View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

THE ORIGIN AND IMPACT OF INFLATION
Remarks by
Darryl R. Francis, President
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Before the
Committee to Investigate a Balanced Federal Budget
of the
Democratic Research Organization
Washington, D. C.
March 26, 1976
(Originally given to the Canadian Council of Financial Analysts
and The Toronto Council of Financial Analysts, Toronto, Canada,
November 18, 1975)

It is a pleasure to be here and to share with you my views on
inflation. This is a subject whose popularity has fluctuated with cyclical flutua-

tions in business activity: It is debated during upswings only to recede into
oblivion during downswings. Yet, in my opinion, it is a subject which should
be analyzed at all times since it is during downswings that the seeds of inflation

are sown.
You have suggested that I speak on the monetarist view ot

inflation. While the framework within which I analyze the causes and conse­

quences of inflation is of the monetarist variety, I think I should warn you that
what I consider most important does not necessarily represent the view of all

monetarists.

In order to put things into perspective, I should like to outline

this framework of analysis.

The impact of an increase in the total money stock when
it is not accompanied by a similar increase in output has a predictable effect




-2 -

Individuals will attempt to divest themselves of what they

on behavior.

consider to be their excess money balances by bidding for other, non­

money assets. As the prices of these assets rise, additional output
is stimulated.

But such increases in output are limited by the

growth of resources. Expansion of the money stock which is maintained

at a rate greater than the trend growth rate of output produces only a
transitory increase in production, while it leads to a permanent rise

in the rate of increase of prices. Evidence for these results is not
difficult to find.

Rates of growth of money and rates of increase in

the price level closely parallel each other when viewed as long-term

trends.

A great deal of evidence has been amassed showing that
an increase above the trend growth of money which persists for at
least two quarters will lead to a rise in the rate of output which is

quite short-lived.

However, as the rate of production returns to its

trend level, the rate of inflation increases. We have observed a sym­

metrical situation for declines in the rate of money growth. Such

declines create transitory recessions that are replaced by lower inflation
rates in six to eight quarters.

But if we accept this relationship between money supply and
the price level, why has the money stock been allowed to grow in such a
way as to produce persistent and accelerating inflation punctuated by

occasional recessions? Despite many arguments to the contrary, it is




- 3 clear that central banks can control the money supply within a very

narrow range over a time period of a quarter or more.

Have they

produced this growth pattern through some nefarious design? Have

they merely been incompetent?

I, for one, believe that neither is

the case and that we must look to our political and social aspirations
for the root causes of the economic dilemma upon whose horns we

sit so very uncomfortably.
To do this, I shall confine my observations to the
American experience, simply because I am most familiar with

the trails of the United States economy, I am quite sure, however,

that parallels can be drawn for Canada and many other Western
industrialized nations which face the same problems of inflation

and unemployment.
For many years, government spending and the size of the

government sector have expanded at an increasing rate. Since 1950
total annual government expenditures have risen by about $454 billion,

with $328 billion of that having occurred in the past ten years. This

growth was spurred by an underlying philosophy which contends that

greater direct government activity is the best if not the only way to

achieve certain economic and social goals. So let us consider the claims
of those who espouse this philosophy and examine their validity.

Has

this spending accomplished what it set out to do? Was it indeed the "best"

way? And finally, has it had other consequences, too important to be
termed merely "side effects", which have imposed high costs on us all?




-4-

One of the oldest arguments in favor of increased
governmental incursion into economic life holds that fiscal policy

is the proper, indeed the necessary, tool to stimulate the economy

and combat unemployment.

In addition to the automatic stabilizing

effects of tax and transfer payment policy, it has been alleged that the

government should introduce significant spending efforts when the
activity of the private sector is inadequate for full employment,

however defined. And it is argued that this spending should engender

deficits, since financing through higher taxes would reduce private
purchasing power and frustrate the attempt to expand total demand.
Historically, government deficit spending has had no
stimulative effects except insofar as it was accompanied by monetary

expansion. Thus the stimulation desired could have been accomplished
directly through monetary expansion without the government encroach­
ment into the private sector that is inherent in fiscal policy. More

important, we know that the stimulus is only transitory — that the
output effects of excessive money growth are quickly dissipated and

that the only lasting result is ever aggravated inflation. Consider
our actual performance.

Have we reduced fluctuations in output and

employment through the wide use of fiscal deficits and surpluses?

Obviously the answer is na Since the inception of these policies in
the early thirties the frequency and magnitude of economic fluctuations

have not differed significantly from those prior to that period.




-5 A second popular argument, and on the surface a very

persuasive one, states that it is the proper function of government
to employ those resources, particularly labor, which the private
sector is unwilling to employ. Presumably, the whole society benefits

from such programs at no cost, since additional production is being

provided by those who were previously contributing nothing. This is a
seductive argument which merits careful examination. Surely we
must agree that private enterprise will always take advantage of the
opportunity to employ resources which it expects to use profitably.

When some resources are not so employed, it means only that their
services are not worth the price attached to them.
For the cause of this

to the influence of government.

situation, we must again look

Hedged in as we have become by

laws requiring the payment of minimum wages and "equal pay for
equal work", we have seen more and more of the labor force become
unemployable. And when the government puts them to work, one

basic result is the same. To the extent that these people are being

paid more than the market decrees, there is a real transfer of wealth
to them from the rest of society. Real output may be greater, but much
of the increase in their welfare comes not from their new productivity

but from the rest of us.




To gauge the accomplishments of these policies,

-6-

whatever their redistributive effects, we need only to look at what
has occurred.

In the face of many job-creation programs, we find

that output growth has risen at approximately a constant trend rate

since 1946, irrespective of the rate of government spending. And
in the same period, unemployment fluctuated around an average

of 4.9 percent until its recent increase.

An argument of more recent vintage maintains that the
goods and services provided by the private sector in response to society's

demands do not respond to the so-called true needs of society.

It

follows from this that the government should divert resources to the

satisfaction of these needs. More and more programs have been
enacted in areas ranging from health care to cultural pursuits.
Whether they have increased our welfare is highly questionable.

We have obtained these services only by sacrificing other things we
would have chosen for ourselves.

But in their efforts to make it

appear that there is indeed such a thing as a free lunch, our elected
officials have increased government expenditures without attempting

a corresponding rise in taxes. As a result, monetary growth and

inflation have provided the means of transferring control of resources
from private hands into the hands of bureaucrats who, it would seem,
know our needs better than we ourselves do.




Finally, implicit in all the arguments of the advocates of

- 7 interference is the assumption that an expanded government role
in economic activity will,and should, redistribute income in the
direction of some notion of greater equality. Whether this redistri­

bution is indeed desirable is an argument which has probably existed
since the first two humans met.

I will not attempt to make any

enlightening contributions to that debate.
what has been achieved.

It is fair to ask, however,

In spite of the expanding role of government

activity since World War II, the distribution of income has changed

very little. The income group representing the lowest twenty percent

received 5 percent of total income in 1947 and 5.5 percent in 1971 while
the share of the highest fifth fell from 43 percent in 1947 to 41.6 percent

in 1971. This can hardly be considered a significant accomplishment,

expecially in view of the costs incurred.

These proposals to improve our socio-economic welfare
have, through design or through ignorance,overlooked the problem
of financing the additional expenditures. The basic issue in the

financing of government programs is that resources have to be

transferred from one sector of the economy to another. This can
be accomplished in only three ways. One is to tax current private

consumption and investment, that is, to increase taxes. The second
is to tax future private consumption by incurring a deficit and selling
government securities to the private sector. This method moves




-8 -

resources immediately by reducing the purchasing power of security
buyers only but ultimately spreads the burden to all taxpayers when
the securities must be redeemed. And the third is to finance the deficit

by indirectly selling securities to the central bank which buys them
with newly created money.

When deficits are financed by the sale of government

securities, the attendant additions to the demand for credit must
exert upward pressure on the interest rate. Aside from directly

discouraging private consumption and investment spending, higher
interest rates, like taxes, are politically undesirable.
first two methods have typically not been favored.

Hence, these

If the central bank

must submit to political pressure to contain increases in interest
rates, the solution is clear. The monetary authority is compelled to

buy at least a portion of the government issues from the private sector.
This action undoubtedly mitigates the initial pressure on interest
rates but at the same time it stimulates money growth and the ensuing

inflation leads eventually to higher interest rates.

The process I have outlined here is not hypothetical; we
have seen it in operation over the greater part of the past thirty years.
Since 1950, the federal government's debt has grown by $176 billion.

In

that same period, the Federal Reserve System's holdings of debt have

grown by $68 billion and the money stock has increased by $176 billion.
Meanwhile, proponents of deficit spending as a stimulus have proudly

pointed to their successes as they saw output and employment increase —
however briefly — with each new deficit, and considered the attendant



-9-

inflation a small price to pay for the short-run achievements.

To sum up: there is no convincing evidence that increased
government spending, with its accompanying deficits, has accomplished
its stated social goals. There is no evidence whatsoever that it is the

most efficient way to pursue these goals or even that any benefits have
exceeded the costs involved. On the other hand, there is overwhelming

evidence that it has led to our persistent inflation.

I can therefore say

unequivocally not only that the causes of inflation are identifiable, but

that they can be eliminated. That they should be eliminated becomes
clear once we consider the consequences of inflation.

One of these is that it can inspire monetary policies that
reinforce inflationary pressures. A closely-related policy effect is

the recurrent effort to reduce inflation drastically which produces
recession.

I have already discussed the fact that increased government
borrowing exerts an upward pressure on interest rates. When the

central bank is then called upon to monetize a part of the debt in

order to counteract that pressure, inflation ensues. Each time this
process has been pursued interest rates did not stay down for long.
As people become aware of inflation and the expanded money supply,
they expect prices to rise further.

Interest rates rise as inflationary

premiums are incorporated into them. The central bank again attempts




- 10 -

to resist by increasing the money supply and the whole cycle is renewed.
When the concern for inflation becomes greater than that

for interest rates, there are periodic attempts to reduce the rate of price

rise by sharp reductions in the rate of money growth. These reductions

have been responsible for most of our recessions and increases in
unemployment.

The less visible consequences of inflation are perhaps even
more ominous. An inflation which is not fully anticipated brings about

a redistribution of wealth from creditors to debtors. When people see
this occurring, they will bend their efforts toward protecting themselves
from these effects.

Another aspect of this wealth transfer is the loss which

inflation imposes on all holders of money. This leads all economic
units, both individual consumers and firms, to try to maintain smaller
money balances and, as it becomes a more costly productive resource,

to make greater attempts to economize on its use.

But these attempts

require the use of substitute resources, not the least of which are
the time and effort involved in devising alternatives to money transactions

I think you can easily visualize where this leads; we are all aware of the

inefficiences of bilateral barter transactions. Money is a useful good
which permits increased specialization in production and any decrease

in that specialization necessarily leads to a reduction in output. The
recorded instances of very rapid rates of inflation in Europe and South




- II America convincingly illustrate this fact.

A major consequence of the inflation that we have

experienced is the increased uncertainty which has had an impact
on every aspect of our economic life. There are really two factors at

work here. First, when a society has come to expect a fluctuating

inflation rate which cannot be accurately predicted, long-term financial
contracts become increasingly risky to both lenders and borrowers;

hence, they become increasingly rare.

I am sure you are all aware

that since the early thirties the average time to maturity of debt
obligations has decreased substantially. Greater uncertainty - that is,

greater risk — as to the financing of long-term investment leads to

reluctance to undertake such investment. As a result, productive
capacity is lowered and future consumption possibilities are decreased.

Another source of increased uncertainty, and one whose
effects become immediately apparent, is that we have been led to expect
the government periodically to attempt to combat inflation in ways and

at times that we cannot predict. Many of these techniques, such as

wage and price controls, and reactions to them can,and already have,
produced serious distortions in the economic process.
An excellent example is the phenomenon observed in the
American automobile industry in the past year.

Faced with poor sales,

manufacturers reacted, not with straightforward price cuts, but

instead by instituting elaborate rebate programs which were more




- 12 costly both for them and for the buyers. The only reason which I can
see for this extraordinary maneuver is that they feared the imminent
reimposition of price controls and wished to insure themselves the
greatest possible flexibility in the face of this threat.

It is the long-term, often slowly working and hardly visible
effects of inflation, which, in my opinion, represent the greatest danger.

They lower the standard of living; they undermine the fiber of our political,

economic and social system. And because they are not readily apparent,

inflation frequently is considered to be of secondary importance to more
visible, but transitory economic problems.

Our current situation affords us a perfect example of the
problems I have outlined. Although it seems that we have reached the

bottom of the recession and that recovery is well underway, unemploy­
ment rates remain relatively high and some industries still suffer low
rates of demand. As recovery progresses and inventory liquidation

ceases it is reasonable to expect that private borrowing will increase;
this is bound to exert an upward pressure on interest rates.
Now, how will the government react to this combination

of circumstances? Will it again consciously disregard the dangers of

inflation, addressing itself to the short-run unemployment problem with

traditionally ill-conceived and ineffective spending programs? These
will engender massive government demands on the credit market, adding




- 13 to the push on interest rates. To combat this, money growth must

accelerate, bringing with it greater inflation in a year or so and still

higher interest rates.
What then? Will aggravated inflation be permitted or
will we subject the economy to another recession? Or shall we,
alternatively, break from our traditional response, allow the economy

to continue the progress it has begun without creating new problems
by attempts to accelerate the progress or to depress the interest rate.

These are the alternatives which face policymakers.
In conclusion, let me restate my fundamental propositions.

First, it is quite evident that inflation is the result of excessive monetary
growth and that demand-induced recessions are caused by sharp down­
ward deviations from this growth path. Second, monetary growth in

excess of resource growth has been the most dependable result of govern­

ment deficits and the desire to mask the resource transfers that these
deficits are assumed to entail. Third, deficits have typically arisen from
attempts to change socio-economic conditions, attempts which have, just

as typically, been futile.
Solutions are readily available, but they require a time

horizon which extends beyond the next election and beyond the short­
term outlook and narrow analytical base of many economists. The basic

requirement is the realization that all social and economic programs
entail a cost which must be paid in one form or another.




If this

- 14-

realization becomes prevalent and if the costs become clear, there will
be no need for central bank financing of huge government deficits.
Neither will there be a necessity for maintaining interest rates at some

predetermined level.

In short, there will be no need to fool the electorate.

This would free the monetary authorities to control the growth of the
money stock, keeping it at a rate consistent with the rate of growth of

output and eliminating the major cause of both inflation and demandinduced recession.

Meanwhile, in the current circumstances, it is perfectly
feasible to permit interest rates to seek their market-determined level

and to start a very gradual deceleration in the trend rate of money
growth.

It may take a year or two or three, but inflation can be reduced

without the emergence of recession.

But again, a necessary condition

is the discipline imposed by public knowledge that any service provided
by the government must be paid for by the public itself and must be paid

immediately.
Perhaps such knowledge will reduce demands for governmental

services, or at least eliminate the political pressures to pretend that these
services can be provided free of charge. And in my opinion, these pretentions
are the major impulses which set in motion the causes of inflation.