View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

AGRIBUSINESS GROWTH - A BROADENED VIEWPOINT
Speech by Darryl R. Francis
President of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
to the
Chamber of Commerce Agribusiness Institute
Ramada Inn, Columbia, Mo.
October 23, 1970

It is good to have this opportunity to discuss with
you some critical issues concerning agricultural industries
in Missouri and the nation.
In the early decades of our nation most of the
supply and processing functions relative to producing and
preparing farm products for the consumer were performed in
the farm household by the farm family. In that period the
successful farmer required numerous skills as carpenter,
wheelright, harness maker, blacksmith, butcher, etc. His
wife displayed equal versatility, as nearly every item of
clothing and food for the family went from raw condition to
finished product in her hands. These functions relative to
producing, processing, and marketing farm products constitute
our agribusiness industries.
With the invention of more sophisticated equipment
during the industrial revolution of the I800's, there was a
sharp increase in farming efficiency and a reduction in the
functions performed on the farm. Division of labor and job




-2specalization began on a wider scale, and it became more
efficient to perform many here-to-fore functions in an
off-the-farm setting.
The manufacture of plowing, cultivating, and
harvesting machinery was an early development in the supply
sector of agribusiness. Farm power equipment, chemical
fertilizers, and more efficient lines of machinery soon
followed. More recently, off-farm controls for weeds, insects,
and diseases have received major emphasis. But more significantly, we continue to remove large chunks of normally farm
functions away from the farm setting. Examples of such
tendencies are the factory-like broiler operations, dairy
parlors, commercial cattle feeding operations, and hybrid
seed production.
Off-farm development of processing and marketing
has accompanied the growth and innovations in the farm supply
sector. Mechanization in the clothing, shoe, textile, and
flour milling industries has tended to reduce the functions
formerly performed in the farm home. More recently, we have
had further food processing operations which have relieved
both the farm and urban wife of many food preparation chores. New
products found on grocery counters include: frozen juice concentrates, frozen desserts from vegetable oils, numerous
baking mixes, and other foods requiring a minimum of




-3preparation. The freeze-drying process, continuous mix bread
baking, improved warehousing, controlled atmospheric storage,
and computer controlled inventories are examples of new handling
methods—

High speed highways have improved the efficiency

of trucking foods. Larger freight cars have increased
the efficiency of hauling feed and grain, and air transportation has become increasingly feasible for some food items.
These developments have reduced the isolation of many smaller
communities and altered the location of food producing and
processing areas.
These industries which are active in producing
farm supplies, farming, and processing and marketing farm
products are a vital and growing sector in the nation. They
account for about $150 billion or one-fifth of national
product. Agriculture is relatively more important in Missouri
than in the rest of the nation. The entire agribusiness
sector will likewise be more important here, because a large
portion of the farm supply and farm commodity processing
activity tends to be located near farm production areas.
Agribusiness growth in recent years has approached
the growth rate of gross national product. From 1955 to 1967,
value added in agribusiness grew about 4.3 per cent per year,
while gross national product grew at the rate of 5.9 per

cent.

Report of National Commission on Food Marketing, Food From
Farmer to Consumer, GPO, Washington, p. 8.
2/ Clifton B. Luttrell, "Agribusiness - A Growth Analysis "
Business and Government Review, November-December 1969, p. 36




-4Growth among the three sectors of agribusiness has been quite
uneven, with the off-farm sectors rising substantially faster
than the farm sector. For example, during the 1955-67 period,
value added per year in processing and marketing rose 5.0 per
cent, in farm supplies 3.7 per cent, and at the farm only
2.1 per cent.
Growth in any sector of agribusiness, like growth
elsewhere, depends upon supply and demand conditions. Demand
for farm supplies is a derived demand. It depends upon the
cost and productivity of those products. Farmers, like other
businessmen, are maximizers. They will purchase additional
supplies for production as long as additional profits are
anticipated from such purchases. Suppliers thus have great
incentive to create products which enhance the efficiency of
farm production. With this incentive we can expect farm
technology growth to continue and to have similar impacts on
the agribusiness sectors as in the past.
As a result of both the transfer of farm functions
to other sectors and the greater efficiencies in performing
those remaining functions, farm labor has been released to
other sectors. For example, only 35 years ago over 10 million
workers, or 24 per cent of the nation's total, were employed
in agriculture. This year only 3.6 million were employed in
agriculture or less than 5 per cent of total national employment.
Although the downtrend of farm labor continues, the rate of
decrease may be somewhat slower in the future than in the




-5past decade. Farm labor declined 4 per cent per year in the
last five years from the peak rate of 4.4 per cent in the previous
five years. The 1950-55 and 1955-60 rates of decline were
2.1 and 3.3 per cent respectively. The gap between returns
to farm and nonfarm workers is closing. Thus the incentive
to leave farm employment is not as great as formerly.
Part of the efficiencies achieved in agriculture
are the result of increased capitilization. Total value of
farm assets rose from $131.6 billion in 1950 to $297.9 billion
in 1969. Some of the increase was the result of inflation,
but the greater portion represents rising capitilization,
primarily additional labor-saving machinery. Capital per worker
rose from $18,400 to $82,600, an increase of 10.9 per cent
per year.
Supply conditions in all agribusiness sectors
are largely influenced by the streams of technology flowing
from research into the industry. This flow will likely
continue; however, it would be surprising if the rate of farm
efficiency gains of the past half century are equalled in the
next half century. In any event, the changes at the farm
cannot have the same impact on the rest of the economy as
heretofore, since the farm sector is now a much smaller
proportion of the total. Efficiency gains in the nonfarm sector
of agribusiness have been at a slower rate than in farming but




-6have probably equalled the average for all nonfarm business
and will likely move with the average in future years.
Demand for products of all sectors of agribusiness
is heavily weighted by the demand for the final consumer
product. Such products range from the relatively unprocessed
farm commodities which are exported or still prepared primarily
by the nation's households to those which undergo a sizable
amount of processing, thereby requiring a minimum of home
preparation.
Demand for unprocessed food tends to grow with
the population and at a much slower rate than total demand
for food. The actual volume of food consumed per capita in
the more advanced nations does not increase rapidly. There
are minor changes in quality of foods purchased as per capita
incomes rise which tends to cause some rise in demand, but
the major demand factors for final agribusiness products are
domestic population growth, demand for additional processing
services, and export demand.
Consumers have a choice of purchasing relatively
unprocessed food at lower prices or paying someone else
to perform the various stages of preparation. The greater
the amount of commercial preparation, the larger is the
processing and marketing sector. Consumers in the United
States have steadily demanded increased food processing.




-7The fact that the processing and marketing of food has grown
almost as fast as GNP indicates that consumers are willing
to pay increasing amounts for leisure time.
Our greatest opportunity for agribusiness growth
is in the export market. Export demand for agribusiness
products could be increased substantially under free world
trade policies. Since the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act of
1934, we have pursued an announced policy of "freeing"
international trade. We have negotiated numerous tariff reductions.
Nevertheless, other restrictions are so effective that export
trade has not been greatly affected.
While tariffs have traditionally been the chief
means of protecting domestic producers from foreign competition,
in recent years other protective devices have increasingly been
used. Chief among them are import quotas, special clearing
agreements, domestic subsidies, bilateral trade agreements,
import licensing, and domestic monopolies operating under
governmental authority. In some instances the restrictions
have involved special legislation. In others, informal agreements
have been sufficient to limit trade to arbitrarily determined
levels. With the aid of one or more of these measures,
nations can maintain tariff duties at relatively moderate
levels and still protect producers from foreign competition.
This change in method of protection provides an opportunity
for great obscurity in discussing trade policies and results




-8of tariff reduction agreements. A reduction in tariff rates
has little meaning since real barriers to trade remain unchanged.
International trade barriers are as unreasonable
under competitive production and marketing conditions as
are trade barriers between states, cities, or counties. To
the extent that they reduce the international volume of goods
and services they reduce welfare.
Our country has not been innocent with respect
to the use of these protective devices. Even in agriculture,
which has such a large stake in free trade, we have established
highly protectionist policies. We have sugar import quotas
which, based on the New York wholesale price, cost U. S.
consumers an additional 22 cents for each five pounds of
sugar purchased.^

We have subscribed to international

trade agreements which set minimum prices on coffee
and wheat, thereby limiting trade in these commodities. We
have meat import quotas which provide limits on imports of
beef. Our cotton export subsidy, designed to offset the
trade retarding features of our domestic price support program,
is sufficient to permit exports of cotton to Japan and imports
of goods made from cotton to the U.S. for sale in competition
with our own mills. In order to avoid excessive disruptions
from such competition, however, we have a tacit agreement with
the Japanese to limit cotton goods exports to the U.S.

Such

3/^ International Monetary Fund, International Financial
Statistics, Sept. 1970, p. 29.




-9tacit arrangements are apparently preferred to formalized legal
actions, but if they are equally effective in reducing trade,
they are likewise equally effective in reducing welfare.
Also important in limiting foreign trade are
production controls and subsidies. For a number of years
the British have subsidized their farm producers, maintaining excessive labor in agriculture which, in effect,
limits their imports and our exports of farm products to them.
These workers could earn more in nonfarm pursuits, and under
free trade conditions the British would export more nonfarm
products and import more farm products, thereby enhancing
total production and welfare.
Our own domestic farm programs inhibit world trade.
Despite our conscious policy of free trade since 1934 as
measured by tariff rates, our domestic farm policies pursued
since then have probably offset the advantages gained from the
reduced tariff levies. We initiated farm production control
and price support programs in the mid-1930's which contributed
to higher farm production cost and higher prices both here and
abroad. Our farm products became less competitive in the world
market and worse, from a long range view, was the fact
that our policy of arbitrary farm product pricing at higher
than free market levels led to a loss of confidence in the
U.S. as a long run source of farm products. This move from
competitive to arbitrary pricing indicated to our customers
abroad that hereafter prices of U.S. farm commodities would




-lObe in excess of free market prices. Higher export prices in
turn indicated higher food and fiber costs to importing nations.
Their costs of imported food thus hinge on the decisions of our
price making authorities who are likely to be more influenced
by political pressures at home than by living costs elsewhere.
Our tariff reduction policies have not led to more
trade relative to total output. In the 1920 to 1934 period, prior
to the Reciprocal Trade Agreement Act, U. S. commodity exports
averaged 5.1 per cent and imports 4.1 per cent of gross
national product. In contrast, since the announced liberal
trade policies in the mid-1930's, total exports have averaged
only 4.1 per cent and imports only 2.9 per cent of GNP. The
proportion of foreign trade in farm products declined even more
sharply than the total. Exports declined from 17.4 per cent
of farm output in the 1920-34 period to 8.6 per cent since
1934 and imports from 19.9 to 10.9 per cent. In the five
years 1965-69 commercial farm exports totaled 12 per cent
of cash farm receipts, somewhat above the 1935-69 average
but well below the per cent exported prior to the so-called
change to more liberal trade policies. Furthermore, export
subsidies such as government credits and guarantees,
government commodity sales at less than market prices, and
export payments in cash were responsible for a large portion of




-IIrecent exports. We view such practices as dumping when
other countries export products to us under similar conditions.
Thus, despite our announced freer trade policies,
our new barriers to international trade have offset our
trade freeing actions. The trade barriers are usually
imposed in such a way as to inhibit trade growth rather than
have a strong immediate impact, thus becoming successively
more restrictive over time.
It is my conclusion that the predominent
political forces in most nations today do not really want large
increases in foreign trade. Large gains in trade upset
markets and cause changes in resource use. Some hardships
occur in the short run in the relatively less efficient
industries. Gains occur immediately, however, in the
relatively more efficient industries and among all consumer
groups. In the longer run all groups gain from the greater
efficiency of international specialization. But, neither this
nation nor other nations have to date indicated a willingness
to adopt policies that will assure these major gains at the
expense of minor adjustments among some producer groups.
Let's take agriculture as an example and consider
the impact of greater exports of American farm products
to Western Europe. Such exports will first cause a reduction
in prices to European farmers and a reduction in food costs




-12to their consumers. Incomes to their farmers will decline,
providing incentive for farm workers seeking higher paying jobs
in the nonfarm sector. The larger nonfarm labor force which
is relatively more efficient will achieve greater output of
nonfarm goods and services, and exports of these products
to the U.S will increase. Greater efficiencies will occur
in both their farm and nonfarm sectors and a larger volume
of products will be available at lower prices, enhancing real
incomes and welfare. On the American scene, the larger
volume of farm exports will increase domestic farm prices
and incomes. This would attract new resources into agriculture
from other sectors or more likely reduce the outflow of
resources from agriculture. The larger imports of nonfarm
products by the U.S. will reduce demand for resources in
our nonfarm sector, but, similar to the European case,
the increased efficiencies will provide more goods and
services to our people.
The argument that imports from low cost factories
abroad are unfair to labor is similar to the farm import
argument. Import restrictions aid workers in import
competing industries in the short run but injure workers in
export industries. But once workers have adjusted to the new
market forces, greater output is achieved and the benefits
of greater production efficiency accrue to all.

-13Almost all major countries subscribe to the vital
industries argument for protection. Certain industries are
assumed to be vital for national survival. England, for example,
has in the past attempted to maintain domestic food production
at about 50 per cent of domestic usage. These policies
originated from a lack of confidence in supplies from abroad
at critical periods, such as during wartime blockades. Other
nations, including our own, prefer to maintain sufficient
resources in vital lines of production to provide a minimum
level of output in case of loss of supplies from abroad. Oil
and sugar quotas here are an example of such protection.
Nations are willing to maintain inefficient production of
these vital products, despite the fact that such use of resources
is a waste of effort. Protection for these industries against
competition from abroad maintains stability of employment
for a few at the expense of many. Nations are willing to tax
more for defense items and pay higher prices for the civilian
output of such industries in order to maintain these industries,
despite the fact that methods of modern warfare have made such
excuses obsolete. Nations now have the power to destroy
one another long before supplies of such critical products
are depleted. The solution lies in increased confidence that
world trade channels will remain open and supply sources
unimpaired.




From the standpoint of U.S. agriculture we look




-14abroad at rapid growth of Western European nations and see
great opportunities for farm commodity exports, provided
these nations will only open their trade doors and invite
us in. It is my conclusion that we have not earned the
invitation. Trade must be a two-way affair. Our nation
must adopt free trade policies if we expect to sell more
products abroad. Despite our numerous pronouncements, our
policies have not contributed to two-way trade arrangements.
We have done little to merit the dependence by Western
European nations upon us for an indefinite source of vital
products at competitive prices. We have neither consistently
followed a free trade policy nor domestic pricing policies
that are conducive to free trade.
Although the arguments are overwhelming in favor
of more trade between nations, I am quite pessimistic as to
its future course. Forces tending to reduce welfare through
trade barriers are better financed and more powerful than the
forces active in promoting welfare through freeing trade
channels. As an indication of the power of protective groups,
about 590 import quota proposals were introduced in the recent
session of Congress prior to the end of August^- One bill
was approved by the House Ways and Means Committee which was

4/ International Commerce, Sept. 7, 1970, p. 10




-15described by the New York Times as the "most protectionist
and reactionary trade legislation in forty years.—

Signs

admonishing us to purchase American goods and protect American
jobs can be observed daily. Only the textbooks, however, are
available to point out the gains from free trade and few
professors are out shouting the story to the general public.
SUMMATION
In summary, agribusiness growth can be explained
through the working of supply and demand forces in a free
market setting. Inefficiently performed functions were removed
from the farm when more efficient means were discovered for
performing them in a factory setting. The supply schedule
for farm production inputs and farm products is largely determined
by how efficiently they can be produced. Efficiency here as
elsewhere leans heavily on capital and technology. Our
stock of these factors is likely to continue upward, but the
rate of efficiency gain at the farm sector may be somewhat less
in the next half century than in the past half century.
Demand for agribusiness products has grown almost
at the rate of GNP, but most of the growth has occurred in the
processing and marketing sectors rather than in unprocessed
farm products. These trends are likely to continue as volume
of food consumed per person does not change rapidly and our
population growth has slowed in recent years.
51 New York Times, Sept. 21, 1970.




-16Our greatest opportunity for agribusiness growth is
through exports. The removal of trade restrictions would be
especially beneficial to American agriculture. We have a major
relative advantage in the production of farm commodities. Under
free world trade policies and free domestic producing conditions,
world-wide food prices could be lowered and world diets improved.
The political forces in most nations have not indicated
a willingness to pay the small price in economic adjustments
at home to achieve these major gains. Proposed liberal
policies are often followed by restrictive actions more typical
of the medieval and ancient ages. In practice, we still follow
the outdated theories of several centuries ago despite the more
enlightened instruction in our colleges and universities.
Most of the arguments used against free trade
practice are not applicable to modern world conditions.
The implied disruptions in local industries are generally
overstated and are often excuses for maintaining resources
in inefficient lines of production. Current unemployment
and labor retraining social programs minimize hardships to
the labor force resulting from the change. Little capital
loss would likely occur with the high rate of obsolescence
due to technological change. The vital industries argument
is no longer applicable, since, in case of all-out war
under modern conditions, no industry is secure regardless
of where it is located.




-17The United States should take the lead in dropping
the trade barriers. Tariffs are not the only item to consider.
We should move immediately to build world confidence in us
as a supplier and market. Real accomplishments will require
more than the rhetoric of recent decades followed by high
level conferences which tend to free trade where no potential
trade exists. We must be willing to reduce barriers and
permit major increases in imports and oppose the power of
producer groups who have made their short run interest
paramount to the welfare of the nation. We must be willing
to dismantle our inefficient production controls in agriculture
and assure foreign consumers that our farm products will
be available at competitive prices. A move toward free trade
is a move toward less government control of prices and
production and greater reliance on market forces for resource
adjustment.
These moves are counter to our great surge to
alleviate all individual hardships through general legislation
which temporarily aids the few but reduces national welfare.
Their adoption can reverse the trend to isolationism in the
current century and greatly enhance the welfare of both
our own citizens and those of the rest of the world.

-18It is growing and changing as a result of developments within
banks, supervision, the economy, and competitors.

Competition

is keen and probably increasing. Costs have been rising steadily
and are likely to continue to increase. As a result of these
developments, successful banks will need to be guided by capable
management. I have confidence that commercial bankers will
meet the challenges of the future as they have those of the past.
The structure of banking is in for further change in
the 1970's. Pressures for a banking system that provides for greater
efficiency contributed to major changes in the 1960's. Such
pressures will likely be greater in the 1970's, and the changes will
likely accelerate. Most changes in state laws during the past
decade have been toward less regulation with respect to bank
structure. In addition, it is being increasingly recognized that
inefficient financial institutions retard economic growth.
I believe that every community has an equal right to
market rates on loans and on savings. We know that some isolated
banks fail to provide these services at competitive prices.
The demand for these financial intermediary services
will continue to grow. If the current banking system cannot
or will not provide them efficiently, the community will demand
another type of banking system or other financial institutions.
I believe that banks can do the job provided they have freedom
to bring all areas into competitive financial markets.