View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

THE U.S. ECONOMY AND WORLD MONETARY SITUATION
Remarks by
Darryl R. Francis, President
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
Before
Farm and Industrial Equipment Institute
at the
Regency Hyatt House
Atlanta, Georgia
October 10, 1973

It is good to have this opportunity to discuss with you
some of my views on the outlook for the United States economy in
the near future. It happens that We stand presently in one of
those rare situations in which there is a wide divergence of forecasts with regard to almost all areas of economic interest. Moreover, economic issues, for various reasons, have become more
newsworthy and of greater interest to the average citizen in recent
times.
Let me first summarize briefly the current economic
situation and then address myself to three broad questions:




1) When will inflation end?
2) Will there be a recession?
3) What is the outlook for the international
monetary situation?

2
I must tell you now that I will advance neither specific
numerical forecasts nor quick and easy solutions to our existing
economic problems. The adoption of specific and usually optimistic
targets, and the employment of quick, politically expedient solutions
in an attempt to achieve them, have, in my opinion, contributed
much to our current economic difficulties.
Let us now focus attention for a few minutes on the current economic situation. The present time is relatively prosperous,
and therefore should be an enjoyable one for most people — not
only with regard to economic well being, but in other important
respects. The unemployment rate is lower than it has been in
several years, corporate profits after taxes are almost double their
1970 low point, per capita disposable personal income has never been
greater, and even lost output due to labor strikes was at a nine-year
low in the first half of 1973. Also, this country's participation in
the bitterly divisive Vietnam conflict has ended, no more young people
are being drafted, and social unrest has declined significantly.
However, a number of factors suggest we are not enjoying
our prosperity to the degree one might expect. The stock market,
often taken to reflect the public's mood, has been depressed throughout most of 1973. A new measure of welfare has been advocated by
Professor Paul Samuelson which is obtained in part by eliminating
ostensibly undesirable goods, such as pollution and military expenditures, from total output. This index has been growing progressively



3
slower relative to gross national product in recent years, indicating
our happiness has not kept pace with our GNP.
The index of consumer sentiment, which is compiled on
the basis of answers to questions such as "will you be better off
financially a year from now" and "will the country have good times
or bad over the next five years/ 1 was about as low in the second
quarter of 1973 as in the depths of the 1970 recession, and lower
than at any point in the period from 1957 to 1969.
Now, I have no great confidence in any of these kinds of
indexes, singly or even en masse, because attitudes and welfare are
so difficult to measure. But I do happen to agree that there currently exist serious economic and noneconomic problems which are
contributing to a widespread feeling of malaise, or general unhappiness.
I trace much of this atmosphere to the failure of policymakers to inform the public of the hard choices which must be made
in a world where resources are limited and desires are not. It is my
belief that by fostering the impression that there are no problems
which cannot be cured by government action, policymakers have unnecessarily elevated the public's expectations and then dashed their
hopes when confronted with economic reality. Let me give you some
examples.
In the mid-1960's, the Federal Government greatly
exoanded both its domestic outlays, primarily for the Great Society



4
Programs, and its foreign involvement, mainly in the form of
defense expenditures for the Vietnam conflict. After several years
and numerous glowing reports on both projects, it appears to me
that the main effect on the domestic economy of the expenditure of
many billions of dollars has been severe inflationary pressures.
The attempt to maintain both a "guns and butter" economy has
satisfied few and disappointed many.
Just a few years ago, cleaning up the environment became a major objective of public policy, with little thought as to the
effects of single-minded pursuit of such an admirable goal on our
energy reserves. Now that we have found that our energy resources
are more limited than we thought, environmental concerns are
battling crash energy programs for newspaper headlines. Thus, it
is my contention that the public has discovered the hard choices to
be made only after having been allowed to believe the environmental
objective could be attained with minor costs over a relatively short
span of time.
Some time ago, the public was told that the adoption of
wage and price controls was a temporary expedient to relieve inflationary pressures in a less than fully employed economy. The controls were to be removed before shortages and economic uncertainty,
two byproducts of price controls in a high employment economy,
would appear. The "temporary" controls are now into their fourth
phase. In the current high employment economy, shortages and



5
economic uncertainty have emerged along with the inflationary
pressures that the controls were adopted to alleviate.
There are many other cases in which the well meaning
efforts of policymakers to achieve objectives in one area have caused
undesirable side effects in another. State usury laws, intended to
prohibit the financial exploitation of small borrowers, have deorived
such borrowers of virtually any access to credit in tight money
periods. Minimum wage laws were adopted to insure a minimum
level of income to everyone. However, many studies indicate that
the main effect has been higher wages for workers already holding
comfortable jobs and unemployment for many of the low-income
workers the law was supposed to benefit. Government inducements
to foreigners to buy our products and thereby improve our balanceof-payments position were recently reversed in order to stem complaints about foreigners buying up our scarce goods.
Attempts by the monetary authorities to moderate the
tendency of interest rates to rise in the face of strong credit demand
have resulted in sharp increases in the money stock and, subsequently,
intensified inflationary pressures and even higher interest rates. The
extended freeze on beef prices was, of course, not designed to dry up
beef supplies or stimulate cattle rustling, but that was its effect. The
current restrictions on domestic fertilizer prices at levels considerably
below world market prices, if not relieved, could result in the marketing by U. S. farmers of smaller crops in the near future than would



6
otherwise have been the case, despite the release of more land for
crop production.
The list of well-intentioned efforts in pursuit of worthy
social and economic objectives has become very long. The fact that
many of our current problems are directly attributable to such
efforts has not discouraged the majority of policymakers from trying.
Anyone with a knowledge of a few economic principles relating to
basic supply and demand forces could have predicted the adverse
side effects which followed many of the earlier policy actions.
Unfortunately, predicting the policy actions themselves
is much more difficult. The increased size of government, and
steoped-up governmental intervention in market forces, has made
it more necessary than ever before to recognize the influence of
government actions on economic projections. What will happen in
the remainder of 1973 has been largely determined by earlier policy
actions, but much of economic developments in 1974 and beyond
depend on policy actions yet to occur. Let me now turn to the outlook.
First, when will inflation end? Recent polls have shown
that the issue which Americans are most concerned about today is
inflation. The fact that the current inflation has persisted longer
than any in the Post-World War 11 period may partially explain the
current malaise. The public is quite cognizant that rising prices are
eroding their incomes, their savings, and has depreciated the value
of the dollar internationally.



It is not surprising that they are worried

7
about what inflation will do to their futures. It is an issue that
directly strikes every citizen, unlike war, unemployment, or even
Watergate.
It is rather disconcerting to learn from the polls that
the average citizen has little or no idea of the cause (and by implication - the cure) of inflation. Large corporations, unions, or
some sinister "middlemen" are typically blamed. Rarely are fiscal
or monetary actions thought to be the basic cause of inflation.
The common sense answer to the inflation question,
which one hears surprisingly few times outside economic circles,
is "too much money chasing too few goods." The volume of goods
and services produced over a long period depends mostly on the size
of the population that is of working force age, their degree of education, the extent of technological development, and the quantity and
quality of raw resources and capital. The quantity of money produced
which chases the goods is determined primarily by the monetary
authorities, and the quantity could be closely controlled.
Thus, technically, it is not a difficult matter to eliminate
inflation by reducing the rate of growth in the volume of money that
is chasing the goods and services. Unfortunately, historical evidence indicates that the initial consequence of a marked and sustained
reduction in the rate of growth of the money supply has been a
temporary slowing in the rate of growth of real output and a rise
in the unemployment rate. A lessening of price pressures normally



has not occurred for an extended period after adoption of the restrictive policy. This is because the public, after repeated bouts
with inflation, simply has not believed that policymakers would stick
with the restrictive action long enough to make it work.
Public opinion and attitudes are important not only with
regard to determining the length of time it takes to get inflation
under control, but they also influence the tools employed in the
battle. Even after price rises had begun to slow in 1970 and 1971 as
a result of the restrictive stabilization policies undertaken in 1969,
progress was not fast enough to satisfy the public nor their elected
representatives. Polls taken in mid-1971 indicated that more than
half the people thought direct controls should be used to slow the
inflationary spiral. Controls appeared to be a costless way of curbing price rises by getting at the "sinister" middleman, with no ill
effects to befall law-abiding citizens and firms. Controls had the
appearance of working for a while when there was little excess demand
in the country. Once the economy approached full capacity utilization,
as it did over the past year, it became clear that controls not only could
not stop inflation, but could cause serious shortages, black markets,
and confusion.
Now, after controls have been tried, and despite the
problems of floods, bad weather and poor Russian and Chinese harvests,
the basic, underlying cause of inflation remains — too much money
chasing too few goods. In f a j r ^ ^ ^ b e e n the problem world-wide,



I

IE3D/V

BX/

9
as money supplies throughout the world have pushed up local prices.
Money supply growth in England, Japan, Germany, France,
and Canada, to name a few countries, has virtually exploded during
the past two or three years. In the United States, money supply
growth moved up from about a 2 or 3 percent rate in the 1950's and
early 1960's, to a 6 percent average rate over the past five years. The
result has been inflation, high interest rates and dollar devaluation.
The cure for inflation has not changed despite the freezing, semi-freezing and unfreezing of prices. The reversal of stimulative monetary and fiscal actions is a prerequisite to the reduction of
inflationary pressures. Because of the lag of price changes behind
changes in the rate of growth of the money stock, it probably would
be not only months, but years before the adoption of moderate policy
actions would have any lasting, observable, effect on the inflation
rate. A severely restrictive policy could accomplish the job faster,
but the cost in terms of lower employment and output would be more
than most of us are prepared to pay.
And I hasten to add that the use of pervasive wage-price
controls in the current high employment economy would not serve
to speed up the end of inflation. At best, controls have only some
minor, distorting effect on the timing of individual Drice changes,
but no lasting effect on the general inflation rate. Experience both
here and abroad has shown that adoption of a price freeze under the
current circumstances only delays the rise in prices. You can't



10
stop inflation by passing a law against it any more than you can stop
unemployment by passing a law against that.
Since it is my view that there is no easy, costless way to
end inflation through controls, it appears to me that moderate
stabilization actions which avoid the stop-go excesses of the past
would be appropriate. Even this course of action could not be done
now without some cost in terms of a transitional slowing in the rate
of growth of output and probably a temporary rise in the unemployment rate.
The second question regarding the outlook is: Will there
be a recession? At present, there is no indication that a full-fledged
recession is unavoidable. Real GNP did slow to a 2.4 percent rate of
increase in the second quarter of 1973, from an 8 percent increase
in the preceding year. However, the third quarter data are expected
to show a rise in real product closer to its long-run potential rate of
about 4 percent annually.
Despite a slight rise in the unemployment rate from 4.7
percent in July to 4.8 percent in August and September, there remains strong pressure on the productive capacity of the economy.
The Federal Reserve's index of capacity utilization of major materials,
the volume of help wanted ads, order backlogs and the continued
high level of retail sales all suggest substantial strength in the
economy.




11
There is evidence that monetary actions have been of a
more restrictive nature during the past three months as compared
to the past couple of years. In my view the more restrictive nature
of monetary actions is reflected in the recent slowing in the growth
rate of the monetary base and the money stock. If the approximately
zero growth of the money stock from June to September were maintained for three or four quarters, our studies indicate that a
recession would almost certainly occur.
I believe there is still a path available for making some
progress toward the reduction in the average rate of inflation while
avoiding a recession. Such a path would involve a modest deceleration
in the rate of increase in the narrowly defined money stock for the
last half of 1973, followed by a further moderate deceleration in the first
half of next year. Our studies suggest that such a course of persistent,
moderate restraint on the rate of monetary expansion would foster less
inflationary pressure in 1974 than we have had this year, while not
being so restrictive as to plunge us into a sharp economic slowdown.
The third question regarding the outlook is.- What about
the international economic situation? In this area we have also looked
for painless solutions, which so far have escaped us. With the fixed
international value of the dollar from 1944 to 1971 it was quite generally
believed that the best of all possible worlds had been created. The
risks of exchange rate movements were virtually eliminated, the dollar
became the international currency, excesses of exports and imports



12
were to be prevented through voluntary domestic adjustments or
through internationally agreeable changes in the exchange rate.
Early in the post-war period, the United States supplied
dollars to the world through the Marshall Plan and various grant
arrangements, thus transferring resources to the war-ravaged parts
of the world. This provided us with an export balance and pacified
those who were worried about the balance of payments. Later, it
provided dollars for international transactions, thus transferring
resources back to the United States and providing export surpluses
for other industrial nations.
But as other nations built up their industrial potential
and began to compete and assert their sovereignty, economic and
political realities began to emerge. The maintenance of the fixed
dollar exchange rate in the face of improving foreign productivity
and sharply accelerating U. S. inflation generated an overvalued
dollar.
The result was an excess of U. S. imports in the liquidity
account with a hundred billion dollar accumulation of liquid assets
by foreigners. There was also a realization that this accumulation
of dollars meant a transfer of real resources from foreigners to the
United States. Finally, there was the realization that the fixed international value of the dollar could no longer be maintained.
The floating exchange rate system, which emerged from
the so-called crisis of 1971, seems to be working reasonably well,



13
even though it is frequently interfered with my governmental
agencies. U. S. import balance is virtually eliminated, global
trade is again 9 owing at pre-float rates, surplus countries can
deal better with inflation and all countries can pursue independent
domestic economic policies.
But apparently everyone is not satisfied with this arrangement. The transition has not been without cost: our imports have
become more expensive, those who desire a permanent export belance
cannot have it, and those who have a love affair with gold see it
relegated simply to the status of any other commodity.
There are some who still believe that some governmental
or international action can produce an arrangement quite similar to
that which prevailed prior to mid-1971, and that such an arrangement
will improve on the present situation. The recent meetings in Nairobi
are a case in point. The participants of these meetings were groping
for a more fixed exchange rate mechanism and yet realize that the
old fixed rate system is unworkable. The basic argument that emerges
is — how fixed should the rate be? The United States is arguing for
an arrangement where the fixed rate must change when a country
accumulates a certain amount of international reserves. Some other
countries argue that a change should not take place automatically,
but only after consultation and aqreement.
The U. S. position is quite similar to the floating
rate mechanism, and the other position is almost identical



14
to the old fixed rate arrangement. Again, some people have not
learned the lessons of the past and, again, think that they can have
all the benefits without having to pay the or ice.
If some fixity of exchange rates is at all desirable, then
I would support the reported position of the U. S. Treasury. I would
be willing to lay odds that an international payments mechanism with
a non-automatic change in the exchange rate would breakdown and
bring about crises for which we would all have to pay.
Now, let me close my remarks with a few summary observations. The unhappiness of many people today would be greatly
ameliorated if they thought inflation would be ended tomorrow.

It

simply cannot be done, given the stimulative fiscal and monetary
actions of the past few years. Attempts to curb inflation quickly
through controls have resulted in shortages, a reduction in economic freedom, and added uncertainty to everyone's life. Efforts
by monetary and fiscal authorities to quickly end inflation would
likely precipitate a credit crunch and a severe recession.
Adoption now of moderate stabilization actions would
eventaully reduce inflationary pressures without a credit crunch or
recession, but it would take considerable time, patience and a minimum of legal interference in our market economy. Unfortunately,
our past record on patience and avoiding the excesses of either
stimulus or restraint is not one which inspires confidence.




15
Further, we seem to be developing a growing infatuation
with the exercise of power to impede the operation of free markets
by constantly surfacing new ideas and programs for controls which
usually have ended up accomplishing exactly the opposite of what
they were proposed to do. I am fully aware that there must be come
minimum rules and regulations in a market-oriented democratic
society, but why can't we keep our hands off the functioning of the
markets and permit them to continue their proven, traditional role
in the most efficient and equitable distribution of the product of our
labors?