View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

MONETARY POLICY AS A BACKGROUND
FOR COMMERCIAL BANK CREDIT POLICY
Speech by Darryl R. Francis, President,
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
to the National Credit Conference
of the American Bankers Association
Chase-Park Plaza Hotel, St. Louis
March 1, 1971
It is good to have this opportunity to discuss some important
issues at a Credit Conference of the American Bankers Association.
I am especially glad to have the opportunity to discuss the distinctions
and interactions between Federal Reserve monetary policy and commercial bank credit policy, as the title of my talk suggests. A common
fallacy is to refer to money and credit interchangeably. A central
point throughout my remarks will be that money and credit are not
the same. There is no doubt that central bank monetary policies
affect commercial banks' credit policies, and I would venture that
the credit policies engaged in by commercial banks have influenced
monetary policies. Nevertheless, one should not think of them as
being the same.
I will begin by highlighting the distinction between money
and credit, and with this distinction in mind, I will review recent
monetary and credit developments as I see them.
As you are probably all aware, every Thursday evening the
Federal Reserve releases for publication recent data on Federal




-2Reserve credit, bank deposits, reserves, and related items. The
Friday morning editions of major newspapers usually carry a
column in which these data are reported and interpreted. One
Friday last year the heading of one such column in a major newspaper stated that "A Limited Easing of Credit Is Seen." The first
sentence of that column told us, and I quote, "Federal Reserve
credit policy appears to be moving gradually toward a less restrictive
stance, banking data published yesterday showed."
That same morning a comparable column in another leading newspaper was headed by the words "Fed Reports Tight Money
Back Again." The first sentence in this column told us, and again
I quote, "Federal Reserve weekly statistics showed that the basic
money situation has shifted back to the tight side after some temporary
ease last week." One newspaper writer implied money was important,
whereas the other implied that credit movements were the important
factors. Presumably the authors of each of these columns had before
them the same data, so apparently they chose different items as being
important.
I would like to discuss the issues involved in the distinction
between money and credit, and to make clear my view of the relevant
measures to look at when assessing the influence of monetary actions.
I shall contend that there is one appropriate measure when assessing




-3the impact of such actions on over-all economic activity; and one
should take a quite different approach when analyzing the effects
on various segments of our economy of the credit policies of
commercial banks and other financial institutions.
Monetary Policy
The influence of monetary policy, which in recent times
in the United States has been almost the exclusive province of
the Federal Reserve, operates on aggregate spending in the economy.
I believe the fundamental objective of monetary policies is to
provide conditions conducive to an appropriate rate of growth in
demand for services, consumption goods, and investment goods.
This rate of growth should be equal to the ability of the economy
to produce such goods and services. I admit that it is far easier
to state this objective than to achieve it. The distributional effects
of monetary actions on various sectors are not usually the primary
goals of the policymakers. Although such distributional effects
are important and are given consideration, these effects are much
less predictable than are the effects on aggregate demand.
The channel through which monetary actions affect
aggregate demand is by varying the quantity of money made available to the private sector of the economy. If money is provided at
a rate greater than that at which businesses and individuals
desire to acquire currency and demand deposit balances, then




-4the effort to exchange these excess money balances for other
assets will increase aggregate demand for goods and services.
Conversely, if businesses and individuals desire to acquire
currency and demand deposit balances faster than the rate at
which the total amount of money is increasing, their efforts to
build up such balances will result in a decrease in the demand
for goods and services.
The primary tool of the Federal Reserve in the conduct
of monetary policy is buying and selling securities in the open
market. It is useful to summarize short-term monetary actions
within the framework of a concept called the monetary base.
When the Federal Reserve increases its holdings of Government
securities, which is the dominant source component of the
monetary base, the primary uses of the base, currency held by
the public and bank reserves, are increased. The growth of the
monetary base is the dominant determinant of the growth trend
of the money stock, even though short-term movements in the
money stock may also be influenced by changes in time deposits
and U. S. Government deposits at commercial banks.
Studies of the money creation process conducted at the
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis as well as elsewhere indicate
that the stock of money supplied to the economy could be adequately
controlled on a monthly average basis. As techniques for




-5establishing the appropriate amount of money to supply under
varying conditions are improved and gain wider acceptance, the
fundamental objectives of monetary policy, as I view them, can
be met with greater reliability than in the past.
I think it is important to note that during the process of
monetary expansion, the credit policies of commercial banks,
interacting with forces emanating from the nonbank public,
determine the sectors that are first affected. I will return shortly
to further discussion of this process.
Federal Reserve "Credit Policy"
I do not intend for my remarks concerning monetary
policy to imply that the Federal Reserve cannot or does not take
actions which have a direct bearing on commercial banks' credit
policies. Since monetary policy affects the volume of deposits in
banks, both the amount and the price of credit extended by banks
are affected. This is one important channel through which
monetary actions influence the real sectors of the economy.
However, aside from the monetary actions of the Federal
Reserve which have a direct bearing on the growth of aggregate
demand for goods and services, the Federal Reserve can and does
take actions which have a significant impact on the quantity,
quality, and price of bank credit. Furthermore, these actions
may have no more than a marginal effect on the total amount of




-6credit outstanding. This brings me back to my central point
regarding the distinction between money and credit.
An increase in the stock of money increases the total
purchasing power of the economy, whereas changes in the
composition of total private sector credit may represent only a
re-channeling of the flow of purchasing power that is transferred
from some economic units to other economic units. When one
economic unit chooses to save some of its current income by
increasing its holdings of time or savings deposits at a bank, it
is choosing to forego some present spending in order to preserve
some purchasing power for future use. When a commercial bank,
in its intermediary role, uses the proceeds of the increased
deposits to purchase securities or increase its business or consumer
loans, the present purchasing power preserved by one economic
unit is transferred to another economic unit. This transfer
permits some economic units to obtain more current command
over services, consumption goods or investment goods than their
own income would otherwise allow.
One example of an action that could be taken by the
Federal Reserve, which would affect the credit policies of banks,
would be to lower or hold the maximum interest rates banks are
permitted to pay on time and savings deposits below the yields
available to savers from competing institutions or financial



-7instruments. Under such circumstances, these deposits will flow
out of commercial banks, and the amount of bank credit extended
to the public will contract. In addition to a decrease in the volume
of bank credit, there will be an increase in the price of such credit
since banks will allocate the available supply of funds to those most
willing and best able to pay, given quality and other considerations.
A decrease in the volume of bank credit resulting from
such an action by the central bank will not necessarily reduce the
total credit flow in the economy; only the flows through the most
efficient channels are altered. The experience with regard to CDs
U.S. Treasury bills, commercial paper, and direct loans in recent
years confirms this point. Once short-term market rates of
interest had risen to the point that the yields banks were permitted
to pay on time deposits were no longer competitive, the volume of
these deposits at banks declined. Banks were forced to sell
securities and contract loans. However, corporate depositors
merely shifted to direct ownership of short-term Government
securities and to placement of short-term loanable funds on the
commercial paper market.
Credit Policies of Commercial Banks
I will now turn to a discussion of the credit policies of
commercial banks during the past two years, with references to
the monetary actions taken during the same period. For background,



-8I will digress for a moment to a summary of the developments
during 1967 and 1968. Throughout those two years every aggregate
monetary measure, including Federal Reserve credit, member bank
reserves, the monetary base, and both the broad and narrow
definitions of the money supply, were expanding at excessively
rapid rates. I assume that in retrospect there is little disagreement
that monetary policies were highly stimulative during that period,
although at the time some observers chose to point to the rising
interest rates as being an indication that restrictive monetary
policies were being pursued.
At the same time, total loans and investments at commercial
banks were rising at historically rapid rates. Taking volume as the
appropriate measure, one would say that bank credit policies were
very easy. However, the borrowers were pointing to the price they
were paying and arguing that credit was tight. I suspect that the
nation's biggest borrower, the U.S. Treasury, felt that the price
they paid for funds at the time was an indication of tight credit.
The developments in the first half of 1969 highlight the
distinction between monetary and credit policies. From January to
July 1969 the narrowly defined money stock (demand deposits plus
currency held by the public) grew at a little more than a 5 per cent
annual rate, which was somewhat less stimulative than the 7.5
per cent rate of growth of the previous two years, but certainly




-9not sufficiently restrictive to bring an early end to the considerable
inflation that had been generated.
By early 1969 most market interest rates had reached a
point where Regulation Q ceilings on the rates banks were permitted
to pay on time deposits began to sharply impinge. Since banks were
less able to compete for funds, total time deposits at commercial
banks contracted throughout 1969. The contraction was much
sharper in the second half of the year than in the first. As a
result of the considerably reduced growth of total deposits, banks
were forced to correspondingly reduce their rate of total credit
expansion. The growth of total loans and investments in early
1969 was less than half the rate of the previous two years.
Judging from the substantially slower growth of bank credit,
and the continued high and sharply rising interest rates in early
1969, it would appear that policies were much more restrictive than
indicated by the somewhat reduced growth rate of the money stock.
The reduced growth of bank credit, however, was manifested
almost entirely in a rather sharp contraction in the security holdings of banks. There was little slowing in the growth of loans
outstanding. Thus, from a loan volume standpoint, one would not
conclude that bank credit available to loan customers had tightened.




-10Turning to the second half of 1969, there is no question
that both Federal Reserve monetary policy and commercial bank
credit policies were tight. The money stock was essentially
unchanged from July to December 1969, which was very restrictive
in view of the inflation we were experiencing. Furthermore, time
deposits at banks continued to decrease as market interest rates
remained high compared to the ceiling rates banks could offer.
Large banks turned to nondeposit sources of funds to offset the
contraction in total deposits. As a result, banks managed a small
increase in the volume of credit outstanding in the second half of
the year, with loans outstanding continuing to grow at moderately
rapid rates while bank investments contracted almost as rapidly.
From the outset of 1970 the Federal Reserve moved in the
direction of easier monetary policy and also took a series of actions
which had the effect of bringing about easier credit conditions.
Growth of the money stock was resumed and maintained, and by
the end of 1970 the amount of money in the hands of the public
was 5.4 per cent greater than a year earlier. Considering the
inflationary forces continuing in 1970, monetary policy during the
year should be viewed as sufficiently expansionary to prevent
substantial declines in real production and provide for the gradual
abatement of the rate of price advances. At the same time the
monetary policy of the past year has been adequately easy to




-11facilitate the adjustment process of changing national priorities
inherent in the partial demobilization of military forces and shifts
in production from defense to non-defense related industries.
The first step taken by the Federal Reserve in early 1970
to help ease the credit flow through banks was to raise the ceilings
on the rates banks were permitted to pay on small time and savings
deposits. This improved somewhat the banks' competitive oosition
in attracting funds, but probably of considerably greater significance
was the decline in market interest rates.
Early in 1970 the demand for credit was contracting and
short-term interest rates began declining, as a result of the
sharply restrictive monetary actions of late 1969. In February 1970
market interest rates had moved down sufficiently that rates on
bank deposits again became competitive, and all types and sizes of
time deposits began a period of very rapid growth which has continued
to the present time. With the resumption of rapid growth in total
deposits, banks were again able to acquire earning assets and to
reduce their use of relatively expensive nondeposit sources of funds.
The composition of bank credit extended in 1970 was opposite that
of the previous year. Whereas banks had sold securities in 1969
in order to accommodate a continued strong loan demand, the growth
of bank credit in early 1970 was all in investments, as total bank
loans remained about unchanged from December 1969 to June last
year.



-12The very rapid growth of bank credit and the sharply
declining interest rates last year indicate very easy credit conditions.
However, this type of ease should not be construed as having any
implications regarding subsequent strength of aggregate demand or
indicating resurgence of forces contributing to increased inflationary
pressures. The re-intermediation of time deposits at commercial
banks reflected mainly changes in the ownership of securities and
a return of the flow of credit through channels that had been closed
or considerably narrowed during the previous year.
At the end of 1970 banks had increased their outstanding
loans by only 4 per cent from December 1969, while bank investments
rose over 14 per cent during the same period. I think it is clear
that the very rapid growth in the volume of total credit extended by
banks, and the significantly lower prices of that credit as the year
progressed, should not be construed to indicate that the Federal
Reserve was engaged in highly stimulative policies.
Suppose economic conditions had not been such in early
1970 that the Federal Reserve took actions which caused resumption
in the growth of the money stock. Market interest rates on shortterm instruments would have still declined in the face of reduced
demand for funds, although probably not so rapidly. Generally
falling short-term interest rates, together with the actions that
raised or abolished the maximum rates banks could pay on some




-13time and savings deposits would have been sufficient to cause
rapid re-intermediation of time deposits at commercial banks,
even if monetary policy had remained as restrictive as in late
1969. This return of funds to banks through time deposits would
have provided for a substantial increase in bank credit, although
somewhat less than actually occurred.
Outlook for Monetary Policy and Credit Growth in 1971
The growth of total commercial bank credit in 1971 will
be influenced both by monetary policy actions and by the rate at
which time and savings deposits continue to flow into banks. For
discussion purposes I will assume that monetary policy actions
this year will be about the same as 1970; namely, the money stock
will expand about 5 per cent. It is not unreasonable to assume
that the demand deposit liabilities of commercial banks might grow
at about this same rate.
Since a 5 per cent increase in demand deposits by itself
would allow for only about a 2 per cent growth in bank credit,
it is apparent that the volume of credit extended will be determined
mainly by the flow of time deposits and by nondeposit sources of
funds. In 1970 time deposit liabilities of banks increased about
four times as fast as demand deposits. Although this unusually
rapid growth of time deposits has continued in early 1971, it is
likely that as the year progresses time deposit growth will slow to




-14more normal rates relative to demand deposits. Under the
assumption that from April 1971 to the end of this year the
relative growth of time deposits to demand deposits will be about
the same as during 1967 and 1968 before Regulation Q impinged,
time deposits are likely to increase by 12 to 15 per cent by the
end of this year over last.
Some further run-off of nondeposit sources of funds to
banks is likely to occur this year, but much less than in 1970.
It seems reasonable that the net flow of funds into banks through
the end of this year will provide for about an 8 to 10 per cent
growth in total loans and investments.
The composition of the growth in bank credit this year
will depend substantially on the strength of demand for loan
funds ~ especially business loans. The growth in aggregate
demand for goods and services projected for this year, using our
Bank's econometric model, is expected to be moderately strong
and to provide for resumption of real economic growth as inflation
continues to abate. Given this outlook for economic activity,
business loan demand should strengthen from the rather sluggish
conditions of this past fall and winter.
Summary
In closing I will re-emphasize my central point — that
money and credit are not the same thing. Primarily through open



-15market operations, actions of the Federal Reserve determine the
rate of growth of the money stock. Numerous empirical studies
have shown that marked and sustained changes in the growth of
the money stock are followed by changes in the same direction of
the total demand for goods and services in the economy. Our
studies at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis indicate that the
effect on economic activity of a given change in the money stock
takes about four to five quarters to work itself out.
In contrast, our research has shown that it is not
possible to consistently arrive at an accurate assessment of the
outlook for economic activity by relying on observations of changes
in the volume of bank credit or the interest rates at which that
credit is extended. There are simply too many unpredictable
factors, such as the strength and composition of bank loan demand,
the public's saving rate, the inflation premium agreed to by both
borrowers and lenders that is reflected in nominal market interest
rates, and the effects of regulations and competitive factors which
affect the channels through which funds flow at various times.
In recent years we have learned that high and rising
market interest rates are more likely the result of excessive
monetary expansion, rather than an indication of restrictive
policies. We have learned that the flow of credit through banks




-16depends more on regulations on interest rates and on the ability
of banks to find and tap nondeposit sources of funds, than on any
actions taken by stabilization authorities with a view to influencing
aggregate demand. Furthermore we have learned that the volume
of credit flows through banks have little impact on overall economic
activity in the absence of corresponding changes in the stock of
money. Also, I hope we have learned that too rapid growth of
money will unavoidably cause inflation, that too slow of growth of
money will force economic contraction, and that we could do far
worse than to provide a steady and moderate growth in money.