View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

HOW TO IMPROVE FED DECISIONS
OR
MUDDLING THROUGH WITH THE FOMC

Paul Volcker's reappointment as Chairman of the Federal
Reserve has reassured the financial community, but it may yet
cause him to wish he had quit while he was ahead. Having played
a key role in bringing inflation down, he now faces the even
more difficult job of guiding the economy along a smooth path
to non-inflationary growth. The odds are against him.
In his remaining time - he has indicated he may not stay
the full four years of his new term.-the most lasting contribution
he can make is to improve the Fed's decision process. This, too,
will not be easy. He will need to bring along the eleven (actually
eighteen) other individuals - and individualists - who participate
with him in the Fed's most important policy making body, the
Federal Open Market Committee; he will have to work against
entrenched habits and traditions; and he must take some risks.
Given his performance up to now, the task is doable; its completion
would leave a legacy for years to come.
Other Fed Chairmen have made changes as times have demanded
and as their unique styles have required. Arthur Burns, in
particular, is mostly responsible for the FOMC's current decision
process, introducing an element of the seminar (with himself
as professor) but also sharpening and quantifying the end product.
As Volcker builds on this foundation, he will do well to take
advantage of a body of theory and practice of decisionmaking
that has now grown to substantial proportions. One may doubt
that this accumulated wisdom qualifies for the term "science"
sometimes claimed for it - there is too much art in decisionmaking
for that - but it does have a reasonably firm basis in observed




-

2

-

behavior of individuals and groups and in empirical evidence
from psychological experiments. Decision theorists analyze
such phenomena as the risky shift (the idea that participants
end with riskier positions after discussion than before), how
bargaining works, the influence of peer on peer, deliberations in
friendly and hostile environments, the role of preparation,
procrastination, bolstering (i.e. rationalization of positions
and denial of responsibility) and so on. All are relevant to
the FOMC, but two concepts are particularly enlightening. One
is muddling through, an idea developed by Charles Lindblom
at Yale; the other is group-think, a theory expounded by Irving
Janis, also at Yale.
Lindblom backs into muddling through, (his more dignified
term is "disjointed incrementalism") by looking first at the
ideal, rational-deductive decision process. This approach to
decisions involves the common-sense, scientific, steps of defining
the problem, canvassing alternatives, weighing benefits and costs,
assimilating all possible information, planning implementation,
establishing contingency plans, etc. etc. The difficulty with
this approach, Lindblom says, is that it never works. The human
mind, even with he)lp of computers, can't grasp all contingencies,
alternatives and outcomes, nor can it sort out and prioritize
the unstable and fluid values underlying alternatives. The
ideal process ignores shortness of time and resources and limitations
(or a plethora) of information. So the best course is to nibble
away - incrementalism, muddling through. Problems are never
really "solved"; they don't stand still long enough for that.
Small changes are made serially in the direction of improvement
or, more frequently, away from disaster. Graham



-

3

-

T. Alliscn, of Harvard, in dissecting the decision process
explaining the Cuban missile crisis in the 1960's, has described
government action more precisely. "The best explanation of an
organization's' behavior at t",he writes, "is t-- 1; the best
prediction of what will happen at t + 1 is t".
In essence, muddling through is the democratic process,
with all its strengths and weaknesses. The "intelligence of
democracy," another Lindblom concept, flows from this imperfect,
pragmatic, counter-balanced, zig-zagging approach to solving
problems. No one charismatic genius with a bank of computers
could do nearly as well.
If muddling through is the intelligence of democracy, group
think is the unintelligence of a cabal. Janis bases his concept
on analyses of some major debacles i-n history, including Vietnam
Bay of Pigs, and Korea in the Johnson, Kennedy and Truman
administrations. Group-think decisions were those made by a
small, tightly-knit, insulated group dedicated to a common
purpose. Within the group a strong sense of conformity and
us-against-them psychology produced a calloused view of costs
and a blindness to alternatives, risks and unfavorable outcomes.
FOMC decisions contain elements of both muddling through
and group-think. Volcker would do well to bring in a decision
theorist to help find ways to muddle through with greater
purpose and precision and to break down the barriers of groupthink. The effort should cover the entire scope of FOMC decision
making, but especially five component aspects: the FOMC group,
tradition, independence, eclecticism, and secrecy. Because all
are closely interrelated they must be treated together. In a
very real sense, they are the FOMC.



-

4

-

The group
The dynamics of the FOMC center in the interaction between
the Chairman and members. The Chairman clearly plays a leading
role and is spokesman, but his power lies primarily in his
persuasive talents; he has only one vote in twelve. William
Me Chesney Martin,Chairman in the -1950's and 1960's, led by
force of personality. Participants read their prepared remarks
in fixed order (clockwise around the table at one meeting,
counter-clockwise at the next) before Martin would state the
consensus. Observers recall occasions when individual positions
varied widely only to have the Chairman remark with a benign smile
that "we're not very far apart today" and proceed to state his own
version of the "consensus." Arthur Burns, Chairman in the 1970's,
encouraged freer discussion, but he also waited until the end
to announce his position - usually; on important occasions, he
stated the problem and his conclusions at the outset. During
discussion he interjected comments freely on all kinds of issues,
including, for example, the validity of the latest month's
statistic on new orders for durable goods. Volcker more or less
follows the Burns pattero.
In general, FOMC discussion has not been dominated, at least
in objectionable and overt ways, by the Chairman. Group-think
tendencies are not largely traceable to that source.
The composition of the group, however, raises substantial
problems. Aside from the Chairman the other members of the FOMC
are the six other Governors of the Federal Reserve Board and
five Presidents of the regional Federal Reserve Banks. Since the
Presidents (except for the President of the New York Bank who



-

5

-

is a permanent member of the FOMC) serve in rotation and since
all twelve of them participate in all FOMC meetings, "the group"
is really nineteen individuals.
A profile of a typical participant currently looks like
this:
o male
o white
o 55 years old
o 14 years' experience in the Fed (including
before becoming Governor or President)

his experience

o about two-fifths of total working life in the Fed
o professional training in economics
o holder of a Ph D degree
o at one time or another a teacher of economics
Concealed by this quick sketch is some variation in characteristics.
Ages range from 40 to 69, experience in the Fed from a few months
to 30 years. There are two women and one black; a couple members
with law or business degrees; some who have worked in banking
or business; and a number who have served in Government. Yet
characteristics of participants are remarkably uniform.
One distinguishing characteristic of participants is their
geographic base. The seven Governors of the Federal Reserve
Board, originally from many parts of the United States, have spent
considerable years in Washington D.C. - fourteen on average.
They have had long exposure to the political atmosphere dominating
the capital. The twelve Presidents of Reserve Banks, on the other
hand, come to the meeting with exposure to widely differing
economies, from booming Texas to depressed Ohio. The influence of
these varied environments is difficult to discern in any consistent
pattern of voting, but is frequently apparent in discussion.



-

6

-

What changes might be made? Unfortunately, immediate
opportunities for broadening the group are limited. Assuming
the present Governors remain for their full terms and the
Presidents serve until mandatory retirement, the typical member
has about ten years to go. Vet five of the group - Governors
Nancy Teeters, Charles Partee and Henry Wallich and Presidents
Anthony Solomon of New York and John Balles of San Francisco
either reach the end of their terms or retirement age within
five years. In addition, William Ford has resigned as President of
the Atlanta Bank. All are economists.

Variety in the FOMC would

be served if the replacements of some of them were individuals
with broad and practical experience in finance, business or
government. A Ph D in economics is helpful but not necessary
for useful service on the FOMC. Prior experience in the Fed is
also an asset, but to offset tendencies toward inbreeding it
would be refreshing to have the new members come in from the
outside. Even within the present comp-osition of the group,
opportunities should be sought to increase the role of Presidents
of the Reserve Banks, particularly those not currently voting.
Differences in their view points emanating from varied geography
and staff advice could inject an important element of variety.
A case in point is preparation for the meetings. The common
denominator is a set of analyses of economic and financial
conditions and prospects prepared and presented by the Washington

* This is somewhat of an oversimplification. They have also worked
for various periods and in various capacities in business,
banking, government and academia. But they all share a strong
background in economics.




-

7

-

staff in the Greenbook. Quantity is voluminous and quality is
impressive, but it would help to broaden discussion by having
other material and viewpoints presented by Reserve Bank Presidents
or outside economists.
One result might be more spirited controversy. As things are,
discussion is restrained, lengthy, and technical. Because the FOMC
meets so frequently there is often not much new to discuss, and
because participants have met together so many times they seldom
are surprised by what their colleagues say. A participant once
was heard to observe: "Everybody's position is completely
predictable, including mine."
One of the penalties of incrementalism, in short, is a
certain sameness. But it needn't be so. It is entirely possible
to vary the cast of characters by asking a member (again, perhaps,
a non-voting President) to serve as devil's advocate. Invited
guests could make special presentations. Meetings could be made
less frequent, routine decisions handled with more dispatch, and
special sessions held to debate broader and less immediate
concerns.
More variety in discussion would, of course, make it more
difficult for the Chairman to bring it all into focus for a
policy decision. The vehicle for this now is the directive to
the manager of the open market account, the person who supervises
activities in supplying or reducing the volume of reserves in
the open market. It is in specifying the directive that the
Chairman's leadership comes into full play, for in corralling
the largest possible majority he engages in a subtle bargaining
game with respect to guidelines for money growth and



-

8

-

money-market interest rates.* Discussion can become drawn out and
tedious, centering on fairly fine differences of a few basis
points in money rates or a few percentage points in money growth.
Chairman Burns with good reason sometimes deplored the
"narcissistic" proclivities of seme participants, implying
that such fine differences were a matter of personal vanity
and were more than swamped by margins of ignorance in the art
of monetary policy.
In the end, votes focus on this directive, non-voting
Presidents more or less retiring to the sidelines. The Chairman
may find it impossible to avoid some dissents because a move
in a direction to mollify one participant will alienate another.
Dissents are not infrequent, but members of the FOMC place high
value on consensus, in periods of pressure from the outside
will band together to support the Chairman, and usually are
restrained in public statements about-their dissenting views.
Incrementalism means that changes usually are small and
opportunities for correction come frequently. The large size
of the group helps to assure that a point missed by one member
is caught by another. Because policy is made by consensus it moves
slowly. Rarely does it make sharp turns in direction, working like
a moving average in statistics. A lone dissenting member gradually
gains allies in succeeding meetings, a minority becomes a majority
* In one meeting a member, trying to help Chairman Burns bridge
an impasse, offered: "Mr. Chairman, if you do so and so I
believe you would buy a couple of votes." Burns bridled and
replied, "I'm not in the business of 'buying' votes". He was,
of course, doing just that in almost every meeting.




-

9

-

and policy changes. It is a gradual, smooth, careful, responsible,
and often uninspired process - muddling through.
More attention to the longer run could provide direction
to incrementalism. For a considerable time the Fed was urged
to specify annual targets for money growth and finally complied
only after Congressional legislation. Now the Fed is under pressure
to target its objectives for major variables like economic growth,
prices and unemployment. Although it's understandable that the
FOMC would resist being pinned down, the exercise would help
further to focus short-run policy actions. There seems little
danger that the FOMC will be carried away by long-run goals at the
expense of short-run flexibility.
As for group-think, tendencies in that direction can be
offset by changing the composition of the group as opportunities
arise and opening up possibilities for varied viewpoints to be
expressed. Janis makes much of the intolerance of dissent in
group-think situations. This element is not present in the extreme
in FOMC deliberations, and Volcker, unlike Burns, who could wear
the group down in pursuit of unanimity, seems content to live
with a number of dissenting votes. Yet, among the group there
is a certain feeling of fraternity, a certain espirit that comes
from sharing a common purpose as well as long tradition, and
this characteristic does have group-think implications.
Tradition
The FOMC can't do much very drastic about tradition even
if it might want to, but it should be aware of the influence
tradition exerts so that useful elements can be reinforced and
harmful elements dampened. A key to FOMC tradition is tnst its
members consider themselves central bankers, part of a centuriesold, honorable



and elite profession. Writing over

-

10

-

a century ago, Walter Bagehot, the English student of central
banking, concluded that "money will not manage itself." The
idea that, left to its own devices the economy would deteriorate
into inflationary chaos gives FOMC members not only a strong
sense of public dedication but- must, subconsciously at least,
impart a feeling of power and superiority, perhaps mixed with
a twinge of paranoia. Marriner Eccles, Chairman in the 1930's
and 1940's, reflected some of this when he described the Fed's
duty as "leaning against the wind." William McChesney Martin,
Chairman in the 1950's and 1960's likened the task to that of
the chaperone, forever removing the punch bowl just as the party's
getting good.
One must have strength of character to lean against winds
and remove punch bowls. One must know that the wind is blowing
the wrong way and when more punch is bad for the health. Only
a wise parent can do for us what is good for us. To take the
unpopular action invites persecution and through persecution
comes strength.
There is danger in being carried away by this kind of
psychoanalysis, but it sheds some light on-a number of things.
It helps to explain, for example, the Fed's dogged insistence
on independence, about which more in a moment. It illuminates
the relationship of long and short run, already referred to.
FOMC members believe their actions are a necessary balance wheel
in an erratic and unstable environment pushed off center by
politicians, unions and others driven by short-run expediency.
Only an independent Fed, they believe, can look over and beyond
the immediate. Actually, as we've seen, FOMC decisions are almost



-

11

-

completeiy incremental and short-run. This contrast provides
further reason for the FOMC to focus policy more on the long-run;
it needs to put its practice where its tradition is.
Most important, tradition strongly influences the value
systems of FOMC members. It causes them to be essentially conserva­
tive, not necessarily in the usual sense, but in the- sense that,
like their brother central bankers in centuries past, they
dedicate themselves to conserving the value of the currency;
fighting inflation is in the blood. Some participants vote consis­
tently for more expansive or less restrictive policies than others,
but all share the basic tradition. It is taken for granted,
to the extent that members never discuss in depth their underlying
economic philosophy and values.
A case in point is a speech which Paul Volcker made not
long ago at a human relations award dinner in Los Angeles.
He joked at the outset that when he mentioned to an associate
the challenge of talking about humanitarianism and central banking,
the response was that it would be a pretty short speech. Not so,
said the Chairman, launching into an argument why "discipline"
is necessary for human welfare(mercifully forbearing reference
to free lunches). It was a fine speech, made eminently good
sense, and articulated effectively the views of all his colleagues.
The point is not that these values are right or wrong, but that
they are never exposed to debate.
The FOMC would do well to spend some time in introspection.
Making policy incrementally .does not require this. Lindblom
argues, in fact, that settling on a value system is not only
impossible but gets in the way. Values are more likely-to




-

12

-

flow from action than the other way around. It may not be too
much to ask of the people who have so much power over the rest
of us, however, that they do some weighing, measuring and arguing,
about, say, the human costs of inflation as opposed to unemployment,
the pain of recessions in the short run against the benefits of
growth in the longer run. Who knows, their values might even
change. Certainly, the "discipline" the Fed is willing to impose
today is a great deal less harsh than that it inflicted in the
1920's and 1930's. Values and tradition, it seems, can also
move incrementally.
Independence
The Fed mounts the ramparts when any outside force threatens
its independence, so it's hardly likely to take the initiative
in tampering with it. Yet the independence- issue has such a
strong influence on policy making that it should be explored
with some openness of mind. This is difficult for members of
the FOMC to do for each of them has absorbed and expounded the
gospel: independence is within government, not from government;
the Fed is responsible to Congress, not the President; insulation
from narrow partisan politics is essential for sound monetary
policy. Each member takes umbrage whenever it is said policy is
slanted to influence an election. Independence is a matter of
personal- integrity. This feeling of rectitude helps to explain
such things as the indignation of Arthur Burns and his colleagues
with a magazine article alleging that he interrupted an FOMC
meeting to get instructions from the White House. It just isn't
done.




-

13

-

In two decades of observing and participating in FOMC
deliberations I never have witnessed a decision deliberately
slanted for political purposes. On numerous occasions, timing
of a decision has been influenced by a desire to avoid the
impression of political motivation; during election campaigns?,
for example, Fed officials try to lie as low as possible. Occasionally
a Reserve Bank President may feel that a rejection by the Governors
of a recommended discount rate for his bank reflects undue
sensitivity to political conditions in Washington; the Governors,
in turn, may regard the Reserve Bank President as naive about
prevailing realities. This is the stuff of which independence
usually is made - small shadings of action rather than cataclysmic
confrontations.
1 he psychological impact on policymakers of the independence
issue, is complex: a Caesar's-wife approach to political involve­
ment; a suspicion of entrapment in cooperative governmental
programs; stubborness in safeguarding freedom of maneuver;
soul-searching in distinguishing between fundamental desires
of the electorate and short-run political gyrations; and
satisfaction from the frequent exclamation, "With all those
politicians in Washington, thank God for the Federal Reserve!"
Given the deep and complex feelings it arouses, therefore,
independence is not something to tinker with; caution is advised.
With respect to the Fed's relations with Congress no change is
required. The Fed is responsible to Congress and the Chairman
seems to be testifying before some committee or other almost
daily. He frequently is staving off attempts to intervene
directly in the Fed's business and rightly insists




that the

-

14

-

FOMC be given sufficient leeway to do its job. Like any good
boss, Congress should lay down the general guidelines, delegate
responsibility to carry them out, and then assess performance.
With respect to the Executive Branch, it seems possible to
explore closer relations between the FOMC and certain administration
officials. The Chairman, of course, sees Treasury officials
regularly, other officials frequently, and the President sometimes.
It would be helpful to invite the Treasury Secretary or Under
secretary to an FOMC meeting from time to time for an exchange of
views. The same might be done with the Chairman of the Council
of Economic Advisers. The FOMC is not likely to be tainted
permanently.
Ultimately, independence rests on good performance and good
performance is facilitated by good decision-making. The fact
that the Fed has retained most of its independence and is
supported in that posture by most of the nation's citizens
speaks1- well for past decisionmaking. Preservation of independence
can be helped by improving the decision process as time goes on.
Eclecticism
If independence is sacred

and untouchable, ecclecticism

is nearly so. An eclectic view of how monetary policy works
makes for flexibility, and flexibility is an integral part of
muddling through. Lindblom argues that theory is not necessary
for incremental decisionmaking, and, like values, can actually
get in the way. Members of the FOMC would be the last to say
they have no theory of how policy works, but each of them has
his own theory and the amalgam of these shifts over time.




-

15

-

Historically, the Fed always has resisted pressures to
focus on a single objective or guide to policy. In the 1920's,
long hearings in Congressional committee on ways to stabilize
prices found the Fed arguing the need to look at many aspects
of the economy. After the Great Depression, many efforts to have
the Fed focus solely on full employment and, more recently,
Congressional pressure to target desired real interest rates met
the same response. Eclecticism has become part of tradition.
Eclecticism and independence go hand in hand. The Fed
resists being tied down to a theory, goal or operating procedure
partly because it can thereby act more independently. But
eclecticism also bespeaks a good deal of humility in approaching
the art of monetary policy. FOMC members see the economy as a
most complex and ever-changing mechanism which, despite advances
in economics over the years, is only dimly understood, let
alone controlled. The Fed entered the age of econometrics long
since, but probably no one on the FOMC has enough faith in models
to rely on them heavily. A distrust of forecasting models is
particularly critical given the fact that monetary policy exerts
its effects with such long and uncertain lags. So members of the
FOMC prefer to look at everything, sift it through their judgments,
and then decide, but decide subject to the arrival of new
information from all sources at any time.
Many critics are unhappy with this way of conducting monetary
policy. Most of them have some particular thing they would like
the Fed to concentrate on: unemployment, prices, interest rates,
the money supply. More thoughtful observers fault eclecticism
on grounds that the Fed can accomplish only one thing at a time;




-

16

-

if it concentrates on keeping interest rates stable, for example,
it can't control the money supply. The Fed's response always
has been that it will use its best judgment under prevailing
circumstances in balancing multiple goals and guides and that
lack of perfection in reaching all of them is preferable to
tying itself down to any one of them.
This answer satisfies nobody, but it's the right one.
Knowledge is so incomplete, conditions so changeable that this
kind of eclecticism is the most practical and workable way to
live in a muddling-through world. The FOMC can, however, take
action on two fronts, one specific and the other general, to
make the eclectic approach more effective. Specifically, the
FOMC can exploit maximum possibilities of the Bluebook. The
Bluebook is a vehicle of eclectic philosophy, an ingenious
document that serves most effectively to focus decisions and
shorten debate. FOMC staff developed it some years ago to
bridge a gap between members who tended to concentrate on money
growth as the important guide to policy and members who thought
interest rates most important. The Bluebook presents combinations
of money growth and money rates likely in the period immediately
ahead assuming various conditions. Monetarist and Keynesian
alike can choose from this smorgasbord without engaging in timeconsuming theological argument. The Bluebook, has, however,
tended at times to exclude possibilities that should be
considered. Usually, it presents three alternative combinations
of money growth and interest rates: those with no change from
current policy, those with an easier policy, and those with a
more restrictive policy. The Bluebook is a successful and handy



-

17

-

tool of eclecticism, but breaking out of the standard format
from time to time and presenting a larger choice of possibilities
could prevent it from becoming confining.
More generally, the FOMC should exercise self-discipline
in using eclecticism as a copout. Persistent research into
aspects of how monetary policy works - exploring such phenomena
as relationships between money rates and money growth, between
both of them and the economy, and the efficacy of various measures
of money - is essential. "The answer" will never be forthcoming,
and so the FOMC will continue an eclectic approach; but the more
it knows, the better it can muddle-through less haphazardly and
aimlessly. Self-discipline can help the FOMC remain accountable.
Eclecticism offers too many temptations to get off the hook; if
Ml is exceeding the targeted growth path, for example, M2 can
then be made the significant target. In the nature of things,
although the FOMC possesses great power, its power is ambiguous,
and where there is ambiguous power there is ambiguous responsibility.
It is always possible to say that monetary policy didn't work
as intended because Government ran a big deficit or OPEC jacked
up oil prices. Usually this is true, but there are enough external
forces at work to excuse monetary policy without the FOMC adding
internal fudging through its eclectic approach.
Secrecy
Possibilities for making immediate and substantial changes
in the FOMC group, its tradition, independence and eclectic
philosophy may be limited, but steps can be taken right away
to reduce the secrecy surrounding the FOMC. This will not be
easy for the FOMC to do partly because secrecy serves as a cement
that helps bind "the group" together. One of the perqs for serving



-

18

-

on the FOMC (what at salary-review time has been called "the
public-service discount") is the psychic income derived from helping
to formulate monetary policy. This satisfaction is enhanced by
the secrecy enveloping FOMC deliberations; at least for a time
we know something that all of you out there don't.

*

Kenneth Boulding, the economist, wrote a paper in the late
1960's on "The Legitimacy of Central Banks." With that touch
of whimsey that often rings so true, Boulding listed among the
ingredients of legitimacy what he called an element of mystery.
"Whether", he wrote, "the central banks should try to enlighten
the public and to dispel the mystery is a nice point. It may
well be that their own legitimacy is best fostered by preserving
a certain air of charismatic obscurity about their operations.
Their officers might even take to wearing gowns and robes and
their public pronouncements might be couched in even more mysterious
and impressive language than they nowuse."
It's all part of central banking tradition. Central banks
by and large have preferred to let their actions speak for
themselves rather than be explained. In recent years, sunshine
legislation has opened up some Federal Reserve deliberations, but
FOMC meetings are exempt. Secrecy enhances independence of action
and makes it easier to pursue an eclectic course; fewer awkward
questions are likely to be asked.
* In October 1979, I received a call from the Secretary of the
FOMC who was arranging what turned out to be the meeting in
which policy procedures were radically changed. I was not to
tell my secretary or my policy advisor of the meeting and
was to buy my own train ticket. Secrecy can add a touch of
spice.




-

19

-

The official rationale for secrecy, of course, is none
of the above. It is based mainly on the idea that secrecy makes
for more effective policy. For one thing, participants feel
freer in discussion. For another, it is more feasible to experiment;
probing action can be taken in the market and reversed if necessary
without it becoming a big deal. Both reasons make much sense,
but a third is more controversial. It is that open information
can disturb the market and give unfair advantage, to some market
participants. Critics counter with a general principle of markets:
the better the information the better they work. They contend
that by witholding information the FOMC hinders implementation
of its policy. At any rate, although the issue is still open,
FOMC meetings are still closed. Results of the deliberations are
released much sooner (about a month afterward) than they used to
be, but that has evolved only under a good deal of pressure and
criticism.
It is time to lessen the degree of secrecy. As Janis points
out, most errors in group-think situations come from lack of
exposure of the group to ideas from the outside and exposure of
the group's deliberations to the outside. Some of the suggestions
made above such as bringing others occasionally into FOMC meetings
would help to combat this. The time has also come to announce
results of each FOMC meeting immediately. Steps in recent years
to shorten the release time has not had ill effects, and market
participants have become so sophisticated in monitoring open
market activities that they are unlikely to be greatly upset
by word from the horse's mouth. It is true that the FOMC
may give up some element of flexibility, but the greater knowledge
and certainty from immediate disclosure would be worth it. Further



-

20

-

inroads on secrecy are possible, but the time is not yet.
Conclusions
The way the FOMC makes its decisions is not bad, but it
could be better. A better decision process is likely to (although
not guaranteed to) produce better decisions. Those decisions
would encompass a wider variety of viewpoints. They would look
more toward the longer run, leaving shorter run problems to the
market system to take care of. They would be more promptly and
thoroughly explained to the public. And they would reflect a
more thorough consideration of the human and philosophical
values underlying them.
Paul Volcker understands the FOMC, its cast of characters,
its tradition and philosophy, and its methods. He is accustomed
to incremental change, although he also has made a few sharp
zigs and zags during his tenure. The changes suggested here may
strike the layman as mild and inoffensive, but together they
constitute a departure from current practice that would be hard
for some FOMC members to accept. Whether they are adopted in
detail is not important; their major thrust is toward a more
open and innovative attitude in decisionmaking. In various
situations Volcker has indicated a capability of thinking the
unthinkable and acting thereon. He has accomplished a great
deal of what he set out to do in bringing down inflation, for
which we are all grateful. Before he leaves the public scene
for perhaps more lucrative pursuits, bringing new life to the
FOMC could pay even bigger dividends for us all.