View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

by
David P. Eastburn, President
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

before the

1971 Annual Meeting of
THE NATIONAL ASSEMBLY FOR SOCIAL POLICY AND DEVELOPMENT, INC.

April 30, 1971 - 12 Noon
New Albany Hotel
Denver, Colorado

There are two kinds of people in the world today:

those who are

primarily concerned with making a living and those who are primarily con­
cerned with living with their fellows.

The first might be called Economic

Man; the second, Social Man.
One of our main problems these days is that Social Man and
Economic Man see the same things differently.

Social Man urged his Con­

gressman to oppose the SST because it would make too much noise and might
induce skin cancer; Economic Man, if he opposed the SST at all, did so
because it would not get off the ground financially.

Social Man sees the

moon shots as an extravagant use of resources at a time when much of the
world is starving; Economic Man sees them as spinning off many scientific
by-products that some day can improve everyone’s standard of living.
Social Man faithfully lugs his used Coke bottles to the neighborhood collec­
tion center every Saturday morning for recycling; Economic Man is inclined
to feel that if empty bottles were worth anything, somebody would pay for
them.
My point is not that Social Man is soft-hearted and -headed or
that Economic Man is a Scrooge, but that both have much to learn from each
other.

I have developed this theme in a general way elsewhere*, but would

like to explore one important aspect of it here.
To introduce this aspect, let me read an excerpt from the
writings of a distinguished philosopher:
Towards what ultimate point is society tending by its
industrial progress? . . .

* Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, BUSINESS REVIEW, "Economic
Man vs. Social Man," October 1970. THE NEW YORK TIMES, July 26, 1970.




. . . the tone and tendency . . . ]_of the specula- _
tions of political economists of the last two generations/
goes completely to identify all that is economically de­
sirable with the progressive state, and with that alone.

I cannot . . . regard the stationary state of capital
and wealth with the unaffected aversion so generally mani­
fested towards it by political economists of the old school.
. . . I confess I am not charmed with the ideal of life held
out by those who think that the normal state of human beings
is that of struggling to get on; that the trampling, crush­
ing, elbowing and treading on each other’s heels, which form
the existing type of social life, are the most desirable lot
of human kind, or anything but the disagreeable symptoms of
one of the phases of industrial progress. . . . the life of
the whole of one sex is devoted to dollar-hunting and of the
other to breeding dollar-hunters.

There is room in the world, no doubt . . . for a great
increase of population, . . . But even if innocuous, ^ c o n ­
fess I__see very little reason for desiring it. . . . /There
is no_t/ much satisfaction in contemplating the world with
nothing left to the spontaneous activity of nature . . .
with . . . scarcely a place left where a wild shrub or flower
could grow without being eradicated as a weed in the name of
improved agriculture. If the earth must lose that great
portion of its pleasantries which it owes to things that the
unlimited increase of wealth and population would extirpate
from it, for the mere purpose of enabling it to support a
larger, but not a better or a happier population, I sincerely
hope, for the sake of posterity that they will be content to
be stationary, long before necessity compels them to it.
Itfs all there:

a challenge to the unthinking assumption that

growth, per se, is good; a denunciation of money-grubbing and over­
consuming; a clear brief for the zero population advocates; and an eloquent
appeal for preservation of the environment.
The only thing missing is a complaint that we have become slaves
to technology.

This is missing because it was written a century ago.

The

author is John Stuart Mill, a genius who began learning Greek at the age
of three and ultimately became the outstanding economist of his age.
of his most intriguing contributions is the concept of the Stationary
State.




This concept is now captivating many who, overwhelmed by the

One

problems confronting society, wonder whether the solution might be simply
to stop this hectic pace of change and growth.

It is now fashionable to

talk of a new Stationary State.
What are the chances that a new Stationary State is the solution
to our social problems?

Let us look at this question from the points of

view of both Economic Han and Social Man.

Recipe for Growth
Economic Man has developed a most sophisticated recipe for growth,
and for the past century or so has been proudly serving up his product for
us all to consume.
and technology.

The recipe relies heavily on the ingredients of science

Scientists must be free to indulge their limitless curios­

ity about how nature works.

Technologists must be free to apply the fruits

of science to the satisfaction of human wants.
be willing to work to get them.

People must want things and

Producers must be free to turn out these

things with an ever-decreasing input of human effort— that is, with everincreasing productivity.
Economic Man may say that he attaches no moral connotations to
the result.

It is neither "good" nor "bad"; is simply what people want,

and if people want to risk cancer by smoking cigarettes, that is their
decision; the system is neutral.
with that position.

Actually, Economic Man is seldom content

He really believes that the freedom which the system

requires is "good," and that the system has tremendously improved the
physical well-being of mankind and that is "good."

Proof of the Pudding
It is true that we have made tremendous advances in overcoming
the niggardliness of nature and that the advances have been proceeding at
a faster and faster pace.




All of us have been made aware of this by a

barrage of gee-whiz statistics in current literature.

For example, Alvin

Toffler in Future Shock calculates that
. . . the child reaching teen age . . . is literally sur­
rounded by twice as much of everything newly man-made as
his parents were at the time he was an infant.
. . .
Since the increases are compounded, . . . by the time the
individual reaches old age the society around him will be
producing thirty-two times as much as when he was born.
It is also true— in the United States, at least— that a remarkably
large proportion of the people have participated in the growing affluence.
To some extent, this is because Social Man has made a conscious effort to
redistribute slices of the income pie, but to a great extent also it is
because Economic Man has done such a good job of enlarging the total size
of the pie.

We all owe a great debt to Economic Man, and Social Man should

not forget it.
But Social Man is not so coy about attaching values to economic
growth and, in his eyes, they are not all "good" ones.

For most of the

past century he has been striving to round off the rough corners of
economic growth.

His gadfly efforts have contributed child labor laws,

pure food and drugs, the progressive income tax, social security, and
countless other reforms.
Still he is not content.

Indeed, he feels he is losing ground.

Mill’s idea of the Stationary State, therefore, now looks like the ultimate
solution to the mounting problems of economic change.

Reaction to Change
This is a healthy reaction.
unquestioned assumptions.

It involves questioning many long-

In one of his columns in the New York Times,

Leonard Silk has written about J. K. Galbraith:




The real problem today, says Mr. Galbraith, is not
how fast we can increase production and consumption but
how well— how happily— we are to live.

!,In a rational life style, some people could find
contentment working moderately and then sitting by the
street— and talking, thinking, drawing, painting,
scribbling or making love in a suitably discreet way.
. . . None of these requires an expanding economy.11
Some other reactions, however, are not so healthy.
to seek refuge in nostalgia.

One has been

In Philadelphia we have a new magazine whose

journalistic precept (and I fm quoting from its own advertising) is that
. . . too much attention is being directed to the_counterproductive elements . . . in our society . . . /The/ cover
and graphics reflect the feel of a special quality, vintage
nostalgia, wherein we can more comfortably explore the con­
structive workings of our people and community . . . nostalgia
that reminds us that despite the problems and complications
of everyday living, life can still be romantic . . .
Another reaction has been fear and uncertainty, fear of change
and uncertainty in our ability to control it.

J. Irwin Miller, a leading

businessman and spokesman for the Committee for Economic Development—
probably the most enlightened group of Economic Men in the United States—
recently wrote an article entitled f,Can We Afford Tomorrow?11 He began by
saying that no earlier generation of Americans would have asked this.
Such a reaction might have been expected.

Ten years ago the

most contagious idea around was that the age-old problem of scarcity had
been licked.

Galbraith planted the seed with The Affluent Society.

Expectations, already rising for other reasons, were inflated still
further.
Now we see that scarcity was not dead after all; while we were
looking the other way it again has reared its ugly head, more fearsome
than ever.




No wonder people are pessimistic.

Recently, the president of the prestigious American Association
for the Advancement of Science gave an address in which he was asking
whether the ever-faster pace of growth, based on scientific discoveries,
could continue.

This is what he concluded:

. . . so awesome is already the accelerating rate of
our scientific and technological advance that simple
extrapolation of the exponential curves shows unmis­
takably that we have at most a generation or two before
progress must cease, whether because the world's popu­
lation becomes insufferably dense, or because we
exhaust the possible sources of physical energy or
deplete some irreplaceable resource, or because, most
likely of all, we pollute our environment to toxic,
irremediable limits . . .

. . . in future histories of the world the decade of
the 1960fs may be known . . . as the time when man,
with unbridled lust for power over nature and for a
so-called higher standard of living measured by the
consumption of the products of an industrial civili­
zation, set in motion the final speedy, inexorable
rush toward the end of progress.
In short, the reaction of Social Man to economic growth is that
he's been had.

Economic Man, he feels, may be a superb producer but a

miserable accountant.

What kind of an accounting system adds up on the

asset side all the wonderful gadgets which the system has turned out but
ignores pollution, exhaustion of resources, and human frustration on the
liability side?

It is time to put a halt to growth, especially now that

reputable scientists say growth is going to come to an end soon anyway.
With our minds freed from the compulsion to increase material wealth, to
consume more and more things, we can turn the full force of our attention
to the social problems threatening to overwhelm us.
what Social Man is saying, and I believe he is wrong.




This, I think is

Possible Courses
Consider these possible courses for society to follow.

Which

promises greatest success in solving our social problems?
Course //I is to slow the rate of economic change.

Population

growth would be zero; the increase in consumption of gadgets would be cut
back markedly; resources would be diverted to cleaning up the environment,
rebuilding the cities, upgrading education, and otherwise improving the
quality of life.
Course #2 is to encourage economic growth and change.

Economic

Man would be given incentives to use technology to raise productivity,
generating a rapid increase in incomes.

Out of these larger incomes more

would be made available for social and environmental use.
Course #1 may have more idealistic appeal, but it is not very
practical.

We talk about reordering priorities, but doing it is some­

thing else again.

I find it hard to see the average American sitting

still while a slower-growing pie is being sliced up in a radically dif­
ferent way.

He would, of course, benefit from clean water and no ghettos,

but the benefit will be hard to see and touch.

Perhaps he can be edu­

cated to equate a clear stream with a new car, but this would be a long
process.

In any case, Course #1 would take time; for example, even if

every couple started tomorrow to limit its family to two children, the
population would not level off for another 66 years.
Course #2 promises more immediate results.

It would follow

more easily from the path we have been taking; it would be better accepted
because it would provide a bigger pie to be sliced up; and it would make
greater use of the productive talents of Economic Man.

"But," Social

Man would say, f,how can we be sure this would not lead to even a worse




mess than we have now?"

Unfortunately, there is no good answer.

Neither Course #1 nor #2, therefore, is acceptable alone.
What we need is a course of action that combines the best of both.
call this Course #3.

I111

We should continue to encourage rapid growth but

gradually adopt some of those aspects of the Stationary State which are
so appealing to Social Man.
Let me suggest three important requirements for Course #3:
1. Incentives.
thing.

Economic Man should be encouraged to do his

To the extent a free and competitive marketplace accomplishes

this, fine.

To the extent Government must provide the incentive, this

should be done.

And to the extent "his thing" may produce undesired

social results, incentives should be provided to lead him in the right
direction.

I have in mind, for example, tax incentives to install anti­

pollution devices.

This route can best channel Economic Man's energies

in directions which Social Man desires.
2.

Science and technology.

turn back the clock.

It is foolish to talk as if we can

A few philosophers may see the results of science

and technology as dehumanizing, but most people see them as a miracle
that has spared them a great deal of back-breaking labor.

In any case,

once a scientist has set his curiosity going I doubt if anyone can turn
it off.

We'll need all the ingenuity he can bring to bear if we are to

develop a cleaner automobile engine or a quieter jet engine.

What must

be recognized, however, is that the results of his efforts can be "bad"
as well as "good" and that some means must be found to anticipate these
results and channel these efforts.




3* Planning,

This will require more planning than Economic Man

and probably less planning than Social Man would like.
more Government intervention.

It probably means

I see no alternative if rapid growth is

not to continue its collision course with pollution, exhaustion of re­
sources, and over-population.
The proper emphasis should be not on deliberate slowing of
growth but on deliberate planning, for planning may tend to slow growth
anyway.

For example, the president of American Cyanamid recently reported

that
15 years ago we would have been happy to develop a
plastic container that could be profitably marketed
because it provided a safe and more convenient package
for food or beverage. Today, we must inquire into the
plastic’s disposability. And if the answer is unsatis­
factory, we had better go back to the test tubes . . . .
Family planning will tend to slow down economic growth, although
not as much as businessmen might think.

Increases in population are not

as important to a growing economy as some other things, particularly
technology.

And in any case, emphasis should shift away from overall

growth to growth per capita; this is a much more sensible measure of
well-being.

Here, too, income per capita need not suffer significantly,

and could well benefit, from a slower population growth.
Finally, planning can help to stabilize the economy.

Rapid

growth will be increasingly unacceptable if it is periodically inter­
rupted by severe recessions.

Stop-and-go growth can be the most waste­

ful use of resources, human and physical.

But to prevent severe waste

it may be necessary when the economy is going too fast to slow it down
deliberately for a while in order to sustain growth in the longer run.




Conclusions
Course #3, with reliance on incentives and technology to stimulate
growth but also on planning to channel it into socially acceptable direc­
tions, is more likely to lead us to the Promised Land than is pursuit of
the new Stationary State.
Course #3 is a logical next step in the evolution of man’s efforts
to control his destiny.

When Economic Man first applied technology to the

satisfaction of human wants, he was rebelling against the blind laws of
nature.

Social Man wants to take the process one step further; he is

rebelling against the blind forces of growth.
A century ago Mill had a visionary idea.

He concluded that:

A stationary condition of capital and population implies
no stationary state of human improvement. There would be
as much scope as ever for all kinds of mental culture,
and moral and social progress; as much room for improving
the Art of Living, and much more likelihood of its being
improved, when minds cease to be engrossed by the art of
getting on.
In my opinion, this is something to work toward, but something
w e ’re not ready for.

For now we need economic growth, and it would be a

mistake to try to stop it.
growth.

But we need to work toward better control of

Hopefully, before another century has passed, w e ’ll have grown

up to Mill’s vision of the Art of Living.