View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

HOW AND WHY FISCAL ACTIONS MATTER TO A MONETARIST
By
Darryl R. Francis, President
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
At
The University of Southern Mississippi
Hattiesburg, Mississippi
Friday afternoon, May 3, 1974

The topic I have chosen to discuss with you this
afternoon is concerned with the relation between monetary
policy developments over the past few decades and the U. S.
Government debt. My main point will emphasize how the
Federal Reserve's response to deficits in the Federal Budgets
is related to the growing inflationary trend experienced in
recent years.
Before getting into what I want to say, it is
necessary to introduce an analytic concept we find very
useful at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. In order
to summarize in a single series the net influence of all of
the monetary actions of both the Treasury and the Federal
Reserve, we employ a concept referred to as the "monetary
base." The monetary base represents the net monetary
1/
liabilities of the Government - held by the public. 2/
1/ U. S. Treasury and Federal Reserve System.
2/ Commercial banks and nonbank public.



-2The monetary base has been referred to as "high powered"
money because it can be used as reserves by commercial banks
to expand demand deposits by more than the amount of their
reserves.
The approach our staff uses to analyze the factors
influencing the growth of the nation's money stock — demand
deposits plus currency in the hands of the public — holds
that the monetary base is the major determinant of changes
in the rate of growth of the money stock. As the fourth and
fifth tiers on the chart illustrate, the growth rates of the
monetary base and the money stock over periods of several
years are very similar. The primary reason that money grew
somewhat slower on average than the base in the early 1960's
is that this was a period of very rapid growth of time deposits
at commercial banks, especially large negotiable CDs. Growth
in time deposits absorbs reserves, or base money, leaving
less available to support the growth of the narrowly defined
money stock.
Since our analysis holds that growth in the base
determines the growth in money, we want to look at the
factors causing the growth of the monetary base. During
the past twenty years, growth of the monetary base has: been
determined primarily by two sources - the gold stock and
Federal Reserve Credit. An increase in the dollar amount
of either of these sources, other things equal, increases the



-3monetary base by an equal amount.
In September 1949, when the gold stock source of
the base was at its peak, it comprised almost 58 percent of
the monetary base. From 1949 to 1968 the amount of gold
owned by the U. S. Treasury declined almost continuously.
This decline in gold stock contributed a negative influence on
the growth of the base, while increases in Federal Reserve
holdings of U. S. Government securities, the primary
component of Federal Reserve credit, contributed a positive
influence. Other sources, though their net influence
has been positive, have contributed relatively little to
movements in the base during the past twenty years.
From 1952 to the middle of 1961 the monetary base
grew slowly as increases in securities held by the Federal
Reserve System largely offset decreases in the gold stock.
Beginning in the 1960's, increases in Federal Reserve holdings
of Government securities exceeded reductions in the gold stock,
and the monetary base grew more rapidly. A two-tiered
gold system, established in March 1968, separated the gold
market into private and official sectors, each with its own
price. From April 1968 through 1971, the gold stock remained
roughly constant and contributed little to changes in the
monetary base.




-4At the end of 1971 and again in 1973 the U. S.
Government changed the official dollar price of gold - - an
event commonly referred to as a devaluation. These two
devaluations, by themselves, added about $2 billion to the
monetary base, since the book value of the gold held by the
Government was raised. 3/
Holdings of Government securities by the Federal
Reserve represent the System's acquisitions of Federal
Government debt through its open market operations. These
security holdings presently comprise 76 percent of the monetary
base, and since the early 1960s changes in security holdings
have been the dominant influence on the growth of the base.
Through purchases and sales of securities, called open market
operations, the Federal Reserve can control the growth of
the monetary base by offsetting or complementing any
movements in other sources.
Growth of Government securities held by the Federal
Reserve System has traditionally depended both on the growth
of Government debt outstanding, and the percent of this debt
the System decides to purchase. Let's now trace the growth
of Government debt over the last twenty years, the acquisition
of debt by the Federal Reserve System, and the reasons for

3/AlbertE. Burger, "The Monetary Economics of Gold," Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review (January 1974).



-5debt acquisition by the System.
Government debt is shown in the top tier of the chart.
The trend growth of Government debt outstanding oscillated
around a one percent annual rate from the first quarter
of 1952 to the third quarter of 1961. Unified budget deficits
of $3.4 billion and $7.1 in fiscal years 1961 and 1962, respectively,
initiated an increase in the trend rate in the early 1960s. From
the third quarter of 1961 to the fourth quarter of 1966, net
Government debt rose by $20 billion, an average of about
$4 billion per year, or at an annual trend rate of 1.5 percent. 4/
Large unified budget deficits of $8.7 billion and over
$25 billion were incurred in fiscal years 1967 and 1968,
respectively. These deficits further increased the trend
growth rate of Government debt. From the fourth quarter
of 1966 to the fourth quarter of 1970 net Government debt grew
by over $28 billion, an average of over $7 billion per year,
or at a 2.6 percent annual rate.
Federal Government debt held by the Federal Reserve
System (shown in the second tier of the chart) rose by only
about one-half billion dollars per year from 1952 to 1961, but
then began to rise more rapidly in the 1960s. Changes in the
monetary base during the 1960s roughly paralleled that of

4/ Net Federal Government Debt is total gross public debt minus
debt held by U. S. Government agencies and trust funds.



-6the System's holding of debt. The percent of debt held by the
Federal Reserve System is shown on the third panel of the
chart.
Between the first quarter of 1932 and the third
quarter of 1961, the proportion of Government debt held by
the Federal Reserve System remained roughly constant at
around II percent. As net Government debt increased,
securities held by the Federal Reserve System increased
proportionally, and as the debt decreased, securities held
decreased in the same way. Variations in Government debt
outstanding in the 1930s, especially late in the decade, were
associated with accelerations and decelerations in growth
of the monetary base. Variations in the base, in turn, were
a major cause of fluctuations in the money stock.
The trend rate of growth of Government debt
increased in the first half of the 1960s. At the same time,
the percent of the debt held by the Federal Reserve also increased,
as the rate of acquisition of debt by the Federal Reserve was
more rapid than the expansion of Government debt itself.
Increased purchases of Government securities by the Federal
Reserve directly increased the monetary base, increasing its
trend rate of growth, which in turn increased growth of the
money stock and economic activity. As resource utilization




-7approached its upper limit, as defined by potential output,
the rate of inflation increased.
Before looking at the developments in the late
1960s and early 1970s, I want to digress a moment and discuss
with you what I would consider to be the appropriate relation
between a central bank's holdings of government debt and
the growth of government debt outstanding. If the net
amount of public debt were roughly constant or declining - that is, Government budgets were in balance or surplus - then the percent of the debt held by the Federal Reserve
Banks would gradually rise as the level of System holdings
gradually rose. This assumes that there are no major
changes in other factors such as the gold stock or reserve
requirements of member banks.
i believe that monetary policy actions can and should
be geared to providing a relatively steady, non-inflationary
trend growth in the money stock. If this were the case,
the rate at which Government debt is acquired by the central
bank would not be influenced by the size of the budgetary
deficits or surpluses. Therefore, one would expect that when
there are large budget deficits and the outstanding Government
debt is rising at a rapid rate, the proportion of the debt owned




-8by the central bank would decline. This has not been the
case for most of the post-War period.
In contrast to the relation between the Government
debt and the central bank holdings that I would like to see,
we have had a situation where the monetary authorities have
been principally concerned with the general level of and trend
of market interest rates, rather than the growth of the
nation's money stock. The experience has been that larger
deficits have tended to be accompanied by more than
proportional debt acquisition by the Federal Reserve Banks.
The behavioral sequence is familiar to most market observers.
During periods when deficits are large, upward pressure
on market interest rates — downward pressure on
security prices - - occurs at the time the Treasury financings take place. In the past the Federal Reserve often has
"even-keeled" the money markets — that is, provided reserves
through open market operations to "lean against" the tendency
for interest rates to rise in the short-run.
In theory, the Federal Reserve would "unwind" after
the even-keel operation by reducing its portfolio of securities.
In practice, the desire to resist upward pressure on market
interest rates, especially during periods of a strengthening




-9economy and rising demands for credit, has militated against
behaving according to the ideal. Also, during past fiscal years
of very large budget deficits, the Treasury has been involved
in some sort of financing the majority of the time, which has
left the monetary authorities little opportunity to "unwind."
Now let us return to a discussion of the developments from 1969 to present. In 1969 the net stock of
outstanding U. S. Government debt declined as the Federal
budget moved into surplus for a while. This was the result
of the so-called "fiscal package" of mid-1968 — which consisted
of a 10 percent surcharge on personal and corporate income
taxes and a ceiling on the growth of Federal expenditures.
The amount of debt held by the Federal Reserve leveled off
in 1969, and we experienced a fairly sharp contraction in
the growth rates of the monetary base and the money stock.
These developments gave us a period of true monetary restraint,
and the ensuing 1970 recession was the consequence.
Since early in 1970 the Federal budget deficits
have been sizable, as is shown by the rise in the outstanding
debt in the top tier of the chart. In the past three years we
have seen a rise in the debt of over $16 billion per year, or at over
a 5 percent annual rate of increase. This adds up to a rise of
over $49 billion. In the same period the debt held by the
Federal Reserve Banks has risen over $17 billion, an average



-10increase of $5.8 billion per year.
These developments have fostered a rise in the
monetary base of almost $23 billion, or an increase of
7.7 percent per year since 1970. Similarly, the nation's money
stock rose at a 6.7 percent average rate during these three years.
In this period we have experienced the fastest rates of
increase in the money stock and the monetary base since
World War II, and I would submit that the correlation between
big government deficits and rapid increases in the money
stock in recent years, as was true during the second World
War, are high enough to impress even the most casual of
monetary observers.
Having presented my view of the relation between
government deficits and monetary growth, let me turn to what
I see as being the consequences. I draw your attention to the
lower two tiers on the chart, the money stock and the general
price index. Through much of the economic history of this
country as well as others for which data is available, the general
relation between monetary growth and the price index has
shown that the rate of inflation reflects the average rate of
growth of the money stock over the prior two or more years.
The lower two tiers on the chart depict this relationship.
The average rate of growth of the money stock of less than




-II2 percent from 1952 to 1962 was accompanied by an average
rise in prices at less than a 2 per cent rate through 1965.
After money growth accelerated to a 3.4 percent average
rate from 1961 through 1966, the average rate of increase
in the general price index accelerated to 3.7 percent from
the end of 1965 to early 1969.
Following the period of monetary restraint in the
last half of 1966, the average rate of money growth accelerated
further to a 6 percent rate for the next four years. With the
usual lag, the rate of inflation began to accelerate, and on
balance during the period early-1969 to mid-1971, prior
to the wage-price freeze, we experienced rise in prices at a
rate of 5.4 percent. During the three years since the end
of the 1970 recession, money growth has averaged 6.7 percent
per year. During Phases I and II of the price-wage control
program the average rise in prices was only 3 percent, but
with the very sharp increases since the end of Phase II early
last year, in the past five quarters the general price index
has risen at an 8 percent average annual rate.
In view of this acceleration in inflation and the
popular notion of a "trade-off" between inflation and unemployment, let's look at what we have gained. In the decade 1952 to
1962 average real output growth was 3 percent per year,




-12unemployment averaged 4.4 percent, and the general price
index rose at less than a 2 percent average annual rate. Then
from 1962 through 1969, with the huge defense expenditure
of Vietnam, output growth averaged 4.6 percent per year,
unemployment again averaged 4.4 percent, and the rate of
inflation doubled from less than 2 percent before 1966 to
almost 4 percent over the next few years.
In the last period under review, 1969 through 1973,
the average growth in output was only 3.6 percent, about
the same as from 1952 to 1962. Also, in the recent period we
experienced an average unemployment rate of 5 percent,
slightly higher than the 1952-1962 period. However, the past
few years has seen accelerating inflation, without any
benefits in terms of more output or less unemployment.
Let me now try to summarize my view of the relation
that has existed between government deficits, monetary
growth, and inflation over the past twenty or more years. In
the decade 1952 until the latter part of 1961, the net government
debt rose by a total of about $22 billion. Of that amount, the
Federal Reserve System, through its open market operations,
purchased and therefore "monetized," about $5 billion. This
acquisition of Government debt by the central bank was the
primary factor causing a rise in the monetary base of about
$7.5 billion — a growth rate of only one and one-half percent
per year. The relatively slow growth of Government debt,



-13debt owned by the Federal Reserve, and the monetary base,
produced a growth of our money stock of only $23 billion
over a decade, or a rise of a less than 2 percent average rate.
That is why prices rose so slowly through the 1930s and into
the early 1960s.
Beginning in the early 1960s, first with the increased
emphasis of economic policies on stimulating real growth and
achieving lower unemployment rates, followed by the massive
Federal expenditures associated with Vietnam, net outstanding
Government debt rose by about $48 billion from late 1961 to
late 1970. In this period, the Federal Reserve System
purchased in the open market about $33 billion of Government
debt, producing a rise in the monetary base of over $29 billion,
and a rise in the money stock of over $73 billion in roughly
9 years. I assert that this was the original economic policy
development underlying our current troubles. More
recently, in only three years, Government debt has risen
another $49 billion, the Federal Reserve has purchased over
$17 billion, giving us a rise in the monetary base of over
$20 billion and a $48 billion increase in the money stock.
Combining the periods since 1961, in the past twelve years
the Federal Reserve has acquired over one-half of the almost
$100 billion increase in the net national debt, contributing
to almost a doubling of our money supply, or in actual




-14dollar terms a $120 billion increase.
In my view, the successive upward ratcheting in
the average growth rate of the money stock has been the
primary cause of the acceleration in the average rate of
inflation. I do not accept the analyses which point to the
food price increases, the petroleum product price increases,
or other special factors as causes of the underlying
inflationary trend. Certainly these factors influenced the
timing and possibly the magnitude of the recent sharp
increases in the price indexes; but a rise in the price of
any single commodity does not cause inflation any more
than a fall in the price of a single commodity causes deflation.
No one is arguing that the recent declines in prices of a
number of agricultural commodities indicate we are
experiencing deflation.
Finally, let me turn to the outlook. My staff tells
me that by mid-year the average rate of increase in the
money stock will have been at 7 percent for three and
one-half years. Past experience would indicate that if
that rate of money growth were maintained, we would expect
to also observe an average inflation rate of about 7 percent
to persist. Thus, our analysis holds that an essential step
towards bringing inflation down to more tolerable rates is




-15to reduce the average growth of money. Specifically, I
would like to see no more than a 5 percent rate of money
growth in the second half of this year, and then possibly
reduce it somewhat further next year. This approach would
not bring an early end to inflation, but it would be tangible
progress without necessarily involving the hardships
associated with a recession.
However, although I believe the desirability of
achieving lower average money growth is clear, there are
reasons to be less than optimistic that it will occur. The
Federal budget for fiscal 1975, which begins in just two
months, implies a deficit of about $9 billion, and many
private analysts speculate that it could be much larger
than that. Current estimates are for very sizable Treasury
borrowing in the second half of this calendar year. Since we are
already faced with a quite high structure of market interest
rates and prospects for a strengthening economy, the
temptation may be great to repeat the ways of the past and
add substantial quantities of securities to the System portfolio
through open market operations. If that were done, then the
pattern I have outlined to you would be repeated — increases
in outstanding Government debt matched by increased holdings
of debt by the central bank, which means continued rapid growth
of the monetary base and the money stock. That would mean
continued rapid inflation.