View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

GOVERNMENT DEFICITS, MONETARY POLICY, AND INFLATION
Remarks by
Darryl R. Francis, President
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
before the
Summer Workshop of the University of Wisconsin
LaCrosse, Wisconsin
July 9, 1975

Early this year President Ford announced one of the most
ambitious programs of fiscal action ever undertaken in this country. The
program consists of (I) a substantial rise in Federal expenditures, and
(2) a series of tax changes that are designed to lower the average tax
rate in calendar 1975. These fiscal actions are projected to result in
a massive budget deficit at least through mid-1976. Although there is
very little disagreement that current economic policies should be aimed
at expanding economic activity, considerable disagreement has arisen
about the effects of the massive deficit on financial markets and the
future course of inflation.
I, for one, find very little evidence to indicate that deficit
spending per se produces lasting stimulative effects on the economy.
The longer-run effects of deficit spending, as I will indicate later on,
do not appear to have increased the longer-run growth of output of
the economy. If anything, they may have decreased productive
efficiency, thereby lowering long-run growth of output from what it




-2would have been otherwise. I believe it is very important that we
should be concerned now with the long-run effects of the proposed
massive deficit and with the mechanism through which the deficit
may affect not only our standard of living but also our freedom of
choice.
From early 1973 through the first quarter of this year,
the U.S. economy moved progressively into the worst of all possible
worlds—falling real output, rising unemployment, and accelerating
inflation. This was an abrupt change from what had occurred earlier.
From the end of the recession in 1970 to early 1973, the economy had
showed remarkable progress, with real output growing at an average
annual rate of 6.7 percent, unemployment falling to 5 percent of the
labor force, and prices rising at slightly less than a 4 percent annual
rate.
In contrast, from the first quarter of 1973 to the fourth
quarter of 1974, inflation accelerated with a vengeance, averaging
about a 10 percent annual rate. Since late in 1974 it has moderated,
but continues to be very rapid relative to previous periods. Real output
growth slowed to about a 2 percent rate during 1973, and then declined
at a 6 percent rate from the end of 1973 to early 1975. During the past
year unemployment rose to a very high rate by post-World War 11
standards. Given this steadily deteriorating situation with respect to




-3production and unemployment, it is not surprising that the
Administration has launched a very aggressive program of fiscal
action.
As a central banker, my concern with these fiscal
developments stems from my realization that fiscal actions and
monetary policy cannot be put into separate compartments. Spending
and taxing decisions by the Government have a major influence on
the type of economic environment within which monetary policy is
formulated. The Federal Reserve has to accept the fact that the
Federal Government will be selling a massive amount of new securities
in fiscal 1976. Therefore, I would like to share with you some of my
thoughts on the problems that this large deficit financing is likely
to create for monetary policy.
The Government could finance the deficit by selling bonds
to the public, using the money received from the sale of bonds to buy
goods and services and to make transfer payments. After the Government
has completed its expenditures, the public would hold more Government
bonds and the same amount of money as before. Under these assumptions
the upward pressure on interest rates on Government bonds could be
expected to be greater than otherwise.
Alternatively, the Federal Reserve System might increase
its holdings of Government debt. Although the Federal Reserve does




-4not buy new issues directly from the Treasury, except to roll-over
Treasury securities it already holds in its portfolio, it may, through
open market operations, buy Government securities that are held
by the public.
The effect on the growth of the money supply is essentially
the same in either case. When the Federal Reserve buys Government
securities, bank reserves increase and, hence, the money supply
increases. To the extent that Federal Reserve purchases reduce the
increase in the stock of Government securities that are held by the
public, upward pressures on interest rates are initially mitigated by
these central bank purchases. I emphasize the word initially because,
to the extent that such purchases result in an acceleration in the
growth of money, and subsequently raise the trend rate of inflation,
interest rates will be higher later on.
Government deficits, by themselves, do not necessarily
lead to increases in the rate of growth of the money stock, nor do they
cause inflation. The inflationary impact of a deficit depends primarily
upon the extent to which the Federal Reserve monetizes the deficit
through open market purchases and the extent to which the corresponding
growth in the money stock causes aggregate demand to exceed productive
capacity. Looking at the results for two time periods, 1952-62 and
1969-74 shown in Table I, we can see this process in operation.




-5One major difference between these periods is the average
annual increase in net Government debt. During the most recent
five-year period the average annual increase in net Government debt
was about 5 times as great as in the ten-year period 1952-62— 13 billion
dollars per year versus 2.6 billion dollars per year. In the first period
the dollar change in the money stock was approximately equal to the
change in net Government borrowing.
Over the last five years, however, the money stock increased
about 8 billion dollars more than the increase in the net debt. The
Federal Reserve System purchased an equivalent of about 40 percent
of the increase in net Government debt over the last five years, as
compared to about 25 percent over the ten-year period 1952-62.
Consequently, the money stock grew at an average annual rate of about
6 percent over the last five years, compared to a less than 2 percent
rate over 1952-62.
What was the net result, on average, of larger deficits
and a more rapid growth rate of money? Referring again to Table 1,
we see that real output grew at about the same rate in both periods
and the unemployment rate averaged about the same. The really
marked difference was in the rate of inflation and in the average level
of interest rates. During the last five years inflation averaged almost
6 percent, compared to 2 percent in the previous period. Long-term




TABLE I
Relationship of Government Deficits, Federal Reserve Holdings of Debt,
Money Stock, Economic Activity, and Interest Rates
(Dollar amount in billions)
Change i n ;
Period

Deficit

Net Government
Debt 1/

Fed Holdings
of Securities 2 /

Annual Rates of Change
Real
Money
Prices 3 /
Output
Stock

Money
Stock

1

1 1.8%

3.0%

1.9%

6.2%

2.5%

5.8%

1

Interest Rates
r
1

Unemployment
Rate 4/

, 3-Month
Corporate
r Treasury B i l l 4 /
Aaa
4

1952-1962
Level Change
Avg. per year

-*1.7

$26.1

$ 6.6

$24.5

2.6

0.7

2.5

$64.4

$25.7

$72.2

12.9

5.1

14.4

5.1%

2.36%

3.77%

5.4%

5.93%

7.73%

1969-1974
Level Change
Avg. per year

—

-$13.0

'

i

Excludes debt held by U. S. Government Agencies and Trust Funds.

2/
-' Federal Reserve holdings of securities include only those securities included in the national debt. It excludes Federal Reserve holdings
of Government agency securities, and acceptances which are included in Federal Reserve Credit.
~4/l GNF Price Deflator

~ Average for rates during 1953-1962 and for 1970-1974.




-6interest rates were more than twice as high, on average, as in the
previous period. The historical experience during these two periods
seems to indicate that a substantial increase in deficit spending,
accompanied by a somewhat larger creation of money, has raised
the rate of inflation which correspondingly raised nominal interest
rates.
I do not believe that the intention of the Federal Reserve
over the last 5 years was to create an amount of money equal to the
substantial rise in the net Government debt. However, System
actions have been directed toward resisting "substantial" movements
in interest rates, and a significant increase in the amount of Government
securities sold in the market means that interest rates on Government
bonds tend to rise, given that other factors remain unchanged.
If the Federal Reserve attempts to resist these upward
pressures on interest rates, then it has to accelerate its purchase
of Government securities. Consequently, bank reserves, monetary
base, and the money supply grow more rapidly. The more rapid
growth in money leads to increased demands for goods, services, and
credit and, eventually, to a more rapid rate of increase in prices. The
increase in prices, in turn, puts further upward pressures on interest
rates. A cumulative process develops. It is precisely through this
channel that the link between the size of the deficit, rapid money
growth and, hence, inflation develops.




-7Let me now turn to a consideration of some of the factors
likely to influence the path of interest rates over the next year. As
soon as we start to discuss the possible effects of such large deficits
on financial markets and interest rates, we rapidly sail into uncharted
waters. The results of one's analysis depend crucially upon the
assumptions one makes about economic recovery and the behavior
of commercial banks.
However, let us begin with a few statements with which
all of us should agree. First, as a result of the Government selling
enormous amounts of securities, interest rates will be higher than
they would have been in the absence of such Government demands
on the credit market. Second, if the recovery in economic activity
materializes, and almost all forecasters are predicting it will, there
will be a rise in the demand for credit from the private sector. Third,
as a general rule, commercial banks prefer making business loans
to buying Government securities. Fourth, the Federal Reserve has
traditionally tried to resist any tendency for market interest rates
to move sharply up or down.
Before I continue, I would like to make a distinction
between fundamental forces affecting the level of interest rates and
short-term factors that appear to have been influential in recent
movements of short-term interest rates. Two basic factors that I




-8believe currently underlie the level of interest rates are: (I) the
underlying trend rate of inflation, and (2) the changing composition
of Government spending.
Given the past rates of monetary expansion, our research
indicates that the underlying trend rate of inflation is still in the
neighborhood of about 5 or 6 percent. Since this trend rate has
been established over a period of as long as perhaps five years, the
substantial slowing in the growth rate of money since about mid-1973
has only started to reduce it.
I believe there is a further fundamental force that has
been operating over the last few years to raise the average level of
interest rates. This is a subtle factor which has perhaps been
overlooked. To understand it one has to realize that interest rates
reflect the time preference of decisionmakers in the economy. The
interest rate indicates how much future consumption must be given
up to increase present consumption. If people develop a stronger
preference for current consumption, then they must be offered a
higher price to persuade them to forego current consumption. In
other words, the interest rate will be higher to the extent that people
prefer to consume now rather than in the future.
In recent years an increasing proportion of Government
expenditures has gone into transfer payments. In the period 1955 to
I960, transfer payments accounted for about 23 percent of Government




-9expenditures; over the next five years they averaged about 26 percent.
In the last five years this proportion has risen to about 35 percent.
Transfer payments have become the growth sector of Government
expenditures.
These types of expenditures by the Government do not
reflect a demand by the Government for goods and services such as
highways, hospitals, schools, and so on. They result mainly in
income redistribution and ultimately appear as an increased demand
by recipients for short-lived assets; that is, current consumption
expenditures. In effect, the Government is mandating a shift in
time preference from longer-lived assets, such as capital goods,
toward current consumption. Consequently, interest rates—the price
of consuming in the present rather than the future—are higher than
they would have been without this mandated shift in time preference.
The combined influence of accelerating inflation and
rising transfer payments is clearly evident in the behavior of longterm interest rates since about 1966, the point at which I would date
the inception of both of these factors. As shown in Chart 1, long-term
interest rates have generally moved steadily upward since 1965. The
only period when this upward trend was halted was during and following
the 1970 recession. For a short period of time the rate of growth of
prices slowed, partly due to the reduction in money growth in 1969 and
partly due to the temporary cosmetic effect of wage and price controls
in late 1971. In 1973 long-term interest rates began a further



Chart I

Interest Rates
Pe

Perrcenf
15
14
13
12

[\

11
10
9

yi

s

i

l

i f*4

J

I r

\

1

J

..... r ^ - i

Corp orate / aa Bonds

5

Y^

j

:f

^
•j-ecSa^

^

**

3

:Oi

^/*~'

2

+fj\

nl

"1

1950

A

~^\

f
\y«\

]

/ /

f

vA^i

<f\

f

i >>>

r

*

^

^-v/^j

i

V
M

«fonfb ' reasur r Bills.
. . 3-1

A * \A8,

1 /n

i t

\

f
4

^V\^J-KA/

6

1

I

.,iu\ i

w

7

1

n

! 4- to 6-Monlh 1
,'rime Commercial Paper

r\

1

y

V
i

V

/A
'
f\

\A\] r^^J

I'd

1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 197

latest data plotted. June




Prepared by Federal Reserve Bank of St Lou

-10rapid upward movement and then declined slightly near the end
of 1974.
However, even after the substantial slowing in
real output that we have experienced, long-term rates remain about
twice as high as they were in the period 1950-1964. Also, it is
interesting to observe that although the current slowdown in
economic activity is longer and more pronounced than 1970, long-term
rates today are still above the peaks they had reached in 1970.
Let me now turn to what I consider to be some
short-term factors currently affecting the level of interest rates. The
behavior of short-term interest rates over recent months has reflected
a substantial decline in the private sector's demand for short-term
credit. Part of this decrease has been offset by the Government's
increased demand for credit. On balance, however, private demand
for credit has fallen enough to result in lower short-term interest
rates.
The decline in private credit demands has been
especially prominent at large commercial banks, where the outstanding
volume of business loans has fallen by about 12 billion dollars since
mid-December. The fall in the demand for bank credit by businesses
has resulted in a sharp drop in the prime rate, and the rate of return
on Government securities has thus become moreattractiveto banks.




-IIAs a result, banks have substantially increased their holdings of
securities, as is usually the case in periods when economic activity
slows.
As economic recovery progresses, however, the
banks should face a renewed surge in demand for credit. Past
behavior of banks surely indicates that under these conditions we
should not expect a continued substantial rise in the proportion of
Government securities held in bank portfolios. For example, during
the previous period of economic expansion, from the first quarter of
1971 to the first quarter of 1973 bank credit grew by about 130 billion dollars,
but banks' holdings of Government securities increased by less than 2
billion dollars.
The gist of this discussion is that, for long-term
interest rates to decline much further, the growth rate of money would
have to be at a rate below 6 percent, but under developing circumstances
this will be a difficult target to attain. Also, shortly after the economy
begins to recover there will be considerable pressure for a substantial
upward movement in short-term interest rates.
As the recovery progresses, it does not seem likely that the
Treasury will continue to be able to sell Treasury bills at close to a 5
percent yield. Banks will first reduce the rate at which they add
Government securities to their portfolios, and may eventually reduce
their holdings of Government securities. The rise in short-rates
will likely spread across the




-12spectrum of all interest rates, with upward pressures developing on
the Federal funds rate as banks bid for reserves to expand bank credit.
Chairman Burns has announced that the Federal
Open Market Committee's desired growth range for money is 5 to 7 1/2 percent
from March 1975 to March 1976. One of my greatest concerns about
the enormous Government deficit is that the public and political attention paid to market interest rates might make the short-run trade-off,
between achieving the monetary targets versus resisting interest rate
increases, especially unpleasant.
If the Federal Reserve were to resist any tendency for interest
rates to rise markedly, as has been the case in the past, then the growth
of the money stock would accelerate rapidly. Unfortunately, the
pattern seems to have been that sharp rises in interest rates have
been associated with more rapid money growth and sharp declines
in interest rates have been associated with substantial reductions in
the growth of money.
To put the dilemma faced by the monetary authorities
into perspective, let me give you a few numbers to illustrate what I
think would be a growth rate of the monetary base consistent with
the long range target, and what this seems to imply for the growth of
bank credit and the amount of Government debt that must be absorbed
by the nonbank public. These numbers should not be taken as indicative




-13of exact projections, but only as representing the magnitude of the
problems that we face.
In order to hold the growth of the money stock at a
5 to 7 1/2 percent rate from March 1975 to March 1976, I would estimate
that we could permit, at most, about a 7 to 8 percent growth of the
monetary base over this period. This translates into only about a 9
billion dollar increase. If member bank borrowings rise from their
current very low levels, and if some open market purchases occur in
agency securities and acceptences, this implies the Federal Reserve
could buy only around 8 billion dollars of the increase in Government
debt. A rise of 9 billion dollars in the monetary base translates into
the neighborhood of a 55 to 60 billion dollar rise in bank credit.
The next major question is how much of this rise
in bank credit occurs as increased purchases of Government securities
by banks. If we assume that bank loans grow only 5 percent from
March to March, an historically very low rate, then this would mean
that bank holdings of Government securities could rise by about 35
billion dollars, about a 60 percent increase. It also assumes that
banks would not increase their holdings of any other type of securities
such as municipal bonds.
Combining purchases of the Federal Reserve and the
commercial banks, this would amount to about 45 billion dollars of Government
securities. This would leave on the order of 35 billion dollars of new




-14Government securities to be absorbed by the nonbank public over the
period from March 1975 through March 1976. By contrast, the
nonbank public acquired, on average, only 10 billion dollars of Government debt over the five-year period from the end of 1969 to the
end of 1974.
Given the enormous size of the projected increase in the
Government debt, and given the concern that substantially increased
interest rates are undesirable, I believe we face a severe challenge in
the conduct of monetary policy over the next couple of years. I believe
the challenge can be met. However, in order for us to avoid a substantial, and what I consider excessive, growth of money, there
must be a break in the historical pattern of the Federal Reserve acquiring
an increasing proportion of the national debt. Interest rates must be
permitted to rise to whatever level is necessary to restrict the growth
of the monetary base over the period from March 1975 to March of
next year to no more than 8 percent. Each increase in the amount of
deficit spending makes the problem more difficult.
The upshot of this discussion and of the tentative estimates of near-term developments is that we are faced with some unpleasant
choices. The built-in inflation and the composition of Government
spending indicate a higher level of interest rates in the immediate future
than that which we experienced in previous periods when the trend growth of
money was much slower. The projected huge Government deficit and




-15the expected increase in private borrowing suggest rising short-term
interest rates. Past experience convincingly shows that the pressure on
monetary authorities has been to resist increases in interest rates
and the probability is high that these pressures will continue.
If short-term interest rates are permitted to rise now
and the Federal Reserve maintains a reasonable growth of the money
stock, the economy will still revive, and inflation and interest rates
should stabilize in the long run. But if we were to resist short-run
tendencies for interest rates to rise, then I am afraid that we would
have to brace ourselves for more severe inflation and much higher
interest rates a year or two from now. In such event, I would not be
surprised to see pressures for wage, price, and credit controls again
rear their ugly heads. Associated with this would be even further
intervention by the Government in our daily business affairs.
The real long-run solution, in my opinion, lies in achieving
and maintaining a balanced Government budget. As we have seen,
increased Government spending has not resulted in higher average
output or a reduced unemployment rate, but has subjected the economy
to inflation and high interest rates. Until this fact is understood, 1
am afraid we might be toying with the demise of free enterprise, economic
and political freedom, and a drastic reduction in our standard of living.