View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

by
DAVID P. EASTBURN, PRESIDENT
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

The Robert Morris Associates
Annual President’s Night
Peale Ballroom
Holiday Inn
Philadelphia, Pa.
March 11, 1976

Bank regulators are under fire as they have not been since the
1930s.

The criticisms are sharp and the questions pointed.

wrong?

Why do we have lists of problem banks?

What went

How could we be where we

are unless supervisors fell down on the job?
The important issue is not who made what mistakes but what have
we learned from recent experience.
you tonight:

Ifd like to examine three issues with

first, how can regulators anticipate problems; second, who

should be doing the supervising; and, third, how much should the public be
told about the condition of banks?

In doing so I ’ll be making some broad

generalizations about supervisors that obviously will have many exceptions.

How to Anticipate Problems
Examiners do many things when they go into a bank— review internal
auditing, check for violation of laws and regulations, etc.

They also pay

attention to exposure on the liability side, profitability, and character­
istics of management.

But at the heart of the examination process is a

judgment about the quality of assets and how that relates to capital.
are judged to be of acceptable quality or they are classified.
are substandard and below are totaled and related to capital.

Loans

Those that
Basically,

itfs an asset-oriented, snapshot approach to whether a bank is or isnft up
to acceptable regulatory standards at a given moment.
Supervisors are now aware that the main deficiency of this kind
of approach is that it’s after-the-fact— it focuses on what a bank has done,
rather than on what it can do to avoid problems or work out existing diffi­
culties.

What is needed instead is an anticipatory bank examination and

regulatory system.




A basic ingredient in such a system is more use of economic
forecasting, analysis and judgment by examiners.
quality is tied closely to the business cycle.

For example, loan
Loan quality deteriorates

during recessions and improves during recoveries.

Anticipating movements

in the economy— while never eliminating all misjudgments— can reduce the
number of surprises.

This, of course, is difficult, as economists have

recently found to their chagrin.

But by looking ahead more, regulators

can be in better position to criticize before the fact rather than after.
They can talk to bank management about developing problems and what options
are available for avoiding them.
There is, of course, more to avoiding problems than being aware
of the business cycle.
of bankers.

Regulators also must be in tune with the thinking

In the f30s, bankers thought mostly of survival, after World

War II they concentrated on soundness.

Then in the f50s and f60s they

caught the growth bug which evolved into the profit craze known as ,fgo-goM
banking.

Bankers were not alone.

The "go-go" spirit also pervaded the

corporate merger and acquisition area, the "performance funds" of the mutual
fund industry, the real estate market and so on.

The point is that regula­

tors must look at the big picture if they are to anticipate what's ahead—
where the big picture includes movements in the economy as well as being
sensitive to the attitudes of bankers.
In response to recent experience, regulators are spending con­
siderable resources to construct surveillance systems that will help them
monitor the impact of economic and financial developments on banks.

Banks

that are generating early warning signals can be scrutinized more closely.




In this kind of anticipatory examination process, regulators
can better judge the ability of bank management to cope with problems.
The primary test of management should no longer be the magnitude of classi­
fied assets to capital per se, but rather what policies management adopts
and carries out to avoid future problems or get out of current ones.
Regulators would then be in better position to lean against the wind of
collective excesses in the banking industry, or— perhaps a more immediate
danger right now— collective timidity.
So much for anticipating problems.

Let me now turn to who should

do the regulating.

Who Should do the Regulating
My guess is that, although sentiment for reform appears on the
upswing, the odds are still against reform of the regulatory structure this
year.

I say this quite aside from the merits of reform but because there

are so many opposed to change for various reasons of their own.
One of the lessons of recent experience suggests strongly keeping
at least one of the aspects of the present structure.
link between bank supervision and monetary policy.

That is, keeping some

Basically, monetary policy

works through altering the liquidity positions of banks.

When we ease mon­

etary policy, we increase bank liquidity and when we tighten monetary policy,
bank liquidity is reduced.

Supervisors also look at bank liquidity.

Coordin­

ation between supervision and monetary policy is helpful so that the thrust
of monetary policy can be reinforced by liquidity standards of supervisors.




Bank capital standards set by supervisors also should mesh with
monetary policy if national economic goals are to be achieved.

Now, for

example, in the aftermath of several years of rapid credit expansion, the
capital position of many banks could use some strengthening.

Yet, the need

for more bank capital should not be so overwhelming as to impede banks in
financing the economic recovery.
Finally, there is a tendency for central bankers to become too
ivory towerish.

Being involved in the examination process helps us keep

our feet on the ground by having first hand exposure to what is going on
inside banks.
Although I believe there is much merit in keeping the Fed in the
examination business, I would be reluctant to see the entire regulatory
authority vested in the Federal Reserve.

The thought of combining so much

power— regulatory and monetary— in one agency gives me considerable pause.
Where I come out is that what we have is not ideal and not what
we would devise if we were starting from scratch.

But given the practical

obstacles to change, plus the desirability of maintaining a link between
supervision and monetary policy, I shy away from changing the basic structure.
A more productive route is to make changes within the existing framework
along the lines of making supervisors more anticipatory and improving
coordination among the supervisors.

How Much Should the Public be Told?
A final question is how much should the public be told about the
condition of banks?




The traditional position is that the public should be

told very little.

The rationale is that banking plays such a pivotal role

that any public misunderstanding about released information could shake
public confidence in the banking system and hence the whole economy.
Besides, the argument continues, the advantages of close public scrutiny
are more or less achieved through close supervision.
However convincing this argument once was, it has a hollow ring
in a post-Watergate world in which leaks about problem banks have been
taken rather calmly by the public.

Let me make clear, I am against the

pilfering of examination reports and related materials and I am against the
subpoening of examination reports in their present form by Congressional
Committees.

However, I do favor increased public disclosure of the con­

dition of banks.

What’s disclosed, how, and when deserves careful study,

but the general proposition that more disclosure would be in the public
interest makes sense to me.
The reason is that although banking is a heavily regulated industry,
the marketplace can also be a most effective regulator.

It can provide a

strong incentive to do well and can be a harsh critic for doing poorly.
But the marketplace can function only if investors, depositors, and customers
have adequate information about the condition of banks.

Rather than seeing

the growing demand for more disclosure by banks as disruptive, therefore,
I see it— if properly directed— as a positive step toward building increased
understanding and confidence in our financial system.

Summary
Let me sum up.

Building confidence in our banking system is essen­

tial to healthy economic growth and prolonged prosperity.




W e ’ve learned some

lessons in recent years.

The first is that we need a forward-looking,

anticipatory examination process— one that judges the quality of banks
more by the way they are responding to ongoing and prospective develop­
ments rather than a static look at a set of ratios.

The second is that,

as a practical matter, more progress can probably be made now toward
strengthening the examination process within the existing supervisory
structure than trying to modify it, given the obstacles to reform.
more public disclosure of banking conditions— if done prudently—

Finally,
can be

in the public interest by allowing the marketplace to do a better job.
Building confidence takes time, maybe a long time, but the time to start
is now and the people to start are you, the banker, and we, the regulators.