View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

The Fed in a

Political W o rld *
By David P. East burn, President
Federal Reserve Bank of
Philadelphia

Anyone following the banking press at all
closely will notice questions like these
appearing frequently:

There is a strong political overtone to each of
these questions. Yet, it is frequently said that
the Fed is nonpolitical. Which is it? Are we
political, or aren’t we? A simple “ yes” or “ no”
answer, I’m afraid, is just that—too simple. A
more realistic way to phrase the question is:
how political is the Fed and in what sense?
In a broad sense the Fed must be part of the
political process. Politics is the art of
government—in our system, representative
government. Government must do what the
people want; politics is the process of dis­
covering what they want and how to get it for
them.
Accordingly, the Fed must be responsive to
the public. To say that it is nonpolitical—at
least in this broad sense—implies that the Fed
knows better than the people themselves
what they should have. This is an elitist view
inconsistent with our form of government.
Yet, there is something special about the
Federal Reserve. It manages the money sup­
ply. A lesson in history is that sovereigns fre­
quently have abused their power to manage
money. Some years ago we published an

• Whether the Fed in the eyes of Congress is
putting enough money into theeconomy to
assure recovery.
• Whether it is proper for a Federal Reserve
Bank to spend nearly $80 for cigars.
•W hether the Fed should be audited by the
General Accounting Office.
•W hether appointments of Federal Reserve
Bank Presidents should be confirmed by the
Senate.
•W hether the Fed will push up the money
supply in order to help reelect President
Ford in 1976 as some people allege it did for
President Nixon in 1972.

. *A lecture delivered at the Graduate School of Bank'ng. University of Wisconsin, Madison, August 11, 1975.
The views expressed are mine and do not necessarily
'•fleet those of my colleagues in the Federal Reserve

System.




3

BUSINESS REVIEW

OCTOBER 1975

analysis of this history which pointed out how
Henry VIII at one time became known as Old
Copper Nose.1 The reason was that once he
needed money and called in all the silver
coins, and melted and recoined them with a
copper base. As the new coins became worn
and blotched, the most prominent part of
Henry's features, his nose, protruded through
the thin silver coating in a dull relief of
copper—hence, Old Copper Nose. Even our
own George Washington was saddled with
the problem of paying his troops with paper
money that declined so precipitously in value
that the Continental dollar cost more to print
than it was worth as money.
Given this long history of abuse, the
founders of the Federal Reserve System had
good reason for insulating the Fed from
narrow political pressures. The Fed is non­
political in this sense. Its fortunes are not tied
to the reelection of any Government official.
It is for this reason that any official in the Fed
properly resents allegations that policy has at
any time been slanted to influence elections.
Having either observed or participated in
meetings of the Open Market Committee for
a decade and a half, I can recall not a single in­
stance when this motivation was present
either explicitly or implicitly.
There is constant tension between these
two concepts—being responsive to the public
in the broad sense and being insulated from
narrow, short-run politics. This tension
characterizes much of what happens in the
Fed. It is seen in what we do and how we do it.

liberals tend to advocate full employment
policies, conservatives a stable dollar. The
emphasis given to these objectives shifts over
time. Last year public opinion polls indicated
that inflation was the number one problem.
Now it is unemployment. The Fed finds itself
constantly in the middle, trying to reconcile
these two views. For example, in recent Con­
gressional hearings some experts argued for
increasing money at the rate of 10 percent a
year in order to reduce unemployment.
Others argued that money growth should be
kept considerably below this rate because of
the fear of resumption of double-digit infla­
tion.
The official Fed position is that unemploy­
ment is the short-run problem, and that we
should try to facilitate recovery and bring
down unemployment. Inflation, though, is
the long-run problem and we must be careful
not to rekindle it. Overstimulating the
economy now to achieve greater success on
the unemployment front is likely to produce
another round of double-digit inflation later.
The Fed must keep an eye on both the short
and long run when making policy. I agree
with this position but would feel better about
it if there were stronger Government
programs to deal with unemployment by
other means. These include liberalized un­
em ploym ent compensation and more
vigorous commitments to public service jobs,
more effective training, and a more enter­
prising minimum-income program.
The pushing and pulling between the ob­
jectives of stable prices and full employment,
whatever the outcome today, will be a
political struggle which will be with us for,a
long time. It involves value judgments on
which people have strong differences.

WHAT THE FED DOES
This is the biggest political issue because it is
the most fundamental. It has to do with the
kind of economy the people want. Let me
make a generalization that is oversimplified
but nevertheless says a lot about the environ­
ment in which the Fed operates: political

HOW THE FED DOES IT
Dispersion of Power through Organization.
Political considerations strongly influence the
ways in which the Fed goes about ac­
complishing its objectives. They are reflected
first of all in its organization. The Federal
Reserve Act was very much the result of a

’“ Henry VIII Revisited: The Problems and Temptations
of Money Creation,” B u s in e ss R e v ie w of the Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, January 1960, pp. 3-18.




4

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

political process and the founders of the
System had political considerations in mind
when they hammered out the organizational
framework.
Internally, the organization emphasizes
dispersion of power. In this sense, the
organization of the Fed parallels that of
government. Heading the System is the Board
of Governors—seven Governors, not one as
in most other central banks—appointed by
the President and confirmed by the Senate. As
a further dispersion of power, the Fed has 12
semi-autonomous Banks. Each Bank has a
Board of nine Directors. Three come from
banking, three from the ranks of borrowers,
and three (those appointed by the Board of
Governors) from the public at large. The
Federal Open Market Committee (which has
the major responsibility for monetary policy
formation) is a combination of the Board of
Governors and Presidents of Federal Reserve
Banks. The Federal Advisory Council is a
group of bankers which advises the Board of
Governors. This is a complicated mixture of
different groups designed to avoid concen­
tration of power in one person or place.
Authority over policy tools is also dis­
tributed. The Board of Governors determines
reserve requirem ents and sets many
regulations, such as Regulation Q and margin
requirements. Open Market operations are
governed by the Federal Open Market Com­
mittee. The discount rate is set by each Board
of Directors subject to review and deter­
mination by the Board of Governors.2
In all these arrangements the Board of
Governors has most of the power and this is as
it should be, but the decentralized nature of
the organization and the decision-making

process provides an internal balance to this
power. Although it is inevitable that power
relationships will change in this kind of an ad­
ministrative situation, the "dispersion princi­
ple" is so fundamental to the Fed and the
national interest that power shifts over time
should be back and forth rather than in one
direction—offsetting instead of reinforcing.
Externally, the organization provides in­
sulation from certain kinds of political
pressure. The 14-year terms of the Governors
are designed to protect them against short­
term swings of partisan politics. This arrange­
ment enables the Governors to give ap­
propriate weight to the long-run conse­
quences of policy decisions. Without these
long terms, Governors would be subjected to
political pressures to achieve short-run
changes in the economy, possibly at the ex­
pense of what is best for the economy over
the long haul.
In my view-, this complex organization
provides adequate insulation against political
p r e s s u r e s . H o w e v e r , some minor
modifications could be made. First, as has
been proposed by several commissions in the
past, the term of the Chairman of the Board of
Governors could be made to coincide with
that of the President of the United States. Sec­
ond, shorter terms for Governors, say ten
years, could be provided without much risk.
Third, a couple of the provisions which
Senator Proxmire has indicated he will in­
troduce in a bill to reform the Fed could be
accepted without causing any harm.3One of
these would have the Chairman's term sub­
ject to approval of the Senate. This would
enable Congress to have somewhat more
control over general monetary policy. A sec­
ond would require that consideration be
given to candidates from consumer and labor
groups when making appointments to the

2Reserve requirements set the amount of reserves that
member banks are to hold. Regulation Q places a ceiling
on all interest rates paid by member banks on time and
savings deposits. Margin requirements set the cash down
Payment required when purchasing stock on credit.
Open Market operations—the buying and selling of
securities by the Fed—affect bank reserves, interest rates,
and the growth of the money supply. The discount rate is
the interest rate which the Fed charges member commer­
cial banks that borrow from it.




3U.S., Congress, Senate, Housing and Urban Affairs
Committee, S. 22 8 5 : A B ill to A m e n d th e F e d e ra l R e s e r v e
Act to P ro v id e fo r S e n a te C o n firm a t io n o f C e rta in A p ­
p o in t m e n t s , a n d f o r O t h e r P u rp o s e s , 94th Cong., 1st sess.,
3 September 1975.
5

OCTOBER 1975

BUSINESS REVIEW

economy works best with least detailed in­
tervention. The economy does need overall
regulation in the sense that, as Walter
Bagehot4 said, money will not manage itself.
But the Fed has considered its job simply to be
one of regulating the overall supply of money
and credit and leaving it to the market to
allocate that credit. However, there are those
who believe that the market doesn't do the
job well. It allocates credit in a manner that is
incompatible with their view of social
priorities. For example, during periods of
tight money the market allocates credit in a
way that severely affects housing and small
business. Yet, many individuals rank these
sectors of the economy high on their lists of
social priorities and seek methods of
shielding them when credit is tight.
This is a matter that greatly concerns many
people and it is not going to go away. It is also
one for which I happen to have a good deal of
sympathy. Undoubtedly, one approach is to
do what we can to improve financial markets.
Ceilings on interest rates, for example, limit
the free flow of funds, often to the detriment
of “ high priority" sectors of the economy.
The Hunt Commission (President's Commis­
sion on Financial Structure and Regulation)
tried to get to the heart of this problem by its
recommendations for sweeping changes
among financial intermediaries. Improving
markets is all to the good, but it is likely to
happen slowly and with difficulty. Another
approach is for the Federal Government to in­
tervene in markets through fiscal action. In
recent years, the formation of a number of
Government mortgage agencies has been
effective in helping the housing sector. Such
actions are a more direct method of providing
funds. The problem with them is that Govern­
ment may become involved in credit markets
to a greater extent than desired.

Board of Governors. I don't believe this is
necessary since members of the Board con­
sider it their responsibility to look out for the
concerns of these groups among others.
Moreover, it would be undesirable to begin
constituting the Board with members who
view themselves as advocates of special in­
terest groups. Nevertheless, I see little harm in
giving “ due regard" to individuals from con­
sumer and labor interests in considering ap­
pointments.
I do see positive harm, however, in the
other proposals Senator Proxmire has made.
Most of all, it would be highly undesirable to
have Congress make appropriations for
Federal Reserve expenditures. This would in­
volve Congress in details of Fed policy and
operations which, as I'll indicate shortly, Con­
gress should not and cannot effectively un­
dertake. I would also oppose having ap­
pointments of Presidents of Reserve Banks
subject to Senate confirmation. On the sur­
face this appears to strengthen the hands of
the Presidents in serving on the Open Market
Committee, but it promises to politicize their
appointments, to undermine the role of the
local Board of Directors, and to open up a
number of undesirable issues with regard to
employment status and compensation. Final­
ly, the provision to provide staff assistance for
individual Governors is a detail which can be
handled best by internal administrative
arrangement.
Fed Philosophy: Free Markets versus Credit
Allocation and Fine Tuning. A second way in
which political considerations influence how
the Fed does its job is in the philosophy of
operation. Let me make another generaliza­
tion that is somewhat oversimplified but
nevertheless goes far to explain many con­
flicts: the Fed tends to emphasize the free
market; many politicians tend to emphasize
intervention in the free market and fine
tuning.
This difference is seen first of all in the
allocation of credit. In emphasizing the free
market the Fed traditionally argues that the




4This nineteenth-century English economist, political
analyst, and editor, was a practically trained theorist on
banking and financial matters. His L o m b a rd S tre e t (1873),
written to explain the necessity of keeping a greater
reserve in the hands of the Bank of England, helped for­
mulate the modern theory of central banking.
6

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Finally, this leaves us with selective credit
controls.5 This is a possibility that has always
had a great deal of appeal to me. Unfor­
tunately, there is a real question as to whether
such controls work. Representative Reuss's
proposal to place differential reserve re­
quirements on different kinds of assets, for
example, is an intriguing possibility. Our
analysis of this, however, raises practical
problems. If the Fed were to try to encourage
banks to make mortgage loans by putting a
low reserve requirement against them and
discourage banks from making business loans
by putting a high reserve requirement against
them, other lenders would more likely begin
to fill the gap left by commercial banks. If con­
trols were applied to these other lenders, the
open market could move in to close the gap.
We could find ourselves in a costly strait
jacket of credit controls.
In my view, no one has the answer to the
question of credit allocation. I'm certain only
of one thing: the Fed cannot afford to ignore
it and despite practical and philosophical
problems should continue to study all
possibilities.
In addition to those focusing on the alloca­
tion of credit, there are others who advocate
fine tuning the money supply and interest
rates. We are, of course, familiar with the
longstan din g disp ute between the
monetarists and the fiscalists with respect to
fine tuning the economy. What's not always
appreciated, however, is that both schools
nave their fine tuners.
Traditional monetarists are mostly anti-fine
tuning. They argue that if the Fed tries to vary
the rate of growth of money it will do more
narm than good. Consequently, it should
simply aim for constant growth of money
regardless of what happens to interest rates. A
new breed of monetarist—one who pores
over weekly money supply figures in great
detail—has been developing. He puts great

stress on very short-run movements in the
money supply. Financial houses, for example,
put out letters which make mountainous in­
terpretations out of molehill changes in the
money supply.
Most of us in the Fed take an eclectic view
of the money supply and interest rates. Both
are important. On finetuning, we believe that
money growth should not be constant but
know from experience that it cannot be con­
trolled precisely. At the same time, to be
honest, there is often in the Fed a tendency to
pay undue attention to small fluctuations in
interest rates. Hopefully, we're getting over
that syndrome.
I hope also we can avoid the syndrome of
fine tuning the money supply, but it isclear to
me that as attention paid to the money supply
has grown there has been a tendency to ex­
pect too much precision in controlling it. I
believe we should try to smooth out extreme
movements without yielding to the tempta­
tion of trying to eliminate all unwanted
movements in money. To do even this much
smoothing of the money supply will mean we
will have to permit more flexibility in moneymarket rates.
There are a few modifications that would be
helpful in this regard. The first has to do with
making information about monetary policy
decisions more readily available. The Fed now
announces its Open Market decision 45 days
after the fact. This departure from secrecy has
done much to dispel the belief that financial
markets would be unduly disturbed or that
large financial firms would gain an unfair ad­
vantage in money markets. In my view, the
next step is to move to a 30-day delayed an­
nouncement. If this action has no damaging
impact, the immediate announcement of
policy decisions should be considered. More
information of this nature would promote
better understanding of the Fed and its deci­
sion-making process.
The second modification has to do with im­
proving money-stock control by the Fed
Member banks have been leaving the System
primarily because they must forego earnings
on the reserves they are required to hold

’Two bills currently pending in Congress would have
y>e Fed direct some form of selective credit controls:
^•887 sponsored by Senator Richard S. Schweiker and
212 sponsored by Representative Henry S. Reuss.




7

USINESS REVIEW

OCTOBER 1975

the Executive branch is a very delicate
arrangement. Obviously, monetary policy
cannot go completely off on its own without
some coordination with the Government’s
economic organization. Much consultation
and coordination goes on—say 99.99 percent
of the time. The important thing is to preserve
a degree of independence needed for that .01
percent of the time—that rare and extreme
situation in which the Fed disagrees fun­
damentally with the President. This is the
meaning of “ independence.”
A special case in the Fed’s relationship with
the Executive branch has to do with Treasury
financing. The Federal Reserve System has a
great responsibility to see that a new issue of
the Treasury does not fail. At stake is the
credibility of the Government’s credit. There
is a danger, of course, in going too far in this
direction as we learned during and im­
mediately after World War II. At that time, the
Fed supported prices of Government
securities to the point where it had become
“ an engine of inflation.” This problem was
solved in 1951 when the Fed and the Treasury
reached an Accord by which the Fed gave up
its support of the Government securities
market. In return the Fed ever since has pur­
sued an “ even keel” policy during periods of
Treasury financing. This policy in effect
pledges the Fed to a position of neutrality
while the Treasury is raising money.
In times when the Treasury is almost con­
stantly in the market, even keel could serious­
ly erode the Fed's flexibility in changing
policy. However, in recent years, particularly
as the Treasury has evolved new methods of
financing, even keel has gradually been get­
ting more flexible. This is no longer a critical
problem in the relationship between the Fed
and the Executive.
A more difficult question currently has to
do with the Fed’s relationship with the
Legislative branch. The Federal Reserve is a
creature of Congress. Congress can take any
action it wishes with respect to the Fed, in­
cluding abolishing it. The immediate question
is how much should Congress be involved in

/hile their nonmember counterparts often
re permitted to earn interest on a portion of
heir reserves. Declining membership means
smaller portion of the nation's stock of
loney is directly influenced by the Fed. To
ive the Fed greater control over the money
upply, I support legislation that would esablish uniform reserve requirements for all
ommercial banks. An alternative that would
Iso resolve the problem is Congressional acion to permit the Fed to pay interest on
riember bank reserves. While either change
/ould not be a cure-all, it would enhance the
ed’s chances of achieving its monetary policy
oals.
In sum, it is clear to me that all this pressure
Dr fine tuning and improved credit allocation
eflects something basic in our society—the
ising standards expected of public officials. It
eflects the fact that people are not content to
/atch the market exert what they consider
dverse effects on sectors they are concerned
bout. It reflects increasing pressure for inervention in markets and demand for greater
>recision in controlling them. But it is also
lear that the state of the art is not up to these
lemands and that this conflict between rising
expectations and limitations of performance
/ill continue to be a source of political dis>ute. As the conflict continues, I believe the
ed should stand by its free-market
(hilosophy but it cannot ignore these
tressures or take an extreme laissez-faire
iew in dealing with them.
Intragovernmental Relations: A Delicate
ialance. A third way in which political coniderations are reflected in how we do our job
i in the relation to the Executive and
egislative branches of Government. The Fed
eports to Congress, not to the President. The
eason for this is the history of the abuse of
loney by the Executive. The Secretary of the
reasury was once an ex-officio member of
ie Federal Reserve Board. He was removed
ecause he has to borrow money to pay the
ills and might have a tendency to want the
Dwest possible interest rates.
Yet, the relationship between the Fed and




8

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

billions of dollars of assets are all there. As has
been pointed out many times, however, the
danger in the proposal is GAO involvement in
monetary policy. The Fed already reports all
policy actions to Congress and the concurrent
resolution further strengthens that reporting
relationship. The GAO is not well-equipped
to interpose itself between the Fed and Con­
gress on the matter of monetary policy.

the details of monetary policy. The Constitu­
tion gives Congress the power to coin money
and to regulate the value thereof. But this
leaves open the question of how much
authority it should retain and how much it
should delegate to the Fed. I believe it is clear
that Congress should retain general oversight
but should allow the Fed enough room to
make unpopular decisions in the short run
thatwill prove wise in the long run. Also, Con­
gress should not involve itself in the details of
monetary policy. For one reason, Congress
can be just as susceptible to temporary
political pressure as the President. For
another, Congress lacks the necessary exper­
tise in monetary policy formation and in its
implementation to be calling the day-to-day
or even month-to-month monetary signals.
Earlier this year both houses passed a
resolution which provided for more direct
control over monetary policy.6 This was a
proper step and promises to help focus policy
on longer-run objectives. It remains to be
seen, however, if Congress uses the tool
effectively. As the Fed and Congress proceed
to feel their way under the concurrent resolu­
tion, a great deal of cooperation and good
faith will be necessary on both sides.
A final aspect of Fed-Congressional
relationships has to do with the proposal to
have the General Accounting Office audit the
Federal Reserve System. I can speak from per­
sonal experience that the Fed is thoroughly
audited now. I can understand that in a postWatergate environment there would be a
desire to provide for the assurance that the

CONCLUSIONS
Politics is an art. Central banking is an art.
This means that there are no absolutes and
that political influences are constantly fluid.
For example, recently the emphasis on con­
sumerism has involved the Fed in Truth in
Lending, Fair Credit Billing, and Equal Oppor­
tunity in Credit. This additional responsibility
promises to involve the Fed even further in
political considerations. An irony of thisisthat
the Fed tends to get these jobs because it is
regarded as nonpolitical.
Thus, pressures toward greater political in­
volvement for the Fed are increasing.
Awareness on the part of the public of the Fed
is greater than ever. Opinions about what the
Fed should do are more pronounced than
ever. Pressures on Federal Reserve officials to
perform better are greater than ever. De­
mand for information about what they are do­
ing is stronger than ever. If there were times
when officials could sit in their marble halls
and mysteriously pull strings that affect the
economy without anyone questioning their
actions, those times are gone. We must be in­
creasingly open, responsive, and flexible. The
challenge will be to accomplish this and yet
be as firm and far-seeing as necessary to do
our job of securing a healthy economy.

6U.S., Congress, Senate, R e fe r r in g to th e C o n d u c t o f
M o n e t a r y P o lic y : R e p o r t to A c c o m p a n y H . C o n . R e s. 133,
^4th Cong., 1st sess., 17 March 1975.




9