View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

by
David P. Eastburn
President, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

before

LEADERSHIP IDEAS FOR ENVIRONMENT FORUM
at the
Treadway Inn, West Chester, Penna.
November 2, 1972 - 12:30 P.M

A few weeks ago I experienced that increasingly familiar phenomenon of the
metropolis, the blackout.

As usually happens, everyone present took it in good

humor, but in this case for a special reason:

the head of the local power company

had just left the party a few minutes earlier.

If the problem were not so serious, anyone with training in economics might
take some grim satisfaction in these events, the most tangible manifestation of
the "energy crisis".

They demonstrate that resources really are scarce, as the

economics textbook always said they were.

The sudden awareness that there are not enough energy resources to support
indefinitely the expected demands on them has come as a shock to a society only
recently beginning to believe that we can accomplish anything we set our minds to.
Not long ago, J. K. Galbraith persuaded many thoughtful and earnest people that
we had truly solved the problem of production.

As he put it:

To furnish a barren room is one thing.

To continue

to crowd in furniture until the foundation buckles is quite
another.

To have failed to solve the problem of producing

goods would have been to continue man in his oldest and most
grievous misfortune.

But to fail to see that we have solved

it and to fail to proceed thence to the next task, would be
fully as tragic.*

*J.K. Galbraith, The Affluent Society, (Houghton Mifflin Co.; Boston, 1958) pp. 355-6




Accepting this as gospel, a number of influential individuals proceeded with
great expectations to what they considered the next task —

the formation of social

programs to reduce existing "social imbalances" (poverty, deficient nutrition,
slum housing, etc.)*

More recently, as they became concerned over the shape of

the environment, they have advocated placing additional demands on the economy with
policies aimed at cleaning up the mess.

All the while, more consumers continue

to demand more cars, homes and appliances.

The tremendous expectations that grew from the seeds planted by Galbraith
began to crumble with the growing realization that the hobgoblin scarcity was alive
and well.

Even in a society of unparalleled wealth, desires for more social action

programs, higher-quality environment, and more consumer wares outstrip the economy’s
ability to meet them.

As these conflicting demands compete for resources, some must

go unfilled.

And with realization that resources are limited has come disillusionment.
Many thoughtful people have turned away from the notion that growth, science and
technology, operating within the framework of a market economy, offer the solution
to our problems.

There is, I believe, an important lesson in all this.

The lesson is, that the

economy cannot be the ultimate problem solver in the sense that it can generate
limitless consumer goods, social action programs, and improvement in the environment.
Scarcity precludes that outcome.

But it is a

prime problem solver in the sense

that it serves as an effective allocator of resources among conflicting demands.




The point of my remarks today is that by making the economy a better allocator we
can help resolve many of our problems —

including the "energy crisis".

The Non-Growth Solution
The electric power industry realized its golden age of growth from the 1920fs
to the mid 1960fs.

The demand for electricity was small relative to the resources

needed to meet it.

At the beginning, people had few of the appliances that cooked

their food and cooled their homes, not to mention those that brushed their teeth
and popped their com.

As they installed more plug-ins, the power industry had

little problem supplying the juice that drives them.

Resources for generating

electricity were plentiful and their exploitation involved only a small part of the
environment.

Clean air and fresh water were in large supply but the goods and

services electricity made possible were not; so the latter received the higher
relative value.

The first signs of trouble appeared in the late 1960fs when blackouts and
brownouts plagued several portions of the country during peak demands.
appetite for power had surpassed the expectations of planners.

America’s

New projections

indicated that the country would be consuming more than three times as much
electricity by 1990.

The industry stepped up its attempt to boost long-range

capacity.

But a change in values was also in the wind.
no longer so abundant.
rising value.

A quality environment had become an economic good of rapidly

Many of the fuels used in the past to generate electricity were

deemed to be too dirty to be used in the future.




Fresh air and clean water were

Power planners and others began to take a long, hard look at energy resources.
"Cleaner" sources like natural gas and oil have dwindling reserves.
Alaska have helped but are no match for expected future demands.

Discoveries in

Trillions of

feet of natural gas and uncounted barrels of oil may lie beneath the United States
or its waters, but these reserves are yet unproven.

Moreover, to explore, develop

and tap these sources could be an expensive proposition, requiring long lead times.
Oil imports have and will continue to provide some relief, but three-fourths of
world-wide petroleum reserves are in the Middle East and Africa, areas that are
not always on the best of terms with the United States.

Technology offers new energy sources such as oil from shale and breeder reactors
for nuclear power.
standby, coal.

It also offers new methods of cleaning up that abundant old

But developing and implementing new technology takes time and it

is the next 15-20 years that planners worry about most.

Officials in the power industry naturally talk about how to boost output to
match the future demands of a growing economy.

Some others, however, are crying

out for a halt to economic growth, and electric utilities are prime targets for this
non-growth cult.
society —
pollution.

The power industry has come close to symbolizing the consumeristic

purveyors of superfluous goods and gadgets and visible sources of
So it seems a simple solution to slow down economic growth and cut the

output of gadgets.

We could thus curtail the demand for electric power and the

consequent drain on resources and pollution of water and air.

Slowing economic growth, however, seems to me neither a viable nor warranted
solution to the "energy crisis".




Economic growth is necessary to provide the

technological equipment, methods and national income to develop new and better
sources of energy.

It is a costly and time-consuming business to develop the technology to tap
energy resources and to make them environmentally clean.

The problem is to match

supply and demand for existing neleann energy sources over the next few decades in
such a way as to insure that we have the economic strength and technical know-how
to tap new resource bases over the long haul.
this.

The non-growth approach cannot do

We will need growth to generate the estimated $500 billion to $1 trillion

in capital needed over the next few decades for developing and implementing new
techniques, and for replacing existing facilities that are heavy polluters.

Old Tools for an Old Problem
Perhaps the most troublesome issue in the non-growth approach is the forsaking
of science, technology and a proven device for dealing with scarcity —
market-oriented economy.
crisis".

our

These seem to me the tools to use in solving the "energy

Rather than discarding them we ought to look for ways to alter or repair

them so that they can continue to build the structure we want.

In the past, the market system has served us well in resolving conflicts
over scarce resources.
price.

The central force in this system, of course, is the market

It directs the flow of resources into goods and services we value most and

strikes the balance between supply and demand for the economy’s output.

Balance is not being struck in the energy sector.
is that one important set of prices is missing —




Part of the reason for this

those on environmental products.

The environment in the past has been almost a costless place to dispose of the
unwanted by-products of production and consumption.

Consequently, it is over-used

by everyone from the automobile owner to the utility executive.

Without some way

of incorporating environmental costs in the production process, the economy will
continue to produce 11too many” material goods at the expense of environmental quality.

So if we are to strike the balance between power consumption and a quality
environment, we shall have to insure that people pay the price for using the skies
and waterways as dumping grounds.

This would raise the cost of producing energy

from fuels particularly damaging to the environment.

The power industry would be

encouraged to seek less damaging fuels or to apply technology to clean up their
production process.

In either case, consumers of electricity would pay higher rates.
would tend to slow the growth in demand for power.*

These rates

They would also, for example,

make it economical to put more insulation in homes and offices, thereby reducing
energy demands for heating and air conditioning.

The same kinds of pressures would

be at work as have been observed for a long time in Europe where gasoline runs about
a dollar a gallon.

Because of this high price, cars are small and designed to

economize on gas consumption.

My point is not that we should have more insulation

or smaller cars but that our market economy is capable of inducing these kinds of
changes in demand.

* One estimate is that if the "real” price of electricity remains constant over the
next 20 years, the demand for it will triple but if the "real" price increases by
50 percent, demand will increase by only 80 percent.




Moreover, business would be encouraged through changes in relative prices
of energy sources to apply technological know-how to improve environmental quality.
Higher prices on fossil fuels, for example, would not only speed the development
of alternative sources of energy, but also speed the implementation of technology
necessary to reduce the environmental impact of the use of fossil fuel.

In short, when environmental products are priced, utility executives will
find it makes cents to alter their power production in such a way that both fuel
resources and the environment are conserved.

And as higher costs are passed on to

consumers in the form of rate increases, a point will be reached where consumers
find it makes cents to conserve on power consumption.

Role for Government
Incentives.

Government has a major role to play in resolving the pricing

aspects of the energy dilemma.

One method it can use to put dollar signs on

environmental costs is taxation.

For example, the President has already recommended

a tax on sulphur oxides emitted into the atmosphere.

The tax would provide an

economic incentive for polluters to cut back on the use of high-sulphur fuels.

It

would also provide incentive to develop and implement new methods of cleaning up
high-sulphur fuels and to seek out low-pollutant substitutes.

Government could also build in some incentives on the consumption side.
Required labelling of consumer appliances with respect to the amount of electricity
or natural gas used in their operation might encourage consumers to seek out those
brands that use less energy.




Consumers could economize on utility bills and producers

of appliances would have an incentive to lower the energy consumption of their
appliances.

While this kind of incentive may seem like small potatoes now, it

would grow in importance as higher rates for electricity peeled off more of the
consumer’s income.

Planning.

Currently the United States is without an integrated energy policy.

Energy responsibilities are divided among a number of agencies that can sometimes
work at cross purposes.
sources.

Nor is there a single agency devoted to tapping new energy

With energy sources becoming increasingly interchangeable and closer

competitors with each other, a single department (as recommended by President Nixon)
to coordinate policy seems to make good sense.

For example, the host of special incentives, quotas and pricing arrangements
within each agency may be encouraging uneconomical use of our energy resources.
A sole agency could coordinate energy production, allowing market force to play a
larger role in allocating energy resources but taking corrective action when
necessary for environmental reasons.

In addition, a single agency could sponsor

and direct technological research aimed at developing a long-term program that takes
into account all aspects of the problem, such as balance of payments deficits because
of oil and gas imports or national security considerations.

Equity.

Who is going to pay for the rising cost of electricity?

Everyone

will in one way or another.

We will pay with higher prices for products which are

heavy users of electricity.

Interest rates may rise as power companies dip into the

capital market to expand and improve facilities.




And we will pay directly in the

form of higher utility bills.

Government action may be necessary to insure that

the burden of higher prices is spread equitably.

For example, low-income families spend a larger portion of their income on
electricity than higher-income families.

Higher rates, thus, will hit them harder,

just as a sales tax on other necessities does.

To lessen this burden on the poor,

government could alter the rate structure so that those who consume relatively small
amounts of electricity pay a lower rate than those who consume larger amounts.

This

could mean that large industrial users would have to pay higher rates as opposed
to the declining block rates that many now pay.

Crisis?
A real danger —

and perhaps the real "crisis11 —

in the energy issue is that

there will be a turning away from the economy in seeking solutions.

Many will be

tempted to do this as they confront continuing environmental problems, social
disparities and the shattering reality that the economy cannot, after all, give us
everything we might like to have.

The energy problem confronting us is essentially

an economic problem and the market economy is a reliable tool for solving it.
non-growth route is not.

The

If we improve the operation of the economy rather than

forsake it, we can speed technological development, stretch energy resources, and
lead to a cleaner environment, all within the context of growth.

DPE:ll/l/72