
the Board, and the Federal Reserve Banks.

The proposed

legislation would appear to require the Board to take
authority long granted to the Treasury, namely acting as
principal with respect to the structure of Treasury
auctions.

Moreover, the degree to which the Board’s rdle

under H.R. 4450 would supplant Treasury direction in the
specified areas, let alone peripheral areas, is unclear.
Such conflicting authorities could serve to slow the
development of an automated auction system and could create
other difficulties in the fiscal agency relationship.
Monetary policy is difficult enough without the further
entanglement' of substantive decisions about debt issuance.
The Board also is concerned about H.R. 4450’s
requirement that it prescribe regulations'concerning
internal controls for participants in the automated system.
It is essential that firms maintain an effective system of
internal controls.

But once legislation proposed in the

Joint Report is enacted prohibiting misleading statements to
issuers of government securities, the authority of the self
regulatory organizations in this area will be adequate,
rendering it superfluous to enact additional legislation to
mandate internal controls.
Lastly with regard to H.R. 4450, the requirement
for public advisory committees on debt issuance directly
concerns the Treasury, and we defer to its judgment on this

-8-

matter.

I would caution, however, that mandating access may

erode the usefulness of these meetings.

As a result, the

Treasury may need to turn more to informal contacts beyond
the scope of the legislation to maintain their market
knowledge.

Thus, the public could know less than under

present arrangements.
H.R. 3927
In the last nine months we have made much progress
in designing and implementing fundamental improvements in
the government securities market.

Unfortunately, I see

little of that progress reflected in H.R. 3927.

This bill

would allow the erection of elaborate reporting
requirements, under various rationales, that have the
potential to impose upon the government securities market
the enforcement structure of the equity market with little
regard to appropriateness.
The government securities market provides for the
wholesale and large-scale exchange of homogenous securities
among sophisticated market professionals.

It is not subject

to the types of insider-trading abuses that roil equity
markets with a distressing regularity.

The abuses in the

government securities market that have cropped up so far as
we are aware--attempts at price manipulation and violation
of auctipn rules--have simple, targeted remedies appropriate
to their relatively infrequent occurrence.

Markets differ

and regulation should reflect that difference.

With each

-9-

basis point in borrowing cost adding over $200 million a
year to the deficit, the stakes are too high to legislate
for the sake of mere consistency among securities laws.
In the Board of Governors’ view, no compelling
cost-benefit case has been made to impose broad-based
reporting requirements in the government securities market,
either directly or through audit trails or so-called
"transparency" requirements.

Without question, increased

reporting would deter manipulation and facilitate the
investigation of abuses.

But does that high level of

vigilance warrant the substantial cost ultimately borne by
taxpayers?

Aren’t the proposals in the Joint Report equally

efficacious and far less costly in dealing with these
problems?
The Board has not yet been shown the evidence of
widespread malfunctions in the government securities market
that would give reason to impose the substantial costs that
likely would follow from the passage of H.R. 3927.

The

reporting burden, falling on all traders, would boost the
cost of every trade.

True, the direct costs of additional

recordkeeping might be kept manageable by the adroit
application of the law by regulators.

But it might not.

H.R. 3927 turns that decision over to the regulators once
nominal hurdles are passed.
We fear that an indirect cost of reporting
requirements may loom even larger in the long run.

Rather

-10-

than risk divulging their finances and trading strategies,
participants might reduce their presence or withdraw
entirely from the domestic market, leaving the Treasury
fewer willing customers for its mounting debt.

Even backup

authority, because it might be difficult to resist
implementing, sends the same chilling message about the U.S.
market to participants choosing a trading arena in the
global marketplace.

Moreover, in view of the extensive

nature of the other changes proposed in this report, one
might question the capacity of this market to absorb, at an
acceptable cost, this additional change.
participants will not bear that cost:

Market

ultimately, it must

be passed on to the U.S. taxpayer.
My colleagues and I feel that further fundamental
changes in this vital market are too important to be made
without explicit Congressional approval.

While some

supported backup authority in the Joint Report, the agencies
generally agreed that extensive reporting requirements need
not be implemented at this time.

If it is the case that the

other substantial changes already in motion fail to increase
openness in the government securities market, allowing
manipulative practices to lurk in the shadows, then Congress
should make the explicit decision to impose reporting
requirements.

Since H.R. 3927 potentially could allow

regulators to reach into every aspect of trading behavior,
it is a wiser course of action to return here for enabling

-11-

legislation in the future should such authority appear
necessary.
Conclusion
Substantial progress has been made in exploring,
identifying, and implementing approaches to improve Treasury
auctions.

The Board staff has been in almost continual

contact with their counterparts at the Treasury, and we are
confident that good-faith efforts on auction reform will
continue.

We believe that this process should be allowed to

run its course.

If the progress is deemed insufficient,

Congress can then return to legislative approaches to
reform.

In our view, H.R. 4450 is not necessary, possibly

detrimental, and risks entwining debt management authority
and monetary policy.
Similarly, it is unwise to confuse the equity and
government securities markets.

The latter has served the

national interest by efficiently placing the federal debt
with few evident problems.

If we let the force of

competition work to our advantage, the government securities
market can continue to provide substantial benefits.
H.R. 3927 risks imposing large costs in the search for
elusive and, given the information that we now have, perhaps
limited benefits.