View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

INFLATION: CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES
Remarks by
Darryl R. Francis, President
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
Before the
Joint Seminar of
The Canadian Council of Financial Analysts and
The Toronto Council of Financial Analysts
Toronto, Canada
November 18, 1975

It is a pleasure to be here in Toronto and to share with
you my views on inflation. This is a subject whose popularity has
fluctuated with cyclical fluctuations in business activity: it is debated
during upswings only to recede into oblivion during downswings. Yet,
in my opinion, it is a subject which should be analyzed at all times since
it is during downswings that the seeds of inflation are sown.
You have suggested that I speak on the monetarist view of
inflation. While the framework within which I analyze the causes and
consequences of inflation is of the monetarist variety, I think I should
warn you that what I consider most important does not necessarily
represent the view of all monetarists. In order to put things into
perspective, I should like to outline this framework of analysis.
The impact of an increase in the total money stock when it
is not accompanied by a similar increase in output has a predictable effect




-2on behavior. Individuals will attempt to divest themselves of what they
consider to be their excess money balances by bidding for other, nonmoney assets. As the prices of these assets rise, additional output
is stimulated. But such increases in output are limited by the
growth of resources. Expansion of the money stock which is maintained
at a rate greater than the trend growth rate of output produces only a
transitory increase in production, while it leads to a permanent rise
in the rate of increase of prices. Evidence for these results is not
difficult to find. Rates of growth of money and rates of increase in
the price level closely parallel each other when viewed as long-term
trends.
A great deal of evidence has been amassed showing that
an increase above the trend growth of money which persists for at
least two quarters will lead to a rise in the rate of output which is
quite short-lived. However, as the rate of production returns to its
trend level, the rate of inflation increases. We have observed a symmetrical situation for declines in the rate of money growth. Such
declines create transitory recessions that are replaced by lower inflation
rates in six to eight quarters.
But if we accept this relationship between money supply and
the price level, why has the money stock been allowed to grow in such a
way as to produce persistent and accelerating inflation punctuated by
occasional recessions? Despite many arguments to the contrary, it is




-3clear that central banks can control the money supply within a very
narrow range over a time period of a quarter or more. Have they
produced this growth pattern through some nefarious design? Have
they merely been incompetent? I, for one, believe that neither is
the case and that we must look to our political and social aspirations
for the root causes of the economic dilemma upon whose horns we
sit so very uncomfortably.
To do this, I shall confine my observations to the
American experience, simply because I am most familiar with
the trails of the United States economy, I am quite sure, however,
that parallels can be drawn for Canada and many other Western
industrialized nations which face the same problems of inflation
and unemployment.
For many years, government spending and the size of the
government sector have expanded at an increasing rate. Since 1950
total annual government expenditures have risen by about $454 billion,
with $328 billion of that having occurred in the past ten years. This
growth was spurred by an underlying philosophy which contends that
greater direct government activity is the best if not the only way to
achieve certain economic and social goals. So let us consider the claims
of those who espouse this philosophy and examine their validity. Has
this spending accomplished what it set out to do? Was it indeed the "best"
way? And finally, has it had other consequences, too important to be
termed merely "side effects", which have imposed high costs on us all?



-4One of the oldest arguments in favor of increased
governmental incursion into economic life holds that fiscal policy
is the proper, indeed the necessary, tool to stimulate the economy
and combat unemployment.

In addition to the automatic stabilizing

effects of tax and transfer payment policy, it has been alleged that the
government should introduce significant spending efforts when the
activity of the private sector is inadequate for full employment,
however defined. And it is argued that this spending should engender
deficits, since financing through higher taxes would reduce private
purchasing power and frustrate the attempt to expand total demand.
Historically, government deficit spending has had no
stimulative effects except insofar as it was accompanied by monetary
expansion. Thus the stimulation desired could have been accomplished
directly through monetary expansion without the government encroachment into the private sector that is inherent in fiscal policy. More
important, we know that the stimulus is only transitory — that the
output effects of excessive money growth are quickly dissipated and
that the only lasting result is ever aggravated inflation. Consider
our actual performance. Have we reduced fluctuations in output and
employment through the wide use of fiscal deficits and surpluses?
Obviously the answer is no. Since the inception of these policies in
the early thirties the frequency and magnitude of economic fluctuations
have not differed significantly from those prior to that period.




-5A second popular argument, and on the surface a very
persuasive one, states that it is the proper function of government
to employ those resources, particularly labor, which the private
sector is unwilling to employ. Presumably, the whole society benefits
from such programs at no cost, since additional production is being
provided by those who were previously contributing nothing. This is a
seductive argument which merits careful examination. Surely we
must agree that private enterprise will always take advantage of the
opportunity to employ resources which it expects to use profitably.
When some resources are not so employed, it means only that their
services are not worth the price attached to them.
For the cause of this

situation, we must again look

to the influence of government. Hedged in as we have become by
laws requiring the payment of minimum wages and "equal pay for
equal work", we have seen more and more of the labor force become
unemployable. And when the government puts them to work, one
basic result is the same. To the extent that these people are being
paid more than the market decrees, there is a real transfer of wealth
to them from the rest of society. Real output may be greater, but much
of the increase in their welfare comes not from their new productivity
but from the rest of us.




To gauge the accomplishments of these policies,

-6whatever their

distributive effects, we need only to look at what

has occurred. In the face of many job-creation programs, we find
that output growth has risen at approximately a constant trend rate
since 1946, irrespective of the rate of government spending. And
in the same period, unemployment fluctuated around an average
of 4.9 percent until its recent increase.
An argument of more recent vintage maintains that the
goods and services provided by the private sector in response to society's
demands do not respond to the so-called true needs of society. It
follows from this that the government should divert resources to the
satisfaction of these needs. More and more programs have been
enacted in areas ranging from health care to cultural pursuits.
Whether they have increased our welfare is highly questionable.
We have obtained these services only by sacrificing other things we
would have chosen for ourselves. But in their efforts to make it
appear that there is indeed such a thing as a free lunch, our elected
officials have increased government expenditures without attempting
a corresponding rise in taxes. As a result, monetary growth and
inflation have provided the means of transferring control of resources
from private hands into the hands of bureaucrats who, it would seem,
know our needs better than we ourselves do.




Finally, implicit in all the arguments of the advocates of

-7interference is the assumption that an expanded government role
in economic activity will,and should, redistribute income in the
direction of some notion of greater equality. Whether this redistribution is indeed desirable is an argument which has probably existed
since the first two humans met. I will not attempt to make any
enlightening contributions to that debate. It is fair to ask, however,
what has been achieved. In spite of the expanding role of government
activity since World War I I , the distribution of income has changed
very little. The income group representing the lowest twenty percent
received 5 percent of total income in 1947 and 5.5 percent in 1971 while
the share of the highest fifth fell from 43 percent in 1947 to 41.6 percent
in 1971. This can hardly be considered a significant accomplishment,
especially in view of the costs incurred.
These proposals to improve our socio-economic welfare
have, through design or through ignorance, overlooked the problem
of financing the additional expenditures. The basic issue in the
financing of government programs is that resources have to be
transferred from one sector of the economy to another. This can
be accomplished in only three ways. One is to tax current private
consumption and investment, that is, to increase taxes. The second
is to tax future private consumption by incurring a deficit and selling
government securities to the private sector. This method moves




-8resources immediately by reducing the purchasing power of security
buyers only but ultimately spreads the burden to all taxpayers when
the securities must be redeemed. And the third is to finance the deficit
by indirectly selling securities to the central bank which buys them
with newly created money.
When deficits are financed by the sale of government
securities, the attendant additions to the demand for credit must
exert upward pressure on the interest rate. Aside from directly
discouraging private consumption and investment spending, higher
interest rates, like taxes, are politically undesirable. Hence, these
first two methods have typically not been favored. If the central bank
must submit to political pressure to contain increases in interest
rates, the solution is clear. The monetary authority is compelled to
buy at least a portion of the government issues from the private sector.
This action undoubtedly mitigates the initial pressure on interest
rates but at the same time it stimulates money growth and the ensuing
inflation leads eventually to higher interest rates.
The process I have outlined here is not hypothetical; we
have seen it in operation over the greater part of the past thirty years.
Since 1950, the federal government's debt has grown by $176 billion. In
that same period, the Federal Reserve System's holdings of debt have
grown by $68 billion and the money stock has increased by $176 billion.
Meanwhile, proponents of deficit spending as a stimulus have proudly
pointed to their successes as they saw output and employment increase -however briefly ~ with each new deficit and considered the attendant



-9inflation a small price to pay for the short-run achievements.
To sum up.- there is no convincing evidence that increased
government spending, with its accompanying deficits, has accomplished
its stated social goals. There is no evidence whatsoever that it is the
most efficient way to pursue these goals or even that any benefits have
exceeded the costs involved. On the other hand, there is overwhelming
evidence that it has led to our persistent inflation. I can therefore say
unequivocally not only that the causes of inflation are identifiable, but
that they can be eliminated. That they should be eliminated becomes
clear once we consider the consequences of inflation.
One of these is that it can inspire monetary policies that
reinforce inflationary pressures. A closely-related policy effect is
the recurrent effort to reduce inflation drastically which produces
recession.
I have already discussed the fact that increased government
borrowing exerts an upward pressure on interest rates. When the
central bank is then called upon to monetize a part of the debt in
order to counteract that pressure, inflation ensues. Each time this
process has been pursued interest rates did not stay down for long.
As people become aware of inflation and the expanded money supply,
they expect prices to rise further.

Interest rates rise as inflationary

premiums are incorporated into them. The central bank again attempts




-10to resist by increasing the money supply and the whole cycle is renewed.
When the concern for inflation becomes greater than that
for interest rates, there are periodic attempts to reduce the rate of price
rise by sharp reductions in the rate of money growth. These reductions
have been responsible for most of our recessions and increases in
unemployment.
The less visible consequences of inflation are perhaps even
more ominous. An inflation which is not fully anticipated brings about
a redistribution of wealth from creditors to debtors. When people see
this occurring, they will bend their efforts toward protecting themselves
from these effects.
Another aspect of this wealth transfer is the loss which
inflation imposes on all holders of money. This leads all economic
units, both individual consumers and firms, to try to maintain smaller
money balances and, as it becomes a more costly productive resource,
to make greater attempts to economize on its use. But these attempts
require the use of substitute resources, not the least of which are
the time and effort involved in devising alternatives to money transactions.
I think you can easily visualize where this leads; we are all aware of the
inefficiencies of bilateral barter transactions. Money is a useful good
which permits increased specialization in production and any decrease
in that specialization necessarily leads to a reduction in output. The
recorded instances of very rapid rates of inflation in Europe and South




-IIAmerica convincingly illustrate this fact.
A major consequence of the inflation that we have
experienced is the increased uncertainty which has had an impact
on every aspect of our economic life. There are really two factors at
work here. First, when a society has come to expect a fluctuating
inflation rate which cannot be accurately predicted, long-term financial
contracts become increasingly risky to both lenders and borrowers;
hence, they become increasingly rare. I am sure you are all aware
that since the early thirties the average time to maturity of debt
obligations has decreased substantially. Greater uncertainty - that is,
greater risk — as to the financing of long-term investment leads to
reluctance to undertake such investment. As a result, productive
capacity is lowered and future consumption possibilities are decreased.
Another source of increased uncertainty, and one whose
effects become immediately apparent, is that we have been led to expect
the government periodically to attempt to combat inflation in ways and
at times that we cannot predict. Many of these techniques, such as
wage and price controls, and reactions to them can, and already have,
produced serious distortions in the economic process.
An excellent example is the phenomenon observed in the
American automobile industry in the past year. Faced with poor sales,
manufacturers reacted, not with straightforward price cuts, but
instead by instituting elaborate rebate programs which were more




-12costly both for them and for the buyers. The only reason which I can
see for this extraordinary maneuver is that they feared the imminent
reimposition of price controls and wished to insure themselves the
greatest possible flexibility in the face of this threat.
It is the long-term, often slowly working and hardly visible
effects of inflation, which, in my opinion, represent the greatest danger.
They lower the standard of living; they undermine the fiber of our political,
economic and social system. And because they are not readily apparent,
inflation frequently is considered to be of secondary importance to more
visible, but transitory economic problems.
Our current situation affords us a perfect example of the
problems I have outlined. Although it seems that we have reached the
bottom of the recession and that recovery is well underway, unemployment rates remain relatively high and some industries stilt suffer low
rates of demand. As recovery progresses and inventory liquidation
ceases it is reasonable to expect that private borrowing will increase;
this is bound to exert an upward pressure on interest rates.
Now, how will the government react to this combination
of circumstances? Will it again consciously disregard the dangers of
inflation, addressing itself to the short-run unemployment problem with
traditionally ill-conceived and ineffective spending programs? These
will engender massive government demands on the credit market, adding




-13to the push on interest rates. To combat this, money growth must
accelerate, bringing with it greater inflation in a year or so and still
higher interest rates.
What then? Will aggravated inflation be permitted or
will we subject the economy to another recession? Or shall we,
alternatively, break from our traditional response, allow the economy
to continue the progress it has begun without creating new problems
by attempts to accelerate the progress or to depress the interest rate.
These are the alternatives which face policymakers.
In conclusion, let me restate my fundamental propositions.
First, it is quite evident that inflation is the result of excessive monetary
growth and that demand-induced recessions are caused by sharp downward deviations from this growth path. Second, monetary growth in
excess of resource growth has been the most dependable result of government deficits and the desire to mask the resource transfers that these
deficits are assumed to entail. Third, deficits have typically arisen from
attempts to change socio-economic conditions, attempts which have, just
as typically, been futile.
Solutions are readily available, but they require a time
horizon which extends beyond the next election and beyond the shortterm outlook and narrow analytical base of many economists. The basic
requirement is the realization that all social and economic programs
entail a cost which must be paid in one form or another. If this




-14realization becomes prevalent and if the costs become clear, there will
be no need for central bank financing of huge government deficits.
Neither will there be a necessity for maintaining interest rates at some
predetermined level. In short, there will be no need to fool the electorate.
This would free the monetary authorities to control the growth of the
money stock, keeping it at a rate consistent with the rate of growth of
output and eliminating the major cause of both inflation and demandinduced recession.
Meanwhile, in the current circumstances, it is perfectly
feasible to permit interest rates to seek their market-determined level
and to start a very gradual deceleration in the trend rate of money
growth. It may take a year or two or three, but inflation can be reduced
without the emergence of recession. But again, a necessary condition
is the discipline imposed by public knowledge that any service provided
by the government must be paid for by the public itself and must be paid
immediately.
Perhaps such knowledge will reduce demands for governmental
services, or at least eliminate the political pressures to pretend that these
services can be provided free of charge. And in my opinion, these pretentions
are the major impulses which set in motion the causes of inflation.