View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

THE ROAD TO ACCELERATING INFLATION
IS PAVED WITH GOOD INTENTIONS

Lecture delivered by
Darryl R. Francis, President
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

to

School of Banking of the South
Louisiana State University
Baton Rouge, Louisiana
June 1, 1971

It is good to be here this evening, and it is an exciting
experience for me to deliver the "First Annual Monetary Policy
Lecture" to the School of Banking of the South. I have felt for a
long time that people engaged in banking should become more familiar
with the influence of monetary policy actions on the economy.
Increased public awareness of the ways policy decisions are made,
and the ways stabilization actions work, may help to move us towards
better policies in the future. I wish you a long and successful
lecture series.
As we approach the mid-point of 1971, I wish I could say
to you that it is my belief that the battle against inflation is nearing
successful completion and that we can now turn our primary
attention to moving the economy quickly back towards its noninflationary, high-employment growth potential. Unfortunately,
this is not the case. 1 must report that I am just as concerned now
about the long-run inflationary trend of the U. S. economy as I was
last year and the year before.
Tonight I will trace the economic developments from the
mid-1960's to the present which, in my opinion, created the present
inflationary environment and cause me great concern regarding the




-2prospects for achieving price stability in the near future.
It is important to make clear at the outset that I do not
believe that anyone desires a continuation of the inflationary trend
in this country. However, I do believe that there is a danger of
focusing too much attention on other immediate objectives, and that
the consequences of resulting actions could lead to a reacceleration
of the rate of inflation, contrary to our desires. I will elaborate
more fully on this view after looking back to the events which led
to our present situation.
Approach to Analysis
Throughout my remarks ! will be drawing heavily on research
of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. In recent years our
economists have been exploring new approaches to empirical measurement of the response of total spending, real product, prices, the
unemployment rate, and market interest rates to various monetary
and fiscal actions. This research has shown that changes in the
nation's money stock — that is, demand deposits at commercial banks
and currency in the hands of the public — provide a reliable indicator
of the influence of monetary policy actions on total spending in the
economy.




-3-

Furthermore, evidence has been provided and become widely
accepted that the levels of, or changes in, market interest rates do
not give a reliable indication of the "tightness" or "ease" of stabilization
policy actions. On the contrary, it has been shown that market interest
rates are significantly influenced by the past rate of inflation and
people's expectations with regard to the future rate of inflation.
Finally, the on-going work by our research staff is attempting
to quantify the immediate and delayed responses of real product and
prices to a pronounced change in the rate of increase of total spending.
We have been able to make fairly reliable predictions of the rate at
which total spending will accelerate or decelerate in response to
substantial accelerations or decelerations in the growth of the money
stock. There is less certainty, however, about the breakdown of the
changes in total spending into the real product and price component
parts. The range of estimates on this breakdown is especially large
at a time when there appears to be substantial slack in the economy,
in the form of unused plant and equipment capacity and relatively
high unemployment, while there continues to be a fairly high
rate of inflation as a result of previous excesses. I believe
that a careful study of events from the mid-1960's to the present sheds
considerable light on the risks that would be incurred by underestimating
the speed at which substantial inflationary pressures would be rekindled




-4-

if prolonged monetary stimulus resulted from efforts to achieve
other short-term objectives.
Background to the Current Situation
I turn now to consideration of past developments which seem
to provide clues to assessing our future course. In this review I will
emphasize the fact that avoidance of increased inflationary pressures
was at all times a fundamental desire of stabilization authorities.
For the most part, however, the actions actually taken were with a
view to achieving other near-term objectives. It is my opinion that
this succession of actions taken to deal with goals other than achieving
price stability has added up to an unintentional long-run acceleration
in the rate of inflation.
The review begins with 1964, the last year of a six year period
of relative price stability. Growth of both total spending and real product
strengthened throughout that year as a result of the continuing monetary
stimulus initiated in 1963 and the tax-cut of March 1964. The published
record of Federal Reserve policy actions shows that for the first eight
months of 1964 policy was conducted with a view to maintaining prevailing conditions in the money markets. In the final four months,
System actions were directed to move towards slightly firmer conditions
in the money markets. However, the rate of growth in total spending
was increasing and the public was demanding a growing amount of




-5credit to finance increased spending. Consequently, System holdings
of Government securities rose fairly rapidly as the tendency for market
interest rates to rise was resisted by open market purchases of securities.
The result was progressively more rapid rates of growth in the nation's
money stock. On balance for 1964, money rose 4.5 per cent, over twice
as fast as the average growth rate during the previous decade.
As a direct consequence of the growing monetary stimulus in
1964, 1965 became the first of many years of mounting inflationary
pressures. Reflecting back on 1965, I find it to be a year of great
paradox. At each of the sixteen meetings of the Federal Open Market
Committee in that year, the ultimate policy objective was to avoid
emergence of inflationary pressures, yet monetary actions were more
stimulative than at any time since the Korean War. Throughout the
year the operating instructions for policy were to maintain the same
or slightly firmer conditions in the money markets. In view of the
increasing demands for credit, this meant, in effect, that open
market operations were to be conducted so as to keep interest rates
from rising significantly. Yet interest rates did rise a significant
amount in 1965, in spite of record purchases of securities in the
open market by the Federal Reserve.




-6-

This is where the paradox comes in. Restrictive policy was
desired in order to combat inflation and many observers contended
that the rising interest rates were an indication that restraint was
achieved. But I think a closer look indicates that the rising interest
rates were not at all restrictive, while the actions to resist the upward
trend of interest rates were very stimulative.
During ten of the sixteen policy periods in 1965, open market
transactions were directed to take account of the U. S. Treasury
financing activity. As I see it, the problem was that the public demand
for credit to finance an accelerating rate of total expenditures was
growing very rapidly, and at the same time the Government was
incurring very large deficits as expenditures rose rapidly to finance
the Vietnam War build-up along with mounting non-defense outlays.
Since Federal Reserve policy actions were conducted with an immediateobjective of maintaining stable or only slightly rising interest rates,
System actions provided increased bank reserves at a very rapid rate.
This, in turn, resulted in "a record expansion of bank credit and
deposits" to finance the faster rate of spending of the public and
government.
Early in 1966 policy objectives shifted to "moderating the
growth in the reserve base, bank credit, and the money supply" in




-7-

order to resist inflationary pressures. However, through April of
1966 policy actions were constrained by continued Treasury financing.
As a result, the money stock rose at a very rapid 6 per cent rate from
May 1965 to April 1966.
Here I must emphasize that the 6 per cent rate of money
growth in 1965 and early 1966 was sufficiently rapid to stimulate
substantial inflationary pressure, even though real product was
growing very rapidly as prior unused capacity declined. The rate
of price advance as measured by the GNP deflator moved up from
about 1-1/2 per cent in early 1965 to over 3-1/2 per cent by mid-1966.
The acceleration of consumer price increases was even greater.
The last nine months of 1966 marked a period of effective
restrictive action to combat inflation. The growth of the money
stock dropped to zero as interest rates were allowed to rise in response
to market demand. Policy instructions explicitly called for a reduction
in bank reserves, as fighting inflation finally became a more important
objective than maintaining relatively low interest rates, or stable money
markets, or accommodating Treasury financing.
You may recall that the economy survived a "credit crunch"
in the early fall of 1966, as the continued strong demands for credit
in the face of restrictive monetary actions resulted in a temporary




-8-

upward spurt in market interest rates. In comparison with recent
interest rates, those of the 1966 credit crunch period look rather low.
The yields on neither short- nor long-term market securities rose above
six per cent at their peak levels.
There is an especially important lesson here. During 1964
and 1965, policy actions were directed towards maintaining relatively
low interest rates, but the efforts were in vain since the resulting
rapid growth in money generated inflation and rising interest rates.
On the other hand, following the nine month period in 1966, when
the immediate attention of policy actions was turned to controlling
the growth of monetary aggregates in order to combat inflation, lower
interest rates accompanied the slower growth of total spending and
easing demands for credit.
The restrictive monetary actions of 1966 were followed by a
sharply slower rate of growth of total spending and real product in
late 1966 and the first half of 1967. This was the period of the socalled mini-recession. As the growth of total spending in the economy
slowed, the immediate objective of policy turned to other near-term
goals such as stimulating renewed real economic growth, maintaining
the lower interest rates that had resulted from previous restrictions,
and facilitating continued large Treasury financing activities. During
most of the first half of 1967 there was a definite desire to move policy




-9-

in the direction of ease. Since the growth of total demand continued
to slow in delayed response to the restraint of 1966, demands for credit
continued to be moderate and market interest rates continued to fall.
Even with falling interest rates making money market conditions easier,
System open market purchases of securities increased, resulting in a
rapid resumption in the growth of the money stock.
The very clear intention of policymakers was to be only as
expansionary as necessary to promote growth of real production, but
not so stimulative as to refuel the inflationary forces. During the spring,
however, policy ceased seeking still easier conditions in the money market,
and sought only to maintain the easier conditions that had developed.
Although concern was being expressed about the possibility of reemergence of inflationary pressures, other immediate considerations
received more weight.
By June the economy was strengthening rapidly, and a
definite tendency developed for all market interest rates to rise. Once
again, as in 1964 and 1965, open market policy actions turned towards
a direct attempt to prevent market interest rates from rising further
in response to growing public demands for credit and extremely heavy
Treasury financing requirements.




-10-

The published public policy record shows that through the
summer and well into the fall of 1967, a dominant reason for attempting
to slow the uptrend in interest rates was the view that higher interest
rates might reduce the flow of funds into mortgages and slow the recovery
of residential construction activity. Also, some argued that higher
interest rates might have adverse effects on the flow of funds into
financial intermediaries such as savings and loan associations.
Inasmuch as the U. S. Treasury borrowed over 23 billion dollars in
the fiscal year beginning in July 1967, money and capital markets
were under great pressure. Consequently, many contended
that open market operations by the Federal Reserve should
hold interest rates down in order to avoid these many undesired
effects. In response, the System expanded bank reserves and the
money stock at very rapid rates in this period.
Furthermore, in the fall of 1967, some felt that policy actions
should be constrained from becoming restrictive because of the possible
adverse effects such actions might have on the position of the British
pound sterling in the foreign exchange markets. The prevailing view
was that if System actions became less expansionary through reduced
purchases of securities in the open market, and market interest rates
rose as a consequence, relatively more international capital might flow
out of Britain and into the United States. Such events might, in turn,




-II-

force the British to devalue the pound. Thus, the international
situation was a more immediate concern of policymakers than was
the avoidance of renewed inflationary pressures. As you may recall,
the British devalued the pound in late November 1967 in spite of the
good intentions of United States policy.
By the end of 1967 it finally became clear that inflationary
pressures were building up rapidly and some restraint would have
to be exercised in order to avoid greatly overheating the economy.
However, policy actions were constrained to allowing only slightly
firmer conditions to develop in the money market because of the
continuing concern about the possible adverse effects of higher
interest rates on financial intermediaries.
This is a puzzling period to assess. The experience of 1964
and 1965 had shown that direct policy actions attempting to maintain
low interest rates would be frustrated, since the rapid growth of the
money stock which resulted from the low interest rate policy caused
acceleration of inflation and sharply rising interest rates. The more
recent experience of 1966 had shown that an anti-inflationary policy
of holding down the growth' of the money stock would produce lower
interest rates once the upward thrust of inflationary expectations was
broken. Yet policy actions in 1967 returned to direct attempts to maintain low interest rates. Once again the result was accelerating inflation.




-12-

If policy decisions were misdirected in 1967, it was even more
true in 1968. In the first half of 1968 there was a clear consensus that
a restrictive anti-inflationary policy was appropriate. Yet short horizons
and other immediate considerations forestalled restrictive actions.
There was the almost ever-present Treasury financing to consider, and
in March the crisis in the London gold market militated against restrictive actions.
The public policy record for early April 1968 delineates the
considerations which dominated this period. Although the desirability
of fighting inflation was commonly agreed upon, some argued that
any firming actions should proceed with caution for several reasons.
First, restrictive monetary policy was believed to be inappropriate in
view of the prospects for fiscal restraint. Second, some thought the
sharply rising interest rates indicated "a considerable degree of
monetary restraint had already been achieved" and also there was the
persistent concern that restrictive actions "might have large adverse
effects on flows of funds to financial intermediaries", and such would
be undesirable. Finally, there was uncertainty about the economic
effects of the Vietnam War.
The second half of 1968 was a regrettable period for
United States stabilization policy. In June, Congress passed the
Revenue and Expenditure Control Act which raised corporate and




-13-

personal income taxes and slowed the growth of Government spending.
A view became very widely held in the summer and fall that this fiscal
package was too restrictive and would cause too sharp a slowdown in
the economy. As a result, there was an overt move towards easier
monetary policy to counter this presumably very restrictive fiscal
impact.
By December 1968, however, it became widely recognized that the
fiscal package had little, if any, restrictive impact, and that the monetary
ease had further fanned the flames of inflation. Monetary actions moved
strongly towards restraint as the growth of the money stock was curtailed
in spite of the continuing strong demands for credit and rising interest
rates.
This marked the end, for the time being, of a two year period
of the most stimulative monetary actions since the Korean War. The
direct efforts to thwart the tendency for interest rates to rise had been
a total failure, since the expanding inflationary pressures had resulted
in sharply higher short- and long-term interest rates.
To recapitulate so far, the rapid 6 per cent rate of growth of
the money stock in 1965 and early 1966 resulted in an overall inflation
rate of about 3-1/2 per cent, and interest rates of 5-1/2 to 6 per cent
before the restrictive actions of 1966 took effect. The still more rapid




-147-1/2 oer cent growth in money throughout 1967 and 1968 ultimately
resulted in the overall rate of inflation accelerating to over 5-1/2
per cent and most interest rates peaking between 8 and 9 per cent.
Finally, in 1969, policy actions brought about significantly
slower growth rates of money. In turn, after a iag,the slower growth
of money brought the growth in total demand down to more sustainable long-run rates. As in the "credit crunch" of 1966, restriction
of the growth of money in 1969 temporarily resulted in sharply
higher interest rates as the inflation-fed growth in demands for
credit continued very strong for a while after the supply of new
funds to the market was curtailed. But as before, once the upward
thrust of expectations concerning continued inflation was broken,
growth in the demand for credit slowed and interest rates began to
move quickly downward.
After two major episodes of stop-and-go actions, policymakers
in 1970 were in a position to benefit significantly from their recent
past experience. Last year monetary policy actions moved to a
moderately expansionary stance, and I have no disagreement with
the growth of the money stock that resulted on balance in 1970. By
year's end the quantity of money outstanding was somewhat over 5
per cent greater than a year earlier, and I think that was about
right in view of the lack of real output growth and the rising unemployment we were experiencing.




-15However, I believe that over a longer period of time, and
especially under conditions of a stronger pace of real economic
growth and a higher level of employment, a 5 to 6 per cent rate of
growth of the money stock would prove excessive in terms of the
average rate of inflation. It is my view that the longer-run noninflationary growth rate of money most likely would be on the order
of 3 to 4 per cent. As the economy strengthens, I believe that the
rate of growth of money should be lowered to this more sustainable
range. I would like to elaborate on this view within the context of
the overall experience during the post-Korean War period.
Trend Velocity of Money
During the decade ending in late 1962, money grew at about
a 1-1/2 per cent average annual rate. Both the velocity of money and
the economy's productive potential increased at about a 3-1/2 per cent
average rate during this period. As a result, the overall rate of
price increase was a relatively slow 1-1/2 per cent average annual
rate. Then, from 1962 to the end of 1966, which includes the period
of restrictive monetary actions in 1966, the growth of money was at
an accelerated 3-1/2 per cent average annual rate. With velocity
continuing to rise at its earlier pace, and potential real output growing
somewhat faster, this rate of monetary expansion resulted in a
quarterly rate of inflation of 4 per cent in the latter part of that period.




-46Following the credit crunch of 1966, the growth of money
accelerated to very rapid rates, as emphasized previously. By looking
across the second period of monetary restraint in 1969, the resumption
of moderately rapid growth of money in 1970, and the period of very
rapid monetary growth thus far in 1971, 1 see that the growth of the
money stock has risen at about a 6-1/2 per cent average annual trend
rate since January 1967. In this period there was a marked fall in
the rate of increase of velocity, and the rate of potential output growth
rose slightly. Consequently, the very rapid growth of money since
early 1967 has resulted in about a 4-1/2 per cent average annual rate
of inflation as measured by the implicit price deflator, and a peak rate
of inflation of over 7 per cent as measured by the consumer price
index.
Even if the trend growth of velocity should continue in the
future to be at the recent slower rate, which, in my estimation,
would be a highly optimistic outlook, a continuation of the 6-1/2 per
cent trend growth of money since early 1967 would imply a sustained
4 per cent rate of inflation. If, on the other hand, the trend growth
of velocity in the future were somewhere between the low 1-1/2 per
cent rate of the past four years, and the 3-1/2 per cent rate of the
previous fifteen years, then the recent trend of monetary growth
could imply as much as a sustained 6 per cent trend rate of inflation.




-17If I get somewhat ahead of myself by noting that the money stock
has risen at a 9-1/2 per cent rate in the past six months, I am sure
that you can see why my reading of the events of the past seven or
eight years gives me cause for concern. The trend growth of money
from 1962 to 1966 was over twice the average rate of the previous
decade. I am fairly certain that after the credit crunch of 1966 there
were few who would have viewed another doubling of the growth of
money to be desirable. But that is whathappenedin 1967 and 1968.
After the high interest rate, highly inflationary developments of 1969,
and the liquidity crisis of 1970,

suggest that further acceleration of

the longer-term trend growth of money should be avoided at all cost.
Thus, the excessively rapid growth of money in recent months gives
me a feeling of "butterflies" where "butterflies" ought not to be.
Recent Monetary Growth
Additional insight into how rapid monetary growth has been
recently can be obtained by comparing the increases in some recent
periods with all earlier periods of similar length. In the last three
months money rose at a 12-1/2 per cent annual rate, which is faster
than

all other three-month periods since World War I I . In the

last six months, money rose at about a 9-1/2 per cent annual rate,
which is also faster than all other consecutive six month periods in
the last twenty-five years. Similarly, in the fifteen months since
February 1970, the approximate time when morerapidmonetary



-18growth was resumed following the restraint initiated in early 1969,
money has risen at about a 7-1/2 per cent annual rate. This is
faster than all but one per cent of similar length periods. This is
telling evidence that recent monetary growth has indeed been very
rapid, whether viewed in terms of absolute rates of growth or relative
to historical experience.
Implications for the Future
In closing, I would like to review with you some factors
which may have an important influence on the growth rate of money
in the near future. For obvious reasons I cannot divulge recent
policy decisions, and I could not disclose the growth rate of money
that is likely to result from policy actions, even if I knew. However,
I can discuss some factors which might be considered in the formulation and especially in the implementation of policy, as these have
been made public elsewhere.
I will indicate my judgment as to the direction of influence
of some factors which seem likely to lead to excessive monetary growth
if we do not profit from the experiences of the past. These factors are:
Treasury financing requirements in fiscal 1972, concern over the
general level and the trend of market interest rates, and desires to
rapidly expand growth of real product and to achieve a lower rate of
unemployment as soon as possible. Obviously there is some overlap
among these factors.



-19First, I think the direction of influence of Treasury financing
requirements in the past is clear; that is, periods of large Government
deficits have tended to be accompanied by rapid monetary growth.
President Nixon's budget message in January this year indicated a
deficit of 11-1/2 billion dollars in the fiscal year beginning this coming
July 1. However, as widely discussed at the time, the deficit will be
larger than otherwise to the extent that national income falls short of
the assumptions made by the President's advisors. Also, the deficit
will be larger if there is any tendency for Congress to spend more then
the President requested. According to assessments reported in the
press earlier this year, the planned deficit is probably the minimum
that will occur. The experiences of two previous periods, 1965 through
early 1966 and 1967 through early 1968, indicate that monetary actions
may result in a more rapid growth of the money stock than otherwise
under conditions of substantial Treasury financing.
The second factor which must be guarded against in order to
avoid continued excessively rapid growth of money, and this ties in
with the Treasury financing constraint, is concern for the level and
trend of interest rates. As the growth of real output in the economy
accelerates during the balance of this year and in 1972, or as
anticipation of inflation increases, the demand for credit to finance
production, consumption, and investment will increase. Such
increases in demand for credit put upward pressure on market-interest
rates.



-20There are at least two ways such a tendency for market
interest rates to rise would indicate conditions which might induce
excessively rapid growth of money, unless we carefully guard against
them. First, interest rates have traditionally played an important
role in the implementation of policy decisions, as I have illustrated
previously. High or rising interest rates have frequently been
identified with more restrictive monetary policy, and I doubt there
is a predominant desire of policymakers to achieve a very restrictive
policy stance at this time. Decisions to maintain relatively easy
conditions in the money and short-term credit markets might lead
to substantial purchases of securities on the open market. Such
actions could very well foster too rapid growth of bank reserves and
deposits, and thereby too rapid a rate of money creation, if we are
not careful to avoid such a development.
The other way that a tendency for interest rates to rise
might suggest rapid growth of money, is the view that low interest
rates, especially on longer-term securities, are essential for a
recovery of real economic growth. This view holds that the market
level of long-term interest rates is an important factor in business
investment plans. It is argued that a rise in interest rates might
"choke-off" recovery in business capital expenditures before the
economy has returned to a balanced level of high-employment real
growth. I am suggesting that one approach to stabilization analysis




-21views low interest rates as being a necessity for real recovery, and
that stabilization actions should be directed towards achieving and
maintaining low interest rates. Again, policymakers cannot accept
this line of reasoning without running the risk of excessive growth
in money.
The third factor which, if given considerable weight, would
tend to indicate continued rapid monetary growth is the desire for
rapid re-attainment of high growth in real output and a low rate of
unemployment. Aside from the influence of interest rates, there are
some who argue that rapid growth of money is necessary and
desirable in order to reduce quickly the rate of unemployment by
two or more percentage points, and to avoid the losses in output
inherent in continuing to produce below capacity.
While I agree that these are very desirable objectives, I feel
that achieving continued reduction in the rate of inflation is also a
worthy cause. It seems that some balance between the actions
necessary to achieve a quick end to the inflation and those necessary
to achieve a quick return to full employment is best. Especially at
the present time, those who argue for very stimulative policies
should make a realistic assessment of the implications for future
inflation, and indicate their willingness to accept such consequences.
Given the very long lags we have observed in the past between the
initiation of restrictive actions and progress towards smaller price




-22rises, it is not sufficient to say we can fight that battle when the
time comes.
Present actions must be made with full recognition of their
eventual consequences. In the period we have reviewed tonight,
policy actions were frequently directed towards the attainment of
short or intermediate term objectives, such as holding interest
rates down to help the housing industry or to encourage business
investment. Recently, actions also have been directed towards
achieving an early reduction in the average rate of unemployment,
and a prompt return to growth of real output at long-run potential.
However, a careful analysis of the events of this period show that
actions taken to deal with an immediate concern can later have
adverse effects on longer-run aspects of economic activity. Thus,
it frequently appears that present actions are simply dealing with
problems created by past actions. While I do not view the situation
as hopeless, it is obvious that there is ample room for improvement.
In conclusion, my remarks tonight may not appear to be
very optimistic. Possibly our future policy actions will be better
than in the past. We have ample experience from which
we can learn. If we do, then a quote regarding our ability to learn
from past experience would not be valid, at least with regard to the
conduct of stabilization policy. The quote is:




"What men learn from history,
Is that men do not learn from history.11