View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

INTERNATIONAL MARKETS FOR AGRICULTURE IN THE SEVENTIES
Speech by Darryl R. Francis

President, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
to the
National Extension Transportation Workshop
Hotel Muehlebach, Kansas City, Mo.
March 23, 1971

It is good to have this opportunity to discuss with

you some vital issues of international trade in farm products.
We all have an interest in the international exchange of goods

and services - some as producers of commodities for export, others
as producers of commodities which compete with imports, and

all as consumers who gain from the efficiencies of international
specialization of labor and resource use.
First, I will discuss some historical views and

practices of international trade, followed by a review of trends

in our export trade relative to domestic production.

In conclusion,

I will outline policy actions that could be taken to promote foreign

trade expansion.
Trade Barriers are of Ancient Origin
International trade barriers date back to the dawn of

commercial history. The great Greek reformer Solon had
legislation passed in the Sixth Century B.C. forbidding the export




-2-

of wheat and most other agricultural products in order to provide
lower food prices to the poor city dwellers and improve the quality
and quantity of food on the home market.—

The Roman conquests

were often followed by treaties which provided for indemnities of
farm products for extended periods. Nevertheless, the Roman

government did at times take measures to prevent the export of

precious metals and limit competition from foreign producers.—

With the rapid development of an exchange economy in

the Seventeenth and Eighteenth Centuries, the Mercantilism
doctrine emerged which proposed that international trade be used
to promote national power. These views held that precious metals

were the basis of a strong state and that a so-called "favorable"
balance in foreign trade was the best means of obtaining such

metals. The execution of policies designed to provide the so-called
favorable balance encouraged a host of government regulations,

duties, and bounties. As an example, Oliver Cromwell's Navigation

Acts in the 1600's prohibited foreigners from bringing into England

any goods that were not the product of their own country.—

The

essence of the doctrine was that one should patronize home industry

]/_ Fritz M. Heinchelheim, An Ancient Economic History, (A.W.
Sijthoff's Uitgeversmaatschappij N.V.) Leiden, 1958, p. 286.

2/_ Lewis H. Haney, History of Economic Thought, The Macmillan
Company, New York, 1949, p.83.
3/

Haney, p. 142.




-3-

and that trade each year should always balance in one's own favor.
In the late 1700's and early 1800's, classical economists,
especially David Ricardo, pointed out that international specializa­
tion of labor offers the same opportunity for welfare gains as

domestic specialization.

In the British House of Commons Ricardo

contended that it was sound policy to admit the freest competition
with every branch of industry and with all the world. The writings

of Ricardo and Adam Smith were a major factor in the establishment
of commercial freedom in England by Prime Minister Sir Robert

Peel during the 1840's.-—
A plateau in free trade was reached about 1850 and was

maintained until about World War I.

Despite the appeal of

economists and other social libertarians, our own trade policies
along with those of other nations became more restrictive following
the war. Since that time, no nation has been willing to counteract

this trend with domestic and international policies conducive to

free trade.

Trends in United States Foreign Trade
This nation's exports of merchandise as a per cent of

goods production* has generally trended down since the late 1800's.
Merchandise exports averaged 10.4 per cent of production from

4/ J. R. McCulloch, from The Development of Economic Thought,
edited by H. W. Spiegel (John Wiley and Sons, Inc., New York,
1952.) p. 168.
* gross national product less services.




-4-

1869 to 1901, 9.7 per cent from 1901 to 1911, 7.7 per cent from 1922
to 1931, and 5.1 per cent since 1950. Merchandise exports averaged

only 2.6 per cent of production during the depression years
of 1932-39. Although the 1960-69 merchandise exports average
of 5.2 per cent of production was slightly above the 1950-59
average of 4.9 per cent, the gain is probably attributable to a

higher proportion of merchandise exported with governmental
assistance.
In the early decades of our nation, farm products

were the largest portion of our exports. Such products accounted
for more than three-fourths of our exports in the 1870's, over
one-half in the early 1900's, and more than one-third in the early

1930's.

In the five years from 1965 to 1969, however, they accounted

for only about 20 per cent of the total and only 16 per cent when
foreign aid is excluded.

Commercial farm exports have trended upward since
1955. From an average of $2.5 billion per year for 1955-59

inclusive, such exports rose to an average of $5 billion for the
five years ending in 1970. Nevertheless, these exports currently
are a smaller per cent of farm output today than in the 1920's or

in t he Great Depression of the early 1930‘s.

In the five years 1965-69

these exports accounted for 12 per cent of domestic cash farm

receipts, compared with 21 per cent in 1920-24, 16 per cent in 1925-29,




-5 -

and 14 per cent in 1930-34.
Furthermore, without governmental subsidies commercial

farm exports would have been lower in recent years. Such
assistance included barter shipments for United States Government

agencies, extensions of government credit and credit guarantees,
sales of government-owned commodities at less than market prices,
and payments to exporters in cash or in kind. We view these

practices as "dumping" when other nations export products to us

under similar conditions.
The decline in foreign trade relative to gross national

product in recent decades may reflect three factors - the changing

structure of national production, the faster growth of the United
States economy compared with the rest of the world, and the more
extensive use of restrictive trade policies in this and other nations.

The structure of production has changed over the years from an
agricultural economy to one largely based on manufacturing. This

trend toward greater diversification of output has reduced our

dependence on foreign trade. Also, the fact that our total growth
has been somewhat faster than the rest of the world indicates that
other nations had slower growth in demand for imports and output

of exports. This has led to a relative decline in our export trade.

But of greater significance than either the changing structure

or our faster growth has probady been the increased protection of




-6-

domestic industry.

Protection: Major Trade Restraint
Protection of domestic producers from foreign competi­
tion has been a major political issue throughout our history.
In our nation's infancy, tariffs were levied in preference to
domestic taxes.

Later, tariffs were raised to protect our so-called

infant industries from foreign competition.

Between 1865 and 1935,

our average rate on dutiable imports never fell below 39 per cent,

except for the period during and immediately following the First
World War when the Underwood Law in 1914 imposed an average rate

of 29 per cent on dutiable imports. At this time other nations
5/
had a very small output of civilian goods for export.— In 1923

under the Fordney-McUmber Law, the average rate was again
raised to 39 per cent, and in 1930 under the Hawley-Smoot Law,
it was increased to 53 per cent.

Since the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act of 1934, the

nation has pursued an announced policy of "freeing" international
trade. Numerous tariff reductions have been negotiated. Nevertheless,
duties have often remained so high and other restrictions so

effective that export trade has not increased relative to domestic
production.

5/_ Don D. Humphrey, American Imports, The Twentieth Century
Fund, New York 1955, p. 74.




-7Protection Now Through Nontariff Barriers
While tariffs have traditionally been the chief means

of protecting domestic producers from foreign competition, other
protective devices have been used increasingly by industrial nations
in recent years. These include import quotas, domestic subsidies,
bilateral trade agreements, import licensing, and domestic

monopolies operating under governmental authority.

In some

instances, the restrictions have involved special legislation.

In

others, informal agreements have been sufficient to limit trade to
arbitrarily determined levels. With the aid of one or more of

these measures, nations can maintain tariff duties at relatively
moderate levels and still protect producers from foreign competition.
A reduction in tariff rates may thus have little meaning since real

legislative barriers to trade often remain unchanged.

Our country has not been innocent with respect to the
use of these nontariff protective devices. Even in agriculture,

which has such a large stake in free trade, we have established
highly protectionist policies. We have sugar import quotas which,

based on New York wholesale prices, cost U.S. consumers an
additional 22 cents for each five pounds of sugar purchased.—
We have subscribed to international trade agreements which set

6/_ International Monetary Fund, International Financial
Statistics, Sept. 1970, p. 29.




-8minimum prices on coffee and wheat, thereby limiting trade in
these commodities. We have meat import quotas which provide

limits on imports of beef. A cotton export subsidy, designed to
offset the trade retarding features of our domestic prices support

program, has often been sufficient to permit exports of cotton
to Japan and imports of goods made from the cotton to the U.S.
for sale in competition with our own mills.

In order to avoid

excessive disruptions from such competition, however, we have
a tacit agreement with the Japanese to limit cotton goods exports to
the United States.

Such tacit arrangements are apparently

preferred to formalized legal actions, but if they are equally
effective in reducing trade, they are likewise equally effective

in reducing welfare.
Domestic Subsidies Restrictive
Production controls and subsidies are also important

in limiting foreign trade. For a number of years the British
have subsidized their farm sector. This leads to excessive labor
in agriculture which, in effect, limits their imports and our

exports of farm products. These workers could earn more in
nonfarm pursuits, and under free trade conditions the British

would export more nonfarm products and import more farm products,

thereby enhancing total production and welfare.




-9-

Our own domestic farm prog rams likewise inhibit world
trade. Our restrictive farm programs have probably offset the
advantages gained from the reduced tariff levies since 1934. Farm

production control and price support programs initiated in the
mid-1930's have contributed to higher farm production costand
higher prices for domestic farm products. Our farm products

have become less competitive in world markets.

But worse, from

a long range view, our policy of arbitrarily pricing at higher than

free market levels has led to a loss of confidence in us as a long-run
supply source. This move from competitive to arbitrary pricing
indicated to our customers abroad that our export prices would

be in excess of free market prices. Higher export prices in turn
led to higher food and fiber costs in the importing nations. Their
costs of imported food thus hinge on the decisions of our price

making authorities, who are likely to be more influenced by
political pressures at home than by supply and demand forces.

It is my conclusion that the predominent political

forces in most nations today do not want increased foreign trade.
Large gains in trade temporarily upset markets and cause changes
in resource use. Some hardships occur for the relatively less
efficient industries in the short run; these losses are more than

offset, however, by gains in the relatively more efficient indus-




- 10 tries and among all consumer groups.

In the longer run, all

groups gain from the greater efficiency of international
specialization.

But to date, neither this nation nor other nations

have indicated a willingness to adopt policies that will assure
these major gains at the expense of minor adjustments among

the less efficient producer groups.

Restrictive Arguments are Fallacies
In recent decades arguments advanced for protection7/

ist practices include:—

1.

Large imports lower domestic prices and
incomes.

2.

It is unfair to domestic labor to

compete with producers under "sweatshop"
conditions abroad.
3.

Imports are not a reliable source of vital

products, such as food and critical defense

items.
4.

Excessive imports damage vital defense

industries, which are necessary for survival.
Implicit in each of these arguments are the beliefs that

import restrictions aid certain producer groups or that some

products are vital to national survival and we cannot afford the

risk of relying on imports exclusively for these products.

7/




Humphrey, Chapter 7.

- II The argument that import restrictions aid some producer
groups is true only in the short run.

Under free trade, real

gains accrue to all groups in the long run, as labor and other
resources adjust to new supply and demand conditions. Furthermore,

these restrictions which aid inefficient producers in the short
run reduce the welfare of the rest of the nation.
Increased agricultural exports are a potential source of
major welfare gains from free trade. Such exports to Western

Europe, for example, will first cause a reduction in prices of
European farm products and a reduction in food costs to European
consumers. European farm incomes will decline, providing

incentive for farm workers to seek higher paying jobs in the
non-farm sector. The larger and relatively more efficient

nonfarm labor force will achieve more efficient output of nonfarm

goods and services, thus lowering costs and prices. Exports of

these products to the United States will increase. These greater
efficiencies in their nonfarm sector are accompanied by efficiency

gains in the farm sector where only the most efficient workers

have remained. A larger volume of all products will be available
at lower prices, enhancing real incomes and welfare.
On the American scene, the larger volume of farm

exports will tend to increase domestic farm prices and incomes.
This will attract new resources into agriculture from other sectors

until returns to resources in all sectors are again equal. The




- 12 larger imports of nonfarm products by the United States will tend to
reduce demand for domestic nonfarm output. As in Europe, after

adjustments are made, the increased efficiencies will provide more

goods and services to our people.
The argument that imports from low cost factories

abroad are unfair to labor is similar to the farm import argument.
Import restrictions shield workers in our less efficient industries

in the short run but, at the same time, injure workers in our
more efficient export industries. Exports will decline along with

imports because export accounts over the long run must be settled
through imports. On the other hand, once workers and other

resources have adjusted to free trade markets, greater supplies of
all goods and services are available, and the benefits of greater

production efficiency accrue to all.
Most major countries subscribe to the vital industries
argument for protection of domestic producers who are assumed

to be essential for national survival. England, for example, has

in the past attempted to maintain domestic food production at
about 50 per cent of domestic usage. This practice originated

from a lack of confidence in imported supplies at critical periods,

such as during wartime blockades. Many other nations, including




- 13our own prefer to maintain sufficient resources in these so-called

vital sectors in order to provide a minimum level of output in
case of loss of supplies, such as petroleum and sugar in the
United States.

Protective practices lead to the inefficient production
of these products and the wasteful use of resources. They cause

increased taxes for defense purchases and higher prices for
the consumer goods output of such industries. Methods of modern
warfare have made these long-run safety measures obsolete.

Nations now have the power to destroy one another long before

supplies of such critical products are depleted. Furthermore,
if nations did more trading with one another and were less self-

sufficient, we might have fewer wars.
From the standpoint of U. S. agriculture we look
abroad at rapid growth of Western European nations and see

great opportunities for farm commodity exports, provided these
nations will only open their trade doors and invite us in.

It is

my conclusion that we have not earned the right to this market.
Despite our numerous pronouncements, our policies have not
contributed to two-way trade. We have done little to merit Western

European confidence in us as a source of vital products at
competitive prices. Our domestic pricing and production control

policies in agriculture are not conducive to free trade. A recent




- 14study by the University of Illinois found that Illinois farmers
favor foreign trade but prefer to restrict beef and ham imports. —
This view demonstrates the fact that we have not consistently

thought out a free trade policy.
Although the arguments are overwhelming in favor of
more trade between nations, I am quite pessimistic about its

future course. Forces tending to reduce welfare through trade barriers
are better financed and more powerful than the forces active in

promoting welfare through freeing trade channels. As an indica­
tion of the power of protective groups, about 590 import quota

proposals were introduced in the last session of Congress prior
to the end of August.—

One bill was appraised by the New York

Times as the "most protectionist and reactionary trade legislation

in forty years."—

Signs admonishing us to purchase American

goods and protect American jobs can be observed daily. Even
agreements on quotas are looked upon as favorable to free trade

in lieu of more rigid restrictions. —

Only the textbooks and

economic libertarians are available to point out the gains from free
trade, and few are shouting the story to the general public.

Decade after decade those few who are vitally interested in the

3/_ Harold D. Guither, "Illinois Farmers View Current Policy
Issues," Illinois Agricultural Economics, Vol. 10, No. 2and
Vol. II, No. I, July 1970 - Jan. 1971, p. 23.

9/_

International Commerce, Sept. 7, 1970, p. 10.

JO/ New York Times, Sept. 21, 1970.

11/

New York Journal of Commerce, editorial March I, 1971.




- 15 -

welfare of all the people have been doomed to repeatedly roll the

stone of free trade ideals uphill, and as the stone appeared to
reach the top, down it tumbled to the bottom because of undermining
operations such as import quotas, domestic subsidies, and vital

defense industry protection practices.

SUMMATION

In summary, there are few who deny the gains from

greater exports, but powerful groups fear a rise in imports.

Both

exports and imports enhance welfare. The removal of trade

restrictions would be especially beneficial to United States
agriculture. We have a major comparative advantage in the

production of farm commodities. Under free world trade policies
and free domestic producing conditions, world-wide food prices
could be lowered, and world diets improved.

The Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act, the recent
Kennedy Round, and numerous other acts were designed to

achieve free trade objectives.

Proposed modern liberal policies,

however, are often followed by restrictive actions more typical
of earlier ages.

In practice we still follow the outdated theories

of the Mercantilists of three or four hundred years ago.
Most of the arguments used against free trade practice

are not applicable to modern world condi tions. The implied



- 16-

disruptions in local industries are generally overstated and are
often excuses for maintaining resources in inefficient lines of
production.

Current unemployment, labor restraining, and

other social programs minimize hardships to the labor force

resulting from the change. Little capital loss would likely occur
because of the high rate of normal obsolescense due to technological

change. The vital industries argument is no longer applicable,
since, in case of all-our war under modern conditions, no

industry is secure regardless of where it is located. All-out
wars are likely to be of shorter duration than formerly.

Furthermore, freer trade practices may reduce the chances of

war.

The United States should take the lead in dropping

trade barriers and adopting a consistent trade policy.

Real

accomplishments will require more than the rhetoric of recent
decades. We should move toward the elimination of programs
which reduce world confidence in us as a supplier and buyer

of merchandise. There is no point in reducing trade barriers
only in sectors where no potential trade exists. We must be

willing to reduce barriers that permit increases in imports.
This will require opposition to the power of inefficient producer

groups who have made their short-run interest paramount to the

welfare of the nation. We must be willing to dismantle our

inefficient production controls in agriculture, thereby assuring




- 17-

foreign consumers that our farm products will be available
at competitive prices. A move toward free trade is a move toward
less Government control of prices and production and greater

reliance on market forces for resource adjustment.

These moves toward fewer restrictions are counter to
general legislation which temporarily aids the few but reduces
national welfare. Their adoption can reverse the current trend

of domestic industry protection, increase exports of agriculture
and other efficient industries, and improve the welfare of both

our own citizens and those of the rest of the world.