View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

THE ROAD TO CONFIDENCE
Talk

by

David P. Eastburn, President
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
before the
Rotary Club of Philadelphia
Bellevue-Stratford Hotel, Philadelphia
February 17, 1971 - 12:15 p.m.

The biggest economic problem in 1971 is how to regain confi­
dence.

Surveys indicate that consumer confidence is about the lowest

in the 8 years it has been recorded.

Corporate profits are well below

their peak of 2 and 3 years ago, and businessmen are still worried
about the shape of their balance sheets.

Wages are rising at about

5 per cent a year, but wage earners1 real purchasing power has hardly
risen at all.

More people are out of work than in nearly a decade.

Prices are setting new records every month.

The balance-of-payments

deficit last year was higher than it has ever been.
All this is discouraging.

What is most discouraging, though,

is that progress in solving these problems is so slow.

The public has

been asked to be patient, but patience is running out.
I fd like to talk today about chances of a confidence break­
through in 1971.

To do this I want to look, first, at what I ’d like to

see happen this year; second, what seems most likely to happen; and,
third, what kind of policy will best restore a confidence that will last.

What I Td like to see happen
The ideal road to confidence would be by a rapid and lasting
recovery— with unemployment dropping quickly and the rate of inflation
moving steadily doxmward.
this:




An ideal recovery might go something like

-

2

-

The consumer comes alive again.

Instead of paying off

his debts and saving at near record levels, he starts
spending, especially for big ticket items like cars,
color television sets, refrigerators, furniture.

He

comes up out of the bargain basement and spends on
quality items.

With the consumer spending, the businessman starts to
regain confidence.

Merchants build their stocks.

New

orders pour into manufacturers and order backlogs
rise.

Industrial production rises rapidly and excess

capacity dwindles.

With unutilized capacity on the downslide, businessmen
step up their purchases of new plant and equipment.
Liberalized depreciation allowances, receptive bankers,
lower interest rates, and rising profits make funds
available for investment.

Funds would be available to support a healthy housing
boom, and houses would become available at prices
people could afford.

This is, perhaps, a classical pattern of business recovery,
the traditional road to new confidence.

In the process, unemployment

would drop from 6 to 5% to 5 to 4% per cent, and so on.

At the same

time, the rate of inflation would continue to decline from 5 to 4 to
3 per cent.




-

3

-

This happy combination of declining unemployment and dimin­
ishing inflation could occur because, even though the economy would
be accelerating, there would for a considerable time be enough slack
to keep prices from rising.

Moreover, with output increasing,

productivity would be rising rapidly, holding down costs per unit of
output.
What kind of public policy would we have?

As you know, the

President has adopted the high employment budget concept as his guide
to prudent fiscal policy.

In essence, the high employment budget

concept says that Government spending ought to equal Government
revenues at full employment, defined as a 4 per cent rate of
unemployment.
As long as unemployment remained high, the Federal Government
would run large deficits— thus helping to stimulate the economy and
create jobs.

As unemployment decreased, the budget deficit would

shrink because more people would be paying more taxes.

Finally, when

unemployment reached 4 per cent, the budget would be balanced.

Should

the economy become overheated and unemployment fall below 4 per cent,
the budget would run a surplus, and this would act as a check on
excess demand.
I believe the high employment concept is a major step forward
in fiscal policy.

Had we followed it in the 1960Ts, particularly during

the Vietnam buildup, we almost certainly would not have the inflation
problem we have today.

And I believe if we follow it in the future,

we will go a long way toward avoiding new rounds of inflation.




-

4

-

What kind of monetary policy would we have during this ideal
recovery?

The Federal Reserve would allow money and credit to grow fast

enough for unemployment to drop without planting the seeds for future
inflation.
Thus the budget and the Federal Reserve would be encouraging
recovery by stimulating demand.

If there were tendencies for prices to

be pushed upward by cost pressures, voluntary wage-price guidelines
could be invoked.

Business and labor would cooperate in observing the

guidelines because they would realize that price stability is in their
own long-run interest as well as the public interest.
Now, I fm not just trying to paint a pretty picture.

This is

not only in many respects the traditional road back to confidence, but
it is the course some people are predicting the economy will take in
1971.

I hope they are right.

But what are the probabilities?

What will likely happen?
In my judgment, the chances of this pattern occurring are on
the low side.
dence.

The odds are against a rapid and smooth return of confi­

I say this because the situation we are dealing with is unlike

any we have faced before.

We have had a worse economy before, but we

also expected less of it.

The gap between performance and expectations

is probably wider than it has ever been.
naturally reflects this gap.

The low level of confidence

At the same time, assurance that we know

how and are able to deal with our problems has been shaken by their
very complexity and by the slow progress in solving them.
What seems more likely to me, therefore, is that the economy
will recover gradually rather than rapidly.




Unemployment will fall,

5

but slowly rather than precipitously.

And the rate of inflation will

drop, but not dramatically.
Let’s look more closely at what is likely to happen to
important sectors in the economy:




The consumer will likely open his wallet a little wider
in the coming months.

He is likely to become somewhat

more confident about the economic outlook.

But he will

still know somebody who is unemployed and inflation will
still be chipping away at his paycheck.

So he is likely

to remain cautious about how he spends his money.

He’s

still going to look for bargains; h e ’s still going to be
reluctant about incurring new debt.

In short, the con­

sumer is likely to feel that the worst is over as far as
the economy is concerned but that things are still too
uncertain to throw caution to the winds.

Likewise, the businessman is going to feel better about
the economy, but probably not exuberant.

Most business­

men will probably keep a sharp eye on inventories.

They

would rather take a chance on being too low on stocks
than being too high, especially since inventory-sales
ratios are currently on the high side.

And, as long as

unused capacity remains high— currently over one-fourth
of industrial capacity is standing idle— it is doubtful
that business will increase outlays on new plant and
equipment.

-

6

-

As for housing, this sector probably has the greatest
chance of being strong in 1971.

There is a big demand

for housing and funds are becoming available for
financing.

But the outlook is clouded by rising costs.

In short, the probabilities seem to point to a GNP well under
$1,065 billion, to a gradual recovery rather than a rapid one.
A gradual recovery means that unemployment probably will
continue to rise for a time.
returning servicemen
year.

The reason is that new people, such as

and teenagers, come into the labor force each

If the economy does not grow fast enough to generate jobs for

them, some will end up being unemployed.
about mid-year.

This seems likely until

Then unemployment should level off and begin to fall.

On the inflation front, in contrast to what I would like to
see happen, I suspect w e ’re in for only slow progress.

Demand-pull

inflation is dead, but cost-push inflation remains very much alive.
Although wages are rising less rapidly in non-unionized industries,
union wage settlements do not seem to be abating.

Gains in productivity

will help to moderate cost pressures to some extent, but sustainable
progress against inflation will not come until wage settlements
become more moderate.

So, I suspect that we will see some unwinding

of inflation, but progress will be disappointingly slow.
Given this kind of outlook in the private sector, what can
we expect from public policy?

For one thing, with inflation continuing

stubborn, we will probably hear more about an incomes policy.
will continue to debate about it:




Can it work?

People

Would it do more good

-

than harm?

7

-

Specifically, what should it be?

or mandatory?

etc.

Should it be voluntary

We could debate the matter here, but the important

question is, what is likely to happen?

My guess is that efforts to

deal directly with wages and prices will have some effect but far less
than most advocates of an incomes policy would hope.
As far as the budget is concerned, a slower recovery would
mean a larger deficit than officially forecast.

The deficit would be

larger because there would be a smaller increase in tax receipts.

Also,

Federal expenditures may exceed the $229 billion figure in the
President’s proposed budget.
These kinds of probabilities raise important questions for
the Federal Reserve.

I believe that the Federal Reserve should provide

enough money and credit for the economy to expand so that unemployment
can be reduced.

But, I also believe that the Fed must continue to be

concerned about inflation.

In other words, the Fed should not allow

money and credit to expand so rapidly in 1971 that we plant the seeds
for another inflationary spiral in 1972 or 1973.

Conclusions
The road back to confidence does not seem likely to be smooth
or easy— or short.

This news will disappoint some impatient, dis­

illusioned people and could make the return to confidence even harder.
But there are great risks in promising too much.
Man is an adaptable creature.

During an inflation of five

years, the worst in twenty, he has adapted.

He can adapt again to a non-

inf lationary economy, but it is unreasonable to expect him to do this
rapidly and easily.




-

8

-

You may not like the prospects of only a gradual economic
recovery, but the chances of ending up with lasting confidence in a
stable and prosperous economy seem better if we take this route.
we try to go too fast, we could end up with even worse inflation.
Public policy should take the economy along a course that brings
gradual, steady improvement without stimulating new inflationary
pressures.

The road back may be longer, but when we get to our

destination w e fre more likely to stay for a while.

2/17/71




If