View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

THE FLEXIBLE EXCHANGE RATE: GAIN OR LOSS TO THE
UNITED STATES?
Speech by Darryl R. Francis, President
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
to the
World Trade Club of St. Louis, Inc.
Bel-Air East, St. Louis, Missouri
Thursday evening, October 28, 1971
I am pleased to have this opportunity to
discuss with you some of the current issues in
international trade. I am particularly interested
in this topic since the recent decision by President
Nixon to suspend dollar convertibility into gold is
eliciting high-pitched discussion in the world
press and, even more important, this decision has a
serious impact on the welfare of all consumers in the
world.
Although international trade represents
only four or five per cent of the United States
Gross National Product, its impact on domestic
welfare is much greater, and the settlement
of current problems and uncertainties will be felt
by all of us for a long time to come. As far as I
am concerned, the agreement on an international
payments mechanism is of far greater importance
than the ten per cent surcharge, and consequently I




-2will address my remarks to that portion of the new
international economic policy.
First, I will discuss the functioning of
the international payments system; second, the historical events leading to the current situation;
third, the alternative solutions available.
Finally, I will indicate my choice of an international payments mechanism.
The Benefits from Trading Internationally.
The United States can produce virtually
any commodity and service that it currently consumes. Why, then,do we engage in international
trade and incur the risks and crises that have plagued
us for the past fifty years? The answer, of course,
is that international trade, like domestic trade,
is profitable. It is profitable in the sense that it
increases the welfare of trading countries.
The reason we buy an imported commodity
is simply that we can purchase it cheaper
abroad than we can produce it domestically. We pay
for our imports by selling goods and services to
foreigners who will accept them only if our goods
are cheaper than the same goods produced by them.
Therefore, the citizens of both trading




-3countries, given their resources, can consume more
goods and services than they could in the absence
of such trade.
The reasons for the relative price differentials are varied - it may be productive
efficiency or it may be domestic demand conditions.
What is important is that the price of the
delivered foreign commodity or service is lower
than the price of the same commodity produced at
home. Therein lies the benefit from international
trade. If such benefit does not exist, trade will
not take place. Any artificial restrictions which
lower this price differential reduce the amount of
international trade and therefore the welfare gains
that may accrue.
The same reasoning applies to international capital movements. We buy foreign capital
goods or foreign securities only if they promise a
higher rate of return than domestic ones. In that
sense, a given amount of resources increases our
income and welfare. The country selling the
securities benefits by attracting a scarce resource
to facilitate the efficiency of the productive
process.




-4What is important to remember throughout
any discussion of international trade is that
benefits accrue from our ability to consume more.
That is, from imports of goods, services and
securities.
The Mechanism of International Payments
Since gains from trade derive from imports,
why don't we keep importing as much as possible and
forget about exports, reserve balances, and various
exchange problems? Like everything else, imports
must be paid for, and exports are the ultimate means
of payment. But since the barter system is extremely
inefficient in individual transactions, we avoid the
item by item matching of imports and exports by
using the international payments mechanism, just as
we avoid the matching of goods and services in
domestic transactions with the use of money.
To demonstrate international payments,
let's assume that I buy a Japanese radio for $30.
I write a check on my bank and send it to the
Japanese exporter who deposits the check in his bank
and gets Japanese money for it. If the Bank of
Tokyo can find an importer who wants $30 to buy




-5something in the United States, it will sell the
draft to him and my $30 finds its way into the
account of a U. S. exporter in a U. S. bank. Under
these circumstances, an import was offset by an
export, the quantity of dollars supplied was equal
to the quantity demanded, and the price of the
dollar, the exchange rate, remained the same.
But what if the Bank of Tokyo cannot
immediately find an importer who wants to buy U. S.
goods and services? What can it do with my $30
check? At this point we must specify the international payments mechanism that is used by the
United States and Japan. There are three main
payments systems that have been used: the gold
standard, the dollar or sterling exchange standard,
and a flexible exchange standard.
On a true gold standard, the Bank of
Tokyo will sell my check to the Japanese Central
Bank who, in turn, will buy $30 worth of gold from
the U. S. Treasury. Thus, my import of a radio was
matched by an export of gold. The exchange rate,
which is fixed in terms of gold, does not change.
If we are on a dollar exchange standard,
as existed until recently, the price of a dollar
is fixed in terms of gold and the prices of all




-6other currencies are fixed in terms of the dollar.
In order for the exchange rate to remain constant,
the supply of dollars created by my purchase must
be matched by an equivalent quantity demanded.
Since central banks are committed to maintenance of
a fixed exchange rate, in the absence of private
demanders of dollars they must buy and hold the $30,
thus increasing their foreign reserves.
A flexible exchange standard implies that
the price of the dollar will be determined by
market forces without official intervention. In
this instance, the Bank of Tokyo would offer my $30
on the exchange market. If there are buyers of U. S.
goods and services at existing prices, the $30 will
be purchased by them and the exchange rate will not
change. But if these importers view U. S. prices as
being too high, they will offer less foreign currency
for my $30 check and the transaction will be
consummated only at the lower price of the dollar.
Thus my import is still paid by an export, but only
when accompanied by a change in the exchange rate.
To summarize this illustration, my import
of the radio was paid for with either a gold export,
a U. S. liability that a foreign central bank is
willing to hold, or an export of U. S. goods and
services.




-7It should be clear, however, that an
excess of imports over exports can be continued
under a gold standard only as long as our gold
supply lasts. Similarly, under the dollar exchange
standard the excess can continue only as long as
foreigners are willing to supply us with goods and
services in exchange for dollar accounts in U.S.
banks. Since we desire imports, what is there
to prevent the United States from exhausting
its gold stock or prevent an ever increasing
accumulation of dollar balances by foreign central
banks? In other words, is there an adjustment
mechanism which prevents permanent imbalance in
trade and possible breakdown of international
economic relations? Let us examine the adjustment
process in each of the three payments systems I have
outlined.
The gold standard, if permitted to function, would cause an export of gold in our
Japanese radio example. A decline in the U.S. gold
stock will cause a contraction of money supply in
the United States and a decline in nominal income.
Exactly the opposite will occur in Japan. With U. S.
income declining, and Japanese income rising, our
purchases of Japanese goods will decline and our
sales to Japan will increase. This would cause an




-8elimination of any U. S. import surplus.
Similarly, under the dollar exchange
standard, the accumulation of dollar balances by
foreigners would increase their reserves which, in
turn, would lead to an increase in their money
supply and income level. The opposite could happen
here, and again our balance of payments deficit
would be corrected.
The flexible exchange rate, as we have
seen, would tend to establish a balance between
imports and exports by causing a decline in the
price of the dollar in terms of foreign currencies,
which would make foreign goods more expensive to us
and our commodities cheaper to foreigners. This
change in relative prices would discourage our
imports and encourage exports.
All three systems of international payments mechanisms facilitate trade, provide
adjustments, and have within them necessary means
for prevention of trade breakdown. Two of them do
it with fixed exchange rates, and one with a
flexible rate. Thus, the question arises what are the
ultimate differences among them, and why should a person
advocate one exchange rate system over another.

-9The major difference is that within the
fixed exchange schemes, both the gold and the
dollar exchange standards, the adjustments which
are necessary to maintain an equilibrium in the
balance of payments take place in the domestic
economies in the form of changes in prices, income,
and employment levels. In a flexible exchange rate
mechanism, the adjustment is in the form of changes
of prices and quantities of internationally-traded
commodities, and in the welfare aspects generated
by the changes of the terms of trade.
The adjustments required by a fixed exchange rate
system frequently conflict with domestic goals. Virtually
all national governments have adequately demonstrated
that they are committed to the achievement of stable
conditions in domestic economic activity. In our example,
for instance, it is difficult to imagine that, given an
import balance,the United States would be willing to
permit the indicated contraction of domestic production
with its inherent probability of higher unemployment.
It is just as difficult to visualize Japan deliberately
submitting to inflation because their exports have exceeded
their imports.
As a result of the strong desire for
economic stability at home, central banks have
generally undertaken policies which mitigate the






-10adjustments necessary to correct a disequilibrium in
international trade under a system of fixed exchange
rates. Such actions have resulted in the development
of persistent and fundamental trade deficits and
surpluses. In turn, these surpluses and deficits
have produced crises requiring periodic adjustments
in the exchange rate, direct controls, and other
arbitrary impediments to international trade.
A flexible exchange rate, on the other hand,
does not necessarily imply domestic fluctuations in
income and employment. It is, therefore, more
likely to be permitted to achieve the adjustments
necessary for the smooth functioning of international
trade. In the choice of different exchange rate
systems, it seems to me, the crux of the matter is
not the ability of these systems to make necessary
adjustments, rather, given the demonstrated
political necessity of maintaining full domestic
production and employment, it is a matter of which
one will be permitted to do so.
Historical Background of the Present Crisis.
I have sketched the various international
payments mechanisms and have indicated how
equilibrium can be achieved under several exchange




-IIrate standards. 1 would like to turn now to the
specific case of the U. S. balance of payments
difficulties and discuss historical events leading
to the "international monetary crisis" of 1971. In
capsule form, the history of the U.S. balance of
payments position is as follows.
From 1790 to 1875, the United States was
a net importer of goods, services, and capital. A
developing economy provides good investment
opportunities and foreign capital flows in. This
inflow financed the excess of merchandise imports.
As the economy matured and the ratio of capital to
other resources began to grow, repayment of foreign
loans, and eventually U.S. foreign investment,
began to take place. In the United States this change
occurred approximately in 1875, and since that time
we have been a net exporter of capital and merchandise.
At the end of World War II, we emerged as
virtually the only industrial country with its
productive capacity intact. In spite of the strong
postwar domestic demand, our relative prices were
still lower than those in the foreign countries and
our export balance became very large. This excess
of exports over imports was financed by private and
government lending and unilateral transfers. After




-121930, U. S. private and government capital outflows
began to exceed the exports of merchandise and
services thus supplying more dollars to the foreign
exchange markets than foreign importers were willing
to absorb. Since 1930, that is, the U. S. balance of
payments on a liquidity basis has been in deficit.
The international payments mechanism, as
established by the Bretton Woods agreements of 1944,
provided that countries can fix their exchange rates
either in terms of gold or in terms of the dollar.
As it turned out, the United States established the
price of the dollar in terms of gold at $33 per
ounce and most other countries defined the prices of
their currencies in terms of the dollar. The
exchange rates were fixed by foreign central bank
intervention in the form of buying dollars when the
price of the dollar was falling in terms of foreign currencies
and selling when the price of the dollar was rising.

It

isn't difficult to see that a persistent deficit in
the U. S. balance of payments and a fixed dollar
exchange rate could coexist only with the accumulation
of dollar balances by private foreigners and foreign
central banks.




-13Until the latter half of the 1960's the United
States experienced a significantly lower rate of
inflation and a lower amplitude of cyclical fluctuations than did other major foreign economies.
Therefore, the dollar, as the most stable of all
major currencies was extensively used as an international means of payment. A large portion of the
deficit-induced dollar balances were thus held willingly
and provided a service as international money.
During the late sixties, however, the U. S.
balance on goods and services began to decline while
capital outflows remained virtually constant. At the
same time, domestic monetary and fiscal policies resulted
in large decreases in the purchasing power of the U. S.
dollar, both domestically and internationally. Thus, in
world trade we had an increasing rate of dollars being
supplied and a reduced demand for them, and under these
circumstances something had to give.
With these developments in mind, let's analyze
our position in the spring of 1971.
U. S. International Position in the Spring 1971.
1. Expansionary monetary and fiscal
policies since 1965 resulted in a rapidly rising
price level and growing expectations of inflation.




-14Attempts to moderate inflationary pressures by
restrictive fiscal actions in 1968 and restrictive
monetary actions in 1969 were reversed in 1970,
eliminating any hope of quickly achieving price
level stability.
2. As a result, our imports continued to
increase, while our exports began to decline. A
deteriorating balance in goods and services,
coupled with substantial net investment in other
countries and government expenditures abroad, meant
an increase in the quantity of dollars supplied
without a corresponding increase in demand.
3. The international price of the dollar
could remain fixed only through sales of gold to
foreigners or through massive accumulation of
dollar balances by foreign private individuals and
central banks. Our gold supply has dwindled to
$10 billion, and we are reluctant to permit its
continued depletion. Dollar accumulation by
foreigners reached $45 billion by March 31, 1971.
4. Foreign exchange dealers and owners
of liquid dollar balances in anticipation of some
kind of a downward readjustment in the value of
the dollar, began converting dollar holdings into
foreign currencies. This forced foreign central




-15banks to purchase even larger amounts of dollar claims.
5. With these pressures increasing, and
with no hope for redress, Germany, Netherlands, and
Belgium announced that they would no longer purchase additional dollars, thus floating their
currencies and permitting them to appreciate. Meanwhile, Switzerland and Austria undertook outright
revaluation by announcing that their central banks
would continue to purchase dollars but only at a lower
price.
6. Our deteriorating competitive position
and resulting reduction in the export surplus were
contributing to unemployment in the United States.
Alternative options available
Given this situation, neither the United
States nor the major trading countries which were
running sizeable surpluses could continue under the
existing fixed exchange rate alignment. It was clear
that the U.S. dollar was overvalued with respect to
many major currencies and that the existing exchange
rate mechanism was prone to the development of persistent balance of payments deficits and surpluses.




-16Any new system which could remain viable for any
length of time would not only have to alleviate the
United States deficit but also provide for a payments mechanism which would inhibit the persistence
of international disequilibrium.
Three unilateral actions were available to
the United States: the establishment of import
controls in order to equalize exports and imports,
the revaluation of gold with the hope that other
countries would permit the exchange depreciation of
the dollar, and the suspension of dollar convertibility into gold, thus subjecting the international
value of the dollar to market forces.
Import controls, whether in the form of
high tariffs or of direct or exchange quotas,
represent a type of interference with consumer
choice. As we have seen earlier, the benefits from
international trade are a result of satisfying
consumer preference for imported commodities and the
consequent reallocation of resources so as to
increase the efficiency of the trading economies.
Arbitrary intervention with the consumer preference
pattern will reduce the total volume of trade and
the benefits to be derived from it. The size




-17of this welfare loss is difficult to measure, but
it is of such magnitude that, even under the most
trying circumstances, governments which are concerned
with the satisfaction of individual citizens' wants
have undertaken such measures only as a policy of
last resort.
The revaluation of gold, in spite of its
current mention as a solution, does not produce the
desired effects, particularly when it is unilateral.
As we have seen, exchange rates are fixed at their
established parities by central bank intervention.
Devaluing the dollar in terms of gold does not, by
itself, realign exchange rates and therefore does
not either improve the United States balance of
payments position nor provide a payments mechanism
which will preclude persistent deficits or surpluses.
The suspension of dollar convertibility
into gold, again, as a unilateral action, does not
insure that the dollar will float in response to
market forces. We may say that the dollar is
floating and we may not intervene in the foreign
exchange market, but that does not prevent foreign
central banks from interfering and fixing the
dollar rate of their currencies at some level
desired by them.




-18It may be asked at this point, why then did
the President suspend the conversion of dollars into
gold? The answer is to be found in the huge dollar
balances accumulated by the central banks of surplus countries. Without convertibility into gold,
these balances can only be used to buy U. S. goods
and services. Since the accumulation itself is a sign
that at current prices foreigners find it unprofitable to
import from the United States, the probability that
they will continue to support the prevailing price
of the dollar is very small. This was already
indicated by the revaluation and flotation of the
currencies of several countries which took place in
May, 1971. In addition, inconvertibility of the
dollar into gold, in effect, removed the cornerstone of the Bretton Woods agreements and made some
multilateral action imperative.
To sum up, unilateral actions on the part
of the United States, as economically powerful as
it may be, either do not solve the current international economic problems or are too costly to
undertake and to enforce. What is required is a
multilateral action of all countries involved to
realign the exchange rates and to agree to a pay-




-19ments system which will provide enough exchange
rate flexibility to forestall another crisis such as we
face today.
Possible Choices of Payments Mechanisms.
In view of the discussion up to now and in
view of the sentiments expressed by international
authorities and the world press, we are left with
two effective possible payments systems: a multiliterally agreed upon freely fluctuating exchange
rate mechanism or a multilaterally established
fixed exchange rate system with readjusted par
values and with somewhat greater flexibility around
par. I should like to discuss these in reverse
order.
A fixed exchange rate system will require
a negotiated realignment of exchange rates. The
events of the past few weeks demonstrate the
magnitude of the problem. Surplus countries all
appear to acknowledge the necessity of devaluing
the dollar. However, when it comes to a true
commitment, few countries wish to revalue their
currencies to a true market level at which their surpluses and our deficits would be eliminated. In short, a




-20surplus to them at the expense of a deficit to the
United States, is "fair."
Given this attitude, it is difficult to
conceive that the governments Involved would pursue the domestic policies necessary for a fixed
rate system to survive, because fixed rates without
balance of payments difficulties require that each
country maintain a rate of domestic economic
growth approximately equal to that of other countries. Significantly different growth rates would again
produce persistent balance of payments surpluses
and deficits and would again lead to exchange crises
with all the losses of trade that accompany them.
Increased flexibility around par will
permit larger deviations from a concerted rate of
growth but will not eliminate the possibility of
some country being temporarily successful in using
foreign trade as a tool of domestic policy. So
long as such a possibility exists, some governments
will have the incentive to use this politically
expedient economic measure at the expense of
welfare gains to their consumers.
Thus, even if a "correct" exchange
realignment is agreed upon, and United States




-21balance-of-payments problems are solved, the
permanency of such a system is very much in question. Of course, if the established bands around
par were very wide, and the par were to change
easily and automatically, my objections would be
removed. But then, of course, it would not be a
fixed rate system.
This leads us to the consideration of the
freely fluctuating exchange rate. I believe that
such a system would best solve current difficulties
and would assure a permanent exchange rate mechanism
which should be free of the type of trade slowdowns
we are experiencing now. Rates would respond to
the forces of demand and supply and accurately
reflect the trading positions of all nations.
Unwanted accumulations of currencies could not take
place; there would be no development of crises with
their resultant losses. And, what is more important,
ail governments could pursue totally independent
domestic policies without imposing their excesses
upon others.
An inflationary policy, for example, would
cause an increase in a country's demand for imports
and a decline in its exports. Instead of running an
extended deficit and exporting its inflation, it will




-22find that the international value of its currency has
fallen and its import surplus is eliminated. Thus,
domestic excesses would have to be paid for at home.
I believe that the knowledge of this fact will prevent
the use of the international market for domestic goals.
Two major criticisms of the freely fluctuating exchange rate are most frequently voiced.
First, because of daily or conceivably even hourly
fluctuations in the rate, it is contended that the
increase in uncertainty will cause a reduction in the
volume of trade. Second, it is further contended that
the freely fluctuating rate will elicit trade restrictions
and unbridled speculation.
There is very little doubt that frequent
changes in exchange rates would induce greater
risks and therefore marginally greater costs of
international currency convertibility. But the
question should not be whether the convertibility
costs are higher than they would be under a fixed
rate system, but whether they are higher than the
total trade costs of periodic real or anticipated
revaluations of fixed exchange rates. After all, we
have many markets, for instance grain and stock,
in which prices change hourly and these markets
still function and function very efficiently.




-23Slowdowns occur in these markets when there is an
expectation of some natural disaster or a strike
or some legal interference, events not unlike the
anticipated official changes in the exchange rate.
Although historical evidence with respect
to freely fluctuating exchange rates is rare, where
it has existed, it shows that in normal economic
and political conditions, the forward cover, i.e.,
the insurance premium for delivery of some currency
at a specified price at some future date, increases
minimally. The recent experience with relatively
"clean" floats, those of Canada and Germany,
supports my contention.
Similar remarks can be made about speculation, an activity which stabilizes rather than
destabilizes prices. Destabilizing speculation,
which everyone fears, occurs as a result of
anticipations of forces outside the normal economic
realm. With freely fluctuating exchange rates,
such forces are much less likely to materialize.
An interesting observation is that with
fixed exchange rates and the associated central
bank intervention in exchange markets, a form of
speculation is performed by central banks rather than
by those individuals who voluntarily bear the risks.
Thus, the risk of loss is borne by all taxpayers,




-24whether they want it or not.
As for the criticism that freely fluctuating exchange rates will elicit trade restrictions
greater than under fixed rates, one simply has to
look at the situation which existed for the past 27
years. It really all depends on what one means by
trade restrictions. It seems to me that arguing
that a fluctuating rate will lead to more
restrictions is simply saying that where disequilibrium
fixed rates can no longer be used to pursue
domestic goals, alternative means may take the form
of new trade restrictions. In other words, a
country, which for purposes of domestic stabilization, maintained an undervalued currency and an
export balance under a fixed rate system, will now
have to resort to other trade restrictions to
achieve the same goal. It is certainly not an
inevitable consequence of flexible rates, and in
any case, it is only a different manifestation of
the same restrictive policy.
The usual example put forward is the economic
warfare of the early thirties. At that time there was
truly a proliferation of various international trade
barriers and for a while the British pound was removed




-25from its convertibility into gold. What these critics
fail to point out is that there was a world-wide
depression under way and that the restraints began
to multiply in 1929 while the pound was not floated
until 1931. A causal relationship is certainly not
indicated.
I believe that the freely fluctuating exchange
rate is far preferable to a fixed one. Whatever the
costs involved, they are less than those imposed by the
present system. There is the chance now to establish
a mechanism which prohibits the exchange exploitation
of one country by another and which therefore has a
better chance of long-run survival.