View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

SECURITY- AT WHAT PRICE?
Remarks by
Darryl R. Francis, President
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
Before the
Faculty and Students
of
Southern Illinois University
Carbondale, Illinois
January 30, 1976

A speech in this bicentennial year of our independence is
usually devoted to recounting our achievements of the past. And,
indeed, there is very much to be proud of. We have evolved a political
system which allows unprecedented freedom and we have developed
an economic system which has provided us with a standard of living
matched by few other countries in the world. (Chart I) Unfortunately
the achievements of the past are not necessarily indicative of achievements
in the future. Our activities in the past thirty years plant seeds of doubt
as to the maintenance of our continued economic expansion and the
maintenance of individual freedom. As one who is interested in economic
and financial progress, I see changes in institutional behavior which
may become the cause of radical curtailment of this progress.
Recently we have been told that the old laws of economics are
no longer valid, that we cannot expect the economy to function as it has




-2in the past, that policy actions cannot produce the same results, and
radical new approaches must be adopted to deal with our problems.
Since the so-called laws of economics are simply a description of human
behavior within some institutional structure, we should expect any
changes to manifest themselves either in some difference in people's
behavior or in the institutions which set limits to their responses.
There seems to be no evidence whatsoever that people react differently
to given economic stimuli, but one can observe radical changes in the
character of our economic and political institutions. And perhaps the most
outstanding is the persistent expansion of the Government sector and the
composition of Government spending.
I will not be so presumptuous as to debate philosophical issues
surrounding the size of the Government, but I believe that the consequences
of the financing of the continuously growing Governmental activity are
misunderstood. That the Government has grown and that the composition
of its spending has changed can be easily seen in Chart I I , I I I and Table I.
The major causes of Government growth are readily identifiable
and are related to our quest for even greater security. I cannot pass
judgement whether this quest is justified — that is a matter for the political
process to decide. But I can point out that this quest has also involved a
method of financing of Government expenditures which, in my opinion,
is inconsistent with the goals themselves and with the survival of our
economic and political institutions.




-3The existence of a Government implies that society has
decided that security can be obtained better by using collective means.
Security must be interpreted broadly and includes such things as
national security and security of individual rights, including property
rights. There is virtually no question that Governmental guarantees
of these are desired and that the society is willing to pay for them.
In the past thirty years, however, we have added to the list
of our various demands the desire for security of income. This again
has taken many diverse forms. Income security consists of such
various goals as the avoidance of economic fluctuations, guaranteeing
a minimum income, providing higher income opportunities through free
education and training, and avoiding the loss of income through health
and social insurance. That this has been the trend in our Governmental
activity can be seen in Table I. What is not clear, however, is whether
the society is willing to pay for these services, or, indeed, that it has
been given the opportunity to make that judgement.
One can see clearly that Governmental spending which is
designed to maintain or redistribute income has been growing rapidly
since World War I I , particularly since the early 1960's. While these
programs have apparently been approved by the majority of our society,
it is my contention that we have not been adequately informed as to the
costs of these programs and have not explicitly approved their financial
support. And it is this lack of explicit approval that generates problems




-4to which I would like to address myself.
Let us now consider the process by which security can be financed.
Any one of us can acquire security by two processes and by these two processes alone: we can save and use resources at a time of need, or we can
buy insurance. Provision of security means that some resources have to
be withdrawn from consumption stream and saved until such time that
security payments have to be made. By saving, an individual denies himself consumption at the present time in order to be able to consume when
income declines or disappears. When we buy insurance, we give up
current consumption in order to pay premiums and we receive resources
in the form of insurance payments when the need arises. To provide
security resources must be withdrawn from the consumption stream to
be available for future payments. This is true of all societies at all times.
When we choose the Government as a medium in providing such
insurance, the process described above must take place. In order to make
insurance payments, the Government must be able to provide resources
for those who receive them. This can be done, as in private cases, by
the Government acquiring and saving resources and disbursing them at
some future time. Or through current redistribution of resources to those
whose income has been guaranteed from the rest of the society.
One way to perform such transfer of resources is to tax some
individuals and pay others. When Government expenditures are financed
through an increase in taxes, the cost is readily visible and readily felt
by all of the taxpayers in the society. The political process then guarantees
that the services demanded are willingly paid for and that there are no



-5unforeseen economic repercussions.
Another way

for the Government to increase spending is to

incur a deficit financed by the sale of Government securities to private
individuals. Resources are then currently transferred from bond buyers
to those who receive Government payments. Lenders willingly give up
current consumption to get greater wealth in the future; the fact that
the goods they are sacrificing are being redistributed by the Government
does not concern them. And society as a whole realizes, or should
realize, that the debt will ultimately be repaid through higher taxes. It
should also recognize that the way in which the private sector is persuaded
to give up control of more resources to the public sector is through the
higher interest rates which increased Government borrowing entails.
This method may not have the prior approval of the electorate, but if
objections to higher interest rates are not expressed through the political
process, it implies at least a tacit approval.
If, on the other hand, demands for security persist and are not
accompanied by a willingness to make immediate payment in the form of
higher taxes or higher interest rates, there is a third method of financing
which produces repercussions that extend beyond the readily identifiable
costs. What is worse, it enables our elected representatives to produce the
illusion that such security can be obtained at no cost at all.
Again, the sale of Government securities to the private sector
will cause interest rates to rise. If at the same time there are pressures




-6to maintain low interest rates (as an instrument of assuring the income
security of, say, suppliers and buyers of housing), the central bank
must buy the bonds from the private sector. Such a purchase will reduce
interest rates from what they would have been otherwise in the short run
but will increase, dollar for dollar, the actual and potential reserves of
the banking system. The banks, given excess reserves, will increase
their loans and investments and thus will increase the money stock.
Thus, in effect, additional Government expenditures have been
financed through the creation of money. The Government enters the
market with its acquired funds and purchases resources that are then
transferred to its selected recipients. But, still, the donors in the society
must be induced to give up those resources, and the inducement comes,
with about a two year lag, by way of an increase in the price level which
makes their money worth less in real terms than they had anticipated. A
continuation of this method of financing produces inflation. Some of the
evidence can be observed in Chart IV.
The upshot of this discussion is that, irrespective of the method
of financing, Government services can be provided only by a transfer of
resources. But the currently favored method of this transfer — financing
through creation of money — temporarily masks the costs involved. This
induces a demand for and approval of additional Government services which
might very well not be forthcoming if those costs were made clear and
explicit.




-7It may be argued, but only by those with a basic contempt
for the public, that so long as payment is made ultimately, there is no
harm in a bit of deception when the services provided meet with society's
approval. This is precisely where the damage is done. Inflation produces
long term consequences which are significantly more serious than the
costs of either a current increase in taxes or in interest rates. And any
choice based on incomplete information is not likely to reflect the real
wishes of the society.
In the first place, inflation, given a structure of progressive
income taxes, increases Government revenue without an explicit increase
in the tax rate. It provides the means of extracting from taxpayers a
larger proportion of their income without their agreement. (Chart V).
Secondly, the expected rate of inflation is a primary determinant of long
term interest rates; when the belief that accelerated inflation will continue
becomes widespread, interest rates will rise. Third, unanticipated inflation
redistributes wealth from monetary creditors to debtors. This occurs as
creditors receive payment in reduced purchasing power and debtors repay
in decreased real value. One can see that this wealth redistribution is
arbitrary and totally unrelated to rewards for productivity, and thus undermines the incentive for productive efficiency.
Fourth, greater uncertainty as to the future course of the price
level reduces willingness to enter into long term contracts with the consequent
discouragement of long term investment. This is illustrated in Table I I .




-8Shorter debt maturities increase the risks for long term investors and
reduce investment in long term projects. The recently debated so-called
capital shortage may well be a result of greater inflationary uncertainty.
Fifth, inflation increases the costs of holding and using money by
reducing the purchasing power of money stocks. Money is a productive
resource which facilitates transactions. A decrease in its use necessarily
means that we move closer to barter. And I don't have to tell you what
this does to the standard of living. We have excellent examples of this
process in the German experiences after World Wars I and II and more
recently in several South American countries.
Finally, in this country inflations have typically not been tolerated
for long without periodic efforts being made to stop them by reducing the
rate of growth of money. In every case where these reductions have been
sharp, a recession has developed, involving highly undesirable human
suffering and loss of output.
What all of this amounts to is that our attempts at ever greater
security, which have not been matched by our explicit willingness to pay
for it, have of necessity resulted in payment which has brought with it
additional economic malalocations. These disturbances have had long
lasting and sometimes irreversible effects.
Now let us see whether we have derived any significant benefits
from our pursuit of additional security. Have we reduced income fluctuations?
We have had an accelerating inflation and six recessions in the past 28 years.




-9This is no less frequent an occurrence of fluctuations than we have
experienced before the Government undertook its diverse activities aimed
at greater income security.
Have we, through all of our income transfer policies equalized
the distribution of income? Table I I I indicates that such reallocation has
been virtually insignificant.
Where do we stand then? It seems that many of our desires for
income security have not materialized. But the repercussions of the
financing of these Government expenditures have created grave problems.
How long would we tolerate an inevitable decline in the growth of the
standard of living? How long are we going to tolerate an arbitrary
redistribution of income? How long are we going to tolerate recurring
recessions? Is not our individual freedom even now being threatened
as the blame for these phenomena is placed everywhere but where it
should be?
And interesting enough, these problems are not caused
fundamentally by our demands for additional security, nor by the level
of Government activity, but simply by a method of financing which has
fooled the electorate into choosing those services and has produced
inflation with all the ensuing deterioration of our economic and political
system. Are we going to give up 200 years of hard work for an illusion
of getting something for nothing?