View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Remarks by
Darryl R. Francis, President
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
At Fulton, Missouri
November 14, 1974
It is good to have this opportunity to discuss with you
our assessment of the economic outlook for 1975. In view of the
seriousness of the current situation and changes being implemented
in governmental programs, the outlook is subject to greater
uncertainty than usual. Nevertheless, we at the St. Louis
Federal Reserve Bank believe that the old rules of economics
still hold, and that useful evaluations of the near-term
future can be gleaned from studying recent fiscal and monetary
actions and the momentum of economic developments. In short,
we subscribe to the "old-time religion" as applied to economic
stabilization and forecasting because the "newer religions" have
not produced any concrete proposals and have not given us any
reason to forsake the old.
Since the recent trends of economic developments are
likely to have a significant influence on future activity, I will
first assess the current state of the economy. In this examination, attention will be devoted to what we consider to be chief
causal forces. This review of underlying forces is undertaken




-2in order to make judgments on the strength and likely endurance
of current trends and to have some basis for evaluating the effects
of any changes in these forces. After this analysis, I will
present our view of the most likely course next year for production,
employment, and prices based on our judgment of the recent
trends, their causes, and our assumptions on the most probable
changes in national economic policies.
Economic Problems
As we all know, the economy is now in great disarray.
From the first to fourth quarters of 1973 growth in real output
of goods and services slowed to a 2 percent annual rate, and
since the end of 1973 real output has declined at a 4 percent
rate. By sharp contrast, output rose at an average 4 percent
annual rate from 1964 to 1972.
Reflecting cutbacks in output, employment has declined
in some areas. Nevertheless, total civilian employment has
risen about three-quarters of a million net since April, or at
a 1.7 percent annual rate. This is roughly the same as the
long-run expansion of population of working force age. Yet,
because of a higher portion of the population desiring to work,
the unemployment rate also has risen recently, reaching
6 percent of the labor force. This is up from the 4.8 percent
average level in 1973, and compares with the 5.8 percent average
which existed in 1971 and 1972.




-3In addition, the country is suffering the ravages of
a severe inflation. Consumer prices have advanced at a 10 percent
annual rate since the end of 1972. By comparison, during the
Vietnam conflict (1965-72), these prices rose at an average
4 percent per year, and in the pre-war years (1959-65), prices
rose at a 1.3 percent pace. The inflation, which many feel is
our most serious economic problem, is causing great redistributions
of wealth and income. To the extent that it has been unanticipated,
those with claims expressed in constant amounts of dollars have
lost purchasing power. Also, the inflation has had the effect
of a heavy tax increase, transferring command over resources
from consumers and businesses to the Federal Government.
Causal Forces
Let us now turn to the basic causes of our economic
problems. As you are all aware, the business and financial
press has placed the blame for our economic disarray on a
number of factors, the emphasis changing from time to time.
Let me enumerate just a few that the press has cited most
frequently: strong labor unions with power to raise wages and
increase in costs of production; businessmen with power to
administer prices; the world-wide food shortage which brought
about a skyrocketing of food costs; the wage and price controls
which distorted the allocation of resources and reduced incentives;




-4the Arabs raising the price of oil; and general political uncertainty.
There is little doubt that each of these factors has had an
impact on the state of our economy during the past year. However,
we believe that it is wrong to attribute the bulk of our underlying
economic problems to such irregular forces. Unions and
management have sought to better their relative positions long
before the current problems arose. Random forces such as
droughts, institutional changes in exchange rates, changing
consumer tastes, and revised legal rules have frequently had
sharp short-run effects on relative prices and on the allocation
of productive factors, but seldom have they influenced overall
prices or overall production significantly over an extended
period.
At the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, we have
conducted a number of studies into the basic cause of economic
fluctuations. Considerable evidence has been developed indicating
that the economy is basically stable and resilient. Despite
monopolistic elements and frequent random shocks, the economy




is not naturally subject to periods of great inflation or severe
recession.
Our studies indicate that the course of monetary expansion
has been the chief destabilizing factor underlying the problems
I have just outlined. According to these studies, the trend

-5growth of the money stock over four or five years determines




the trend rate of inflation. In short, the basic or underlying
rate of inflation is a monetary phenomenon.
Variations of a few quarters in the rate of money growth
around the trend, as well as a shift in the trend rate of money
expansion, have an important bearing on short-run cyclical
movements in output and employment. On the other hand,
after the growth rate of money is stabilized for a period, we
have found that growth of the economy naturally returns to
or near its productive potential.
Monetary Developments
A review of recent history helps illustrate this
monetary impact. First, let us look briefly at the changing
trends of monetary expansion since the early 1950s and
relate them to price developments. From early 1952 until the
fall of 1962 the money stock of the nation rose at an average
1.8 percent annual rate. From early 1952 to the end of 1965
(since money operates with some lag) prices, as measured
by the GNP deflator, also rose at a 1.8 percent annual rate.
Then the pace of monetary creation began accelerating.
From the fall of 1962 to the end of 1966, money rose at a 3.8
percent annual rate, and with a lag, general prices rose at a
3.7 percent rate from the end of 1965 to early 1969. Since late
1966 money has risen at an average annual rate of just over
6 percent, and overall prices have also risen at about a 6 percent




-6annual rate since early 1969.
At times, it has been suggested that inflation resulting
from rapid monetary growth, although not desirable, is the
price that must be paid for encouraging a high level of output
and a low unemployment rate. However, from early 1952 to the
fall of 1962, when monetary growth was relatively slow,
unemployment averaged 4.9 percent of the labor force. From the
fall of 1962 to the end of 1966, when the trend money growth
doubled, unemployment averaged 4.8 percent. Since 1966, with
money growth having accelerated further unemployment has
averaged 4.7 percent. In short, we have found that the trend
growth of money is reflected over time in the trend of prices
and has little sustained influence on production or employment.
Over shorter periods of time, however, fluctuations
of money around the trend growth, lasting several quarters,
have had an impact on output and employment with only a slight
effect on price trends. For a period preceding each of the
business cycle recessions in the post-war period, as well as
before the so-called mini-recession of 1966-67, the rate of
monetary growth slowed markedly. In each case, total real output
declined and unemployment rose. Also, in each case the rate
of inflation slowed somewhat, but at a high cost in terms of
reduced production and employment.




-7From the above casual observations, as well as from
empirical studies of past developments in this country and
others, several conclusions emerge. Monetary developments
have been the chief cause of both inflation and, at times,
high unemployment. They have been the cause of inflation
when there has been an excessive long-run growth of the
money stock. They have been the cause of temporarily higher
unemployment when we have had a marked slowing in the
growth rate of money.
Recent and Prospective Economic Conditions
Now, let us focus our attention on the monetary actions
which appear to have the most relevance for current economic
developments and which might be expected to bear heavily
on economic activity in the near future. The chief monetary
development of recent years has been the rapid trend growth of
money. From early 1970, the money stock rose at about a 6.5
percent annual rate.
Experience indicates that with money rising at this
rapid pace for such an extended period, the trend rate of
inflation would be in the 6 percent range. We attribute the
basic cause of this underlying rate of inflation to monetary
growth.
In contrast to the persistence of a high rate of inflation,
output has declined recently. Output, as measured by constant




-8dollar GNP, had risen at a 4 percent trend rate from 1962 to
1972. From the first to the fourth quarter of 1973, growth in
output slowed to a 2.1 percent rate, and in the first three
quarters of 1974 it declined at a 4 percent rate. Reflecting
the adverse developments in output, the level of unemployment
has been rising recently, but the rise has been much less
pronounced than the changed pattern of output.
There is considerable controversy regarding the basic
causes for this turnaround in output growth. Some analysts
content that the slowdown has resulted in large measure from
factors influencing aggregate demand. Other analysts contend
it has been due mainly to factors affecting overall supply.
Our view is that aggregate demand factors have
contributed very little to the moderation and contraction of
real product growth in 1973 and thus far in 1974. The dollar
volume of total spending, as indicated by current dollar GNP,
has expanded at a 9.5 percent annual rate since the last
quarter of 1972. This compares with the 1962-72 average rate
of 7.5 percent, and is only slightly below the rapid 10.2 percent
rate during 1971 and 1972.
On the other hand, there have been numerous
constraints placed on supply. For example, environmental
requirements imposed on industry, in conjunction with price
controls until last spring, led many firms to close down production




-9facilities. Prices permitted on products did not generate
a return sufficient to justify outlays to meet governmental
environmental and safety requirements.
The oil embargo and the subsequent quadrupling
of the oil price has reduced the growth of oil use. The
depreciation of the dollar since 1971 has reduced the growth
of importation of foreign goods and services and substituted
for them more expensive domestic ones. All of these factors
tended to reduce the resources available for economic use
in production.
Also, as relative prices changed, reflecting the agricultural and oil situations, consumers, in an effort to maximize
satisfaction, changed their spending patterns, but industry
was not equipped to make the change as quickly. Hence, we
found a surplus of certain standard-size automobiles while
consumers have been seeking those that conserve on gasoline.
Furthermore, as overall demands rose rapidly, interest
rates were driven up, and at higher interest rates, consumers
desire more other goods and services relative to housing,
which usually must be financed by sizable loans for long
periods. As a result, we now have excess capacity in auto and
housing production, while many other industries, such as
steel, aluminum, machine tools, paper, chemicals, and
petroleum have been at or near capacity operations with backlogs
of orders. This has resulted in less efficient utilization of the
reduced available resources.




-10All of the above extraneous events thus led to a
reduction in output and, with the trend money growth at
about a 6 percent annual rate, to a sharply accelerated rate of
inflation. It is important to note, however, that the nonmonetary developments described above would produce a once
and for all decline in output, and thus only a once and for all
increase in the price level. In the absence of further external
or institutional shocks, output growth should return to its
historic rate and inflation should return to the pace consistent
with monetary expansion. Meanwhile, the adjustments to the
decline in resources take time to work themselves out, and
produce a statistical picture of sharp decline in the rate of
output growth and a sharp increase in the rate of inflation.
From a policy makers point-of-view, the acceptance
or rejection of the analysis above is of utmost importance.
If the decline and output was caused by supply constraints,
then fiscal or monetary policy to stimulate aggregate demand
further would result almost entirely in pure inflation without
much improvement in the rate of output and employment.
Next, let us shift attention to more recent monetary
developments. Since June of this year the reported rate of
money growth has been at a 2.3 percent annual rate.

We look

at this development as an irregular fluctuation and do not
assume that this slow rate of monetary expansion will be




-IImaintained for long. Experience indicates that an immediate
slowdown in the rate of money growth to, say, about a 2 percent
pace, if sustained for two more quarters, would cause a decline
in output and employment.
Looking at a somewhat longer and more meaningful
time period, the year to date, the reported average pace of money
growth this year has been somewhat less than the 6 percent
rate of 1973. If this rate of money growth were maintained
over the next several quarters, the growth in total spending
on goods and services would probably be around 8 to 9 percent
next year. This would be consistent with a reduction in the
pace of inflation from the recent double digit pace to a 6 or 7
percent range in the coming year. Also some resumption in
real output growth could be expected. We are moderately
optimistic regarding the relaxation of supply constraints on the
economy. Price controls have been removed. Industry has
made great strides adapting to the changes necessitated by the
oil situation. Yet, despite these and other improvements, much
more could be done to improve supply. Following the many
recommendations made at the recent economic summit meetings,
our Government could make a substantial contribution to
further production growth by repealing laws and regulations
which impede competition and efficiency and push up prices.




-12ln short, we anticipate some sluggishness in real
production during the next six months, and after that some
gradual improvement. This forecast might be accompanied
by a further gradual increase in the rate of unemployment
during the spring and summer of next year, before beginning
to recede. Although this development alone is unpleasant
it is much less severe than many recent projections.
Conclusions
In summary, major adjustments are taking place
in the economy. Inflation is severe, and real output has
been declining. The chief causal factor for inflation has
been the acceleration of monetary growth which began in the
mid-Sixties but has been particularly rapid since early 1970.
But in addition, the economy has been hobbled by a number
of Governmental actions, a chief one being the controls
on prices. Also, a greater than normal number of exogenous
shocks have been received, such as droughts and the rise
in foreign oil prices.
It will not be possible to quickly achieve the goal
of maximum potential real growth without inflation. Now
is not the time to advocate quick solutions, fine tuning, or
radically new remedies. Experience, both here and abroad,
teaches that attainment of these two goals will only be achieved
by disciplined monetary actions, facilitated by sound fiscal




-13policies. Even then progress is likely to be slow, and both
patience and fortitude will be needed. The Government could
aid in shortening the adjustment period by eliminating many
laws and regulations which interfere with competition and the
efficient growth of output.
In the near future, we anticipate monetary growth
will be moderate, as it has been so far in 1974. As Chairman Arthur
Burns stated on October 10 to the Joint Economic Committee of
Congress: 'The policy that we have pursued represents a middle
course, We have tried to apply the monetary brakes firmly
enough to get results, but we have also been mindful of the
need to allow the supply of money and credit to keep expanding
moderately."
If this moderation in money growth does continue, the
rate of inflation should gradually recede, no major recession
should occur, and although we anticipate some further
sluggishness, real output should not decline further and
employment should rise.