View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
6:00 p.m. EDT
October 20, 2011

Unemployment, the Labor Market, and the Economy

Remarks by
Daniel K. Tarullo
Member
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
World Leaders Forum
Columbia University
New York, New York

October 20, 2011

I appreciate the opportunity to be at Columbia this evening to discuss the
American economy and, in particular, the employment situation.1 Mindful of the trend of
public discourse toward hyperbole, I hesitated in deciding whether to characterize that
situation as a crisis. But it is hard to justify characterizing in any less urgent fashion the
circumstances of the nearly 30 million Americans who are officially unemployed, out of
the labor force but wanting jobs, or involuntarily working only part time.
This situation reflects acute problems in labor markets, created by the financial
crisis and the recession that followed. But we also confront chronic labor market
problems. In my remarks this evening, I will outline both sets of problems. In my
observations on policy responses, however, I will concentrate on the acute problems--in
part to join the debate on their origins, in part because they call for the most immediate
response, and in part because they are most relevant to my monetary policy
responsibilities as a member of the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) of the
Federal Reserve. That said, I hope you will not think the chronic problems any less
important for the briefer treatment they receive tonight.
Most of what I have to say can be summarized in three points. First, the acute
problems are largely, though not completely, the result of a shortfall of aggregate demand
following the financial crisis and recession. As such, they can be addressed through
measures designed to increase total investment and consumption spending in the
economy.

1

The views presented here are my own and not necessarily those of other members of the Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System or the Federal Open Market Committee. William Wascher, Bruce
Fallick, Christopher Nekarda, and Christopher Smith of the Board’s staff provided substantial assistance
over many months in the research for, and crafting of, these remarks.

-2Second, because the recession arose from a financial crisis, which itself followed
a buildup of asset bubbles and unsustainable debt in important areas such as housing, the
policies likely to be most effective at increasing aggregate demand may be somewhat
different from those associated with a more typical recession and, even so, are not likely
to work as quickly.
Third, if labor market conditions remain this unfavorable for a long period, the
problems I have described as acute could transform into another chronic problem. I refer
not just to the despair and desperation that workers and their families must feel as weeks
of unemployment stretch into months and even years, which alone should be enough to
elicit a policy response, but also to what occurs when the ranks of the unemployed remain
so great for so long--the erosion of skills and labor market attachment may affect the
productive capacity of the economy as a whole.
The State of the Labor Market Today
Let me start with some basic statistics that summarize the current state of the
labor market. The most familiar of these is the unemployment rate, which, except for a
couple of months earlier this year, has been at or above 9 percent since mid-2009. This is
only the second time since the Great Depression that the jobless rate has been so high,
and it is the first time since the 1930s that it has been so high for so long. Unemployment
rates are exceptionally elevated for certain subgroups of the population: Nearly
15 percent for workers without a high school education, 16 percent among African
Americans, about 25 percent among all teenagers, and nearly 50 percent for African
American teenagers. Even among college graduates, whose unemployment rate is much

-3lower than that of the population as a whole, the rate has doubled since the onset of the
recession.
As familiar as the unemployment rate is, both as a measure of economic slack and
as an indicator of the pain experienced by American households, it does not tell the whole
story. About 9 million workers who would like a full-time job can find only part-time
work. Millions of others are working at jobs for which they are likely overqualified and
earning less than in their previous jobs. Meanwhile, another 6 million people who are not
officially counted among the unemployed say that they would like a job but have stopped
looking for one, in many cases because they have become discouraged by the poor state
of the job market.
This effect can also be seen in the labor force participation rate, which has
dropped sharply since 2007. The proportion of the U.S. population that is employed now
stands at about 58 percent, the lowest level since 1983. Finally, more than 6 million
workers--nearly one-half of all the unemployed--have been jobless for more than six
months. The long-term unemployment rate is by far the highest it has been since data on
the duration of unemployment began to be collected in 1948.
Even more dispiriting than this snapshot of the employment picture is that there is
so little momentum toward improvements in labor market conditions. The level of
payroll employment fell by nearly 9 million during and just after the recession. To date,
only about one-fourth that number of jobs has been restored. The pace of job growth in
recent quarters has been barely enough to absorb the increase in the labor force and
wholly insufficient to produce meaningful declines in unemployment. The number of

-4new claims for unemployment insurance suggests only modest gains in employment in
coming months, while measures of job vacancies seem to have turned down.
Longer-Term Concerns for the U.S. Labor Market
Persistent employment weakness during an economic recovery, even such a tepid
one, raises the important question of whether it is symptomatic of longer-run changes in
the labor market. Indeed, in some respects the recent weakness resembles the “jobless”
recoveries that followed the 1990 and 2001 recessions. In both of those episodes, job
growth remained weak well after the downturn in real gross domestic product (GDP)
ended, and the unemployment rate continued to rise, though from lower levels than we
have today. One might reasonably ask if these similarities suggest that structural changes
have placed the labor market on a permanently lower growth path.
A first response is that there are important differences between this recovery and
the recoveries that followed those earlier recessions. In particular, some explanations
offered for the weak labor market recovery following the past two recessions are clearly
not relevant today. Both the 1990 and 2001 recessions were relatively shallow
downturns. This factor may have allowed more of the employment adjustment to occur
through attrition, which can be spread over a longer period than layoffs. And both of
those recessions followed long expansions, which may have permitted a buildup of
productive inefficiencies that gave businesses scope to increase output in the subsequent
recovery without expanding employment.2
That said, there are some discouraging longer-term trends. Even before the
recession, the labor market seemed to be on a slower trajectory than in previous decades.
2

See Michael W. L. Elsby, Bart Hobijn, and Ayegül ahin (2010), “The Labor Market in the Great
Recession,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (Spring), pp. 1-69,
www.brookings.edu/~/media/Files/Programs/ES/BPEA/2010_spring_bpea_papers/2010a_bpea_eslby.pdf.

-5Between the business cycle peak in early 2001 and the peak in late 2007, the number of
payroll jobs rose an average of only about 0.6 percent per year, compared with job
growth of 1.8 percent per year in both the 1980s and 1990s. Similarly, the labor force
participation rate and the percentage of the population employed each peaked around
2000 and have been on a downtrend path since then. It is true that a good part of this
change can be accounted for by demographic factors--notably, lower population growth,
the aging of the baby boom, and the leveling off of participation rates among women.
But other, more disquieting factors are also at work.
Two tendencies in particular suggest that the U.S. labor market has lost some of
the dynamism that had long contributed to its resilience. First, it is apparent that job
reallocation--that is, the sum of the jobs created at some businesses and lost in others--has
been in secular decline since the late 1990s. It may seem counterintuitive to include lost
jobs in a measure of labor market health, and on its own it is obviously not such an
indicator. But when combined with new jobs, it forms part of the dynamic of job
reallocation, an important part of the “creative destruction” that contributes to long-run
economic growth--for example, as jobs shift from less-productive firms to moreproductive ones.
Second, the amount of employee movement across jobs has fallen over time.
Specifically, the rate at which workers move from one firm to another has declined. So
has the rate at which workers quit jobs, an indication of the degree to which they believe
there are better jobs available for them. In what may be a related trend, geographic
mobility across counties and states has decreased.3

3

To date, researchers have been hard-pressed to uncover an explanation for all these declines in worker
mobility. See, for example, Andrea Bassanini and Pascal Marianna (2009), “Looking Inside the Perpetual-

-6Longer-term patterns in the types of jobs being created have also contributed to a
widening gap in wages and income between the richest and poorest Americans.
Adjusting for inflation, earnings for a worker in the middle of the wage distribution have
risen about 10 percent since 1980, while earnings for a highly paid worker at the 90th
percentile of the wage distribution have risen more than 30 percent during the same
period. Earnings for workers near the low end of the distribution--those around the 10th
percentile--have risen only about 5 percent after taking inflation into account. Thus, as
has been widely observed, the gains from economic growth over the past three decades
have disproportionately accrued to the highest wage earners.
To some degree, growing wage inequality reflects rising returns to education.
Since 1980, the average wage for college graduates has increased from about one and a
half times the average wage for workers with only a high school degree to about two
times their wage. The good news is that this rise has encouraged more young Americans
to enroll in college. The fraction of 18- and 19-year-old high school graduates who are
enrolled in college rose from around 50 percent in 1980 to nearly 70 percent today. Even
the good news must be qualified, however, since half this rise took place in the 1980s,
and the pace of increase has slowed since then. The bad news is that less-educated adults
with significant work experience and younger, inexperienced adults who are ill prepared
for, or unable to afford, college may be increasingly excluded from future economic
gains.

Motion Machine: Job and Worker Flows in OECD Countries,” IZA Discussion Paper Series 4452 (Bonn:
Institute for the Study of Labor, September), http://ftp.iza.org/dp4452.pdf. It may be that there are greater
impediments to workers changing jobs (for example, job lock related to health insurance or pensions) or
that workers have become more risk averse. In principle, these trends could also reflect improving
efficiencies in the labor market, such as screening and hiring techniques that result in better matches
between firms and workers, though this more benign explanation strikes me as less likely against the
overall backdrop of labor markets in the past decade.

-7This widening inequality has been described as the result of a broader trend
toward “occupational polarization.”4 This theory posits that the diffusion of computerrelated technologies, the related automation of routine work, and an increased capability
for firms to move their activities offshore have combined to concentrate job creation in
the poles of either high-skill, high-wage employment or low-skill, low-wage work. The
high-skill occupations increasingly require at least a bachelor’s degree. Demand has
shifted away from traditional middle-class occupations. The kinds of workers who would
have been employed in a traditional manufacturing or administrative job now often end
up in lower-paying jobs.
Younger workers have historically filled many of the lower-paying service-sector
jobs that are now more likely to be taken by less-educated adults. Thus, occupational
polarization may be responsible for some of the rapid decline in employment and labor
force participation among young people over the past decade. While part of this decline
is likely attributable to the pursuit of additional education, employment and participation
rates have also fallen for those youth who are not attending school, suggesting that
education-related explanations are not the whole story. Indeed, research by the Federal
Reserve Board’s staff has found that greater crowding-out from adults can account for
much of the decline in youth participation.5 This crowding-out may have undesirable
long-term consequences for the current generation of younger adults, as some research
4

See, for example, David H. Autor, Lawrence F. Katz, and Melissa S. Kearney (2006), “The Polarization
of the U.S. Labor Market,” American Economic Review, vol. 96 (May), pp. 189-94,
www.aeaweb.org/atypon.php?return_to=/doi/pdfplus/10.1257/000282806777212620; and David H. Autor
(2010), “The Polarization of Job Opportunities in the U.S. Labor Market: Implications for Employment
and Earnings,” white paper (Washington: Center for American Progress and The Hamilton Project, April),
www.americanprogress.org/issues/2010/04/pdf/job_polarization.pdf.
5
See Christopher L. Smith (2011), “Polarization, Immigration, Education: What’s Behind the Dramatic
Decline in Youth Employment?” Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2011-41 (Washington: Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, October),
www.federalreserve.gov/Pubs/FEDS/2011/201141/201141pap.pdf.

-8finds that poor job opportunities early in one’s working life can lead to lower
employment and wage rates in the future.6
The Aggregate Demand Shortfall
To this point, I have portrayed a labor market still disabled by the trauma of the
financial crisis and the recession that followed, but also beset by chronic maladies whose
symptoms predate the crisis. In considering the nature and magnitude of appropriate
policy responses, an important question is the extent to which the current high level of
unemployment reflects a shortfall in aggregate demand rather than additional structural
problems arising from the recession. If the high level of unemployment is predominantly
structural in origin, then the increase in aggregate demand intended by various monetary
and fiscal policies would presumably be of limited efficacy.
Although structural problems likely account for some of the high jobless rate, I
believe the evidence points to aggregate demand as clearly the more important
explanation. On its face, the sheer magnitude of the decline in the number of jobs during
the recession, the speed of the increase in unemployment, and the halting nature of the
economic recovery together create a fairly strong presumption that insufficient aggregate
demand is the most significant factor. Moreover, one thing that the current episode has in
common with the previous two “jobless” recoveries is a slow rebound in aggregate
economic activity. Over the first eight quarters of all three recoveries, real GDP grew at
an average annual rate of 3 percent or less, compared, for example, with more than
6

See, for example, Christopher Ruhm (1997), “Is High School Employment Consumption or Investment?”
Journal of Labor Economics, vol. 15 (October), pp. 735-76, www.jstor.org/stable/10.1086/209844; and
Thomas A. Mroz and Timothy H. Savage (2006), “The Long-Term Effects of Youth Unemployment,”
Journal of Human Resources, vol. 41 (Spring), pp. 259-93,
http://jhr.uwpress.org/content/XLI/2/259.full.pdf. For a dissenting view regarding the effect of high-school
employment, see Joseph V. Hotz, Lixin Colin Xu, Marta Tienda, and Avner Ahituv (2002), “Are There
Returns to the Wages of Young Men from Working While in School?” Review of Economics and
Statistics, vol. 84 (May), pp. 221-36, www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/003465302317411497.

-95 percent in the two years following the 1975 and 1982 recessions. Even taking into
account differences in trends across time, the slower pace of overall economic growth
following recent recessions is striking.
Various arguments have been advanced in an effort to rebut the presumption that
an aggregate demand shortfall accounts for much or most of the increased
unemployment. The most common argument is that the deep recession created serious
difficulties in matching available workers to available jobs, resulting in a big increase in
structural unemployment.
The mismatches in question could develop for a number of reasons. First, some
have suggested that the traditional willingness of American workers to move from
weaker labor markets to stronger ones has been impeded by the sharp decline in
residential property prices and especially by the large number of mortgages that are now
greater than the values of the properties securing them. But research to date suggests that
such “house lock” has probably not had more than a small effect on structural
unemployment thus far.7 As noted earlier, migration rates have been falling for some
time. But the declines during the recession have not been larger for homeowners than for
renters. Nor has migration declined more in areas where workers are more likely to have
underwater mortgages because of particularly large declines in housing prices.
A second factor, the one most often cited in support of the structural
unemployment hypothesis, is skills mismatch. While it is quite plausible that certain
features of the current labor market reflect some skills mismatch contributing to a rise in

7

See Raven Molloy, Christopher L. Smith, and Abigail Wozniak (2011), “Internal Migration in the United
States,” Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2011-30 (Washington: Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System, May), www.federalreserve.gov/Pubs/FEDS/2011/201130/201130pap.pdf.

- 10 structural unemployment during the recession, closer examination reveals that they
explain less of this increase than might first appear.
One such labor market feature is the sharp reduction in employment in sectors
related to the housing bubble, such as residential construction and some parts of financial
services. The contention is that the skills of workers in these sectors do not readily
transfer to other sectors, and thus they will have a particularly difficult time finding new
jobs. But in every recession, certain industries and occupations are hit particularly hard,
resulting in significant permanent job losses. Yet previous recessions do not seem to
have been accompanied by notable increases in structural unemployment. Thus, those
who believe the mismatch problem specifically created by the recession--as distinguished
from more-secular trends--is either more prevalent or more persistent now than in the
past would need to identify some additional source of rigidity that has further hampered
labor market adjustment.
Some have also pointed to the high level of long-term unemployment as evidence
that mismatch is a major factor keeping the unemployment rate high. The claim is that
those without the skills sought by employers will take longer, on average, to find new
employment. However, the data do not back this claim, at least to date. If high
unemployment durations were the result of mismatch, the probability of finding a new
job should have declined proportionately more for the long-term unemployed than for the
recently unemployed. In fact, reemployment probabilities during the recession fell by
similar amounts for all durations of unemployment and have edged up by similar
increments in the recovery. Again, this pattern is more consistent with weak aggregate
demand being the most important cause of high unemployment.

- 11 Another argument for the structural unemployment hypothesis is that the
relationship between job vacancies and unemployment has recently changed. Generally,
job vacancies bear an inverse relationship to the unemployment rate; that is, when the
unemployment rate is low, vacancies are relatively plentiful, and when unemployment is
high, vacancies are scarce. The pattern of these changes over time has been plotted on
what is commonly referred to as the Beveridge curve. A stylized interpretation is that
movements along the downward-sloping Beveridge curve are generally caused by
changes in aggregate demand. Persistent shifts of the curve closer to, or further away
from, the vertical and horizontal axes may reflect structural changes in the labor market.
Much has been made of the fact that the Beveridge curve appears to have shifted
out in the past couple of years. The argument is that the shift reflects an increase in job
mismatch, with the vacancies going unfilled because of structural reasons such as lack of
geographic mobility or appropriate skills.
I think far too much has been made of this argument. In the first place, the
Bureau of Labor Statistics data series from which the Beveridge curve is constructed
began only in 2000. Researchers at the Federal Reserve Banks of Cleveland and San
Francisco used other data sources to draw what we might call “approximate Beveridge
curves” for the post-World War II period.8 They found that, during and immediately
after the serious recessions from 1973 to ’75 and from 1981 to ’82, the curve also shifted
out noticeably, but in both cases it shifted back inward during the recovery. Why this
occurred is not so clear. The big increase in job loss during the recession is probably a
8

See John Lindner and Murat Tasci (2010), “Has the Beveridge Curve Shifted?” Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland, Economic Trends, August 10, www.clevelandfed.org/research/trends/2010/0810/02labmar.cfm;
and Robert Valletta and Katherine Kuang (2010), “Is Structural Unemployment on the Rise?” Federal
Reserve Bank of San Francisco, FRBSF Economic Letter 2010-34 (November 8),
www.frbsf.org/publications/economics/letter/2010/el2010-34.pdf.

- 12 factor, as sharp increases in layoffs overwhelm the matching process. It may also be that
during serious downturns, more workers who would have given up looking for a job
continue to look in order to qualify for extended and emergency unemployment benefits,
or that employers take longer to fill vacancies when the labor market is weak.9
An analysis by Federal Reserve Board economists that decomposes the shift in the
Beveridge curve into its various components does point to some increase in structural
unemployment related to a reduction in the efficiency with which unemployed workers
are matched to vacant jobs--that is, mismatch.10 However, the estimated increase is fairly
modest--on the order of 1 percentage point--relative to the total increase in the
unemployment rate experienced in recent years. The remainder appears mainly related to
the delays in filling open positions that I mentioned a moment ago.
Economists at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York conducted a broader study
of the mismatch issue. By examining imbalances between the occupations, industries,
and geographic locations in which vacancies are concentrated and those in which
unemployment is concentrated, they constructed an index of potential mismatch. They,
too, concluded that mismatches accounted for only a small amount of the increase in the
unemployment rate during the recession--on the order of ¾ to 1½ percentage points.11

9

On the effects of unemployment benefits, see Robert Valletta and Katherine Kuang (2010), “Extended
Unemployment and UI Benefits,” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, FRBSF Economic Letter
2010-12 (April 19), www.frbsf.org/publications/economics/letter/2010/el2010-12.pdf. On the lag between
job vacancies and hiring, see Steven J. Davis, R. Jason Faberman, and John C. Haltiwanger (2010), “The
Establishment-Level Behavior of Vacancies and Hiring,” NBER Working Paper Series 16265 (Cambridge,
Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research, August), www.nber.org/papers/w16265.pdf.
10
See Regis Barnichon and Andrew Figura (2010), “What Drives Movements in the Unemployment Rate?
A Decomposition of the Beveridge Curve,” Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2010-48
(Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, August),
www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/feds/2010/201048/201048pap.pdf.
11
See Ayegül ahin, Joseph Song, Giorgio Topa, and Giovanni L. Violante (2011), “Measuring Mismatch
in the U.S. Labor Market,” unpublished paper, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, July,
http://nyfedeconomists.org/topa/USmismatch_v14.pdf.

- 13 In sum, I do not think arguments suggesting that structural factors account for
most of the increase in unemployment are persuasive, either individually or collectively.
Our efforts to quantify the increase in structural unemployment since the onset of the
recession find that it accounts for less than one-fourth of the difference between today’s
unemployment rate and that which prevailed in the pre-crisis years.
Before leaving this subject, I want to mention a different version of the structural
unemployment argument, which is the concern that high unemployment today will result
in an increase in structural unemployment in the future--a form of the phenomenon
known as hysteresis. The unusually long duration of unemployment spells and high
fraction of the labor force unemployed for more than six months raise the prospect that
the long-term unemployed will become progressively less employable as their skills,
reputations, and networks deteriorate. That is, the distinction between cyclical and
structural unemployment may begin to blur. In the aggregate, such effects could result in
a persistently higher level of structural unemployment, a persistently lower rate of labor
force participation, and a concomitant decline in the level of potential output of the entire
economy. Whole cadres of workers, whether younger people leaving school at a time of
high unemployment or older workers losing long-time jobs, might never regain the career
trajectory on which they were headed.
In the past, such effects do not appear to have been very significant in the United
States, and there is little evidence that they have taken hold today. But the current
unprecedented durations of unemployment may reduce the relevance of historical
experience. Even if the rise in structural unemployment is relatively modest to date, the
longer the labor market remains weak, the greater the risk that structural unemployment

- 14 will become more of a problem. Of course, if anything, this possibility argues for moreaggressive policies to reduce unemployment sooner.12
Effective Policy Responses
The policy issues presented by today’s labor market problems are challenging, to
say the least. There is need, and ample room, for additional measures to increase
aggregate demand in the near to medium term, particularly in light of the limited upside
risks to inflation over the medium term.
Unlike in the aftermath of the steep recessions of the mid-1970s and early 1980s,
demand growth has not become sufficiently self-sustaining to produce the strong
recovery that followed those earlier episodes. Of the nine quarters that have passed since
positive GDP growth reappeared in the third quarter of 2009, the rate of growth was
significantly above trend in only three--the fourth quarter of 2009 and the first two
quarters of 2010. These quarters were probably the first to benefit significantly from the
effects of the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act, passed earlier in 2009.
Up until quite recently, the dominant metaphor one heard for the economy was
that it was on its way to a healthy recovery but was hitting occasional “soft patches.”
This reading of the data always seemed to me quite optimistic. Now, I believe, nearly

12

Another line of argument is that the sluggish recovery in the labor market, and in the economy more
generally, is a result of wage rigidity. According to this view, prospective workers are unwilling to accept
wage rates low enough to induce businesses to hire and increase production. However, it is hard to see why
this phenomenon would be any stronger now than in earlier recessions, when a greater fraction of the U.S.
workforce was covered by collective-bargaining agreements. Moreover, there would seem to be little
indication in the wage data to support the idea that wage rigidity is having a major influence on
unemployment. Wage rates have decelerated across a broad range of industries and occupations, and unit
labor costs have fallen sharply. A simple histogram of the distribution of nominal wage changes in recent
years does show a spike at zero, indicating some resistance to reductions in nominal wage rates, but the
spike does not seem particularly large relative to those in earlier recessions. In any case, because the
difficulties suggested by this argument arise from the interaction between nominal wage rigidity and a
deficiency of aggregate demand, the most straightforward way to overcome problems caused by nominal
wage rigidity would be to expand aggregate demand.

- 15 everyone has toned down their expectations. I think the better metaphor is of an
economy slogging through the mud and occasionally hitting stretches of dry pavement,
which may well have been associated with the peak effects of fiscal and monetary policy
initiatives. The economy’s difficulty in gaining traction is, of course, due in no small part
to the continued high levels of unemployment and underemployment, which constrain
demand through both direct effects on household income and indirect effects in sapping
consumer confidence.
Yet it seems quite likely that there is something at work beyond an adverse
feedback loop involving personal consumption expenditures, investment, and
employment. The obvious candidate for that additional factor is the high amount of
debt--particularly household debt--that accumulated before the financial crisis. With the
bursting of the housing bubble, debt levels that may have looked manageable to
consumers who believed their homes were appreciating suddenly appeared burdensome
as house prices declined. In some parts of the country, this decline was dizzyingly rapid.
There has been some progress in working off or writing down some forms of debt, such
as credit card balances. But housing continues to hang like an albatross around the necks
of homeowners and the economy as a whole, with millions of underwater mortgages, a
staggering inventory of foreclosed homes, and depressed levels of sales.
What, then, are the policies best suited to increase aggregate demand? It must
first be said that neither monetary nor fiscal policy will be able to fill the whole aggregate
demand shortfall quickly. But appropriate policies could surely boost output and
employment. There have also been suggestions that attempts to boost aggregate demand
will be unsuccessful when the amount of debt overhang is significant. I agree that

- 16 without more effective efforts to address the manifold problems affecting the housing
market, there is a good chance that the recovery will lack strong momentum for some
time to come. But aggregate demand policies are still important. For one thing, debts
will surely be less burdensome as incomes rise. Moreover, the confluence of housing
debt and aggregate demand problems suggests that particular attention should be paid to
policies that could buttress aggregate demand while addressing at least some housing
market problems.
As you know, the FOMC has maintained the federal funds rate near zero for
almost three years in response to the extraordinary economic and financial problems
faced by the country. With short-term rates already about as low as they can go, the
FOMC has also taken some unconventional measures to provide additional monetary
accommodation. The combined effect of these monetary policies helped stabilize
financial markets in 2009, hold deflation at bay in 2010, and support a modest recovery.
But, in the absence of favorable developments in the coming months, there will be a
strong case for additional measures.
Some have argued that monetary policy should do no more, and that the political
branches of government should adopt fiscal or other policies to encourage increased
economic activity and job creation. I certainly do not disagree that well-conceived
policies by other parts of the government could produce gains in employment,
investment, and spending. But the absence of such policies cannot be an excuse for the
Federal Reserve to ignore its own statutory mandate. The Federal Reserve Act requires
that the FOMC promote the goals of maximum employment and stable prices. The
statute does not qualify that mandate by saying that we should promote these goals only

- 17 if all parts of the government--or, for that matter, the private sector--are acting just the
way we think they should. In other words, we have to take the world as we find it and
adjust our actions accordingly. Sometimes that will mean tighter monetary policy to
offset the inflationary effects of other policies. Sometimes, as at present, it will mean
more accommodative policies, even when we know that monetary policy alone cannot
solve all the economy’s problems.
Within the FOMC and in the broader policy community, there has been
considerable discussion of possible additional accommodative measures, from
communication strategies such as forward guidance on the likely path of the federal funds
rate to additional balance sheet operations. I believe we should move back up toward the
top of the list of options the large-scale purchase of additional mortgage-backed securities
(MBS), something the FOMC first did in November 2008 and then in greater amounts
beginning in March 2009 in order to provide more support to mortgage lending and
housing markets.
In November 2010, when the FOMC initiated another large-scale asset purchase
program, only U.S. Treasury securities were involved, in large part because of a desire to
return, once the recovery was well established, as quickly as possible to a Federal
Reserve balance sheet that did not contain other kinds of assets. A related concern of
some was that the purchase of MBS was a form of credit allocation, rather than simply
monetary policy that lowered long-term rates for all borrowers. For similar reasons, the
proceeds of agency securities accumulated pursuant to the first large-scale asset purchase
program were reinvested in Treasury securities rather than in other agency securities.

- 18 At the September FOMC meeting, we changed our reinvestment policy so that the
proceeds of maturing agency securities will now be reinvested in new MBS. Yields on
longer-duration Treasury securities had trended down appreciably in the late summer in
response to market demand, safe-haven flows, and diminishing expectations for growth.
Even though nominal MBS rates had also declined somewhat, spreads to Treasury yields
had, over the course of the year, widened noticeably. Since this announced change in
reinvestment policy, spreads on lower-coupon MBS have narrowed, but they remain
higher than they were early this year.
A large-scale MBS purchase program has many of the benefits associated with
purchases of longer-duration Treasury securities, such as inducing investors to shift to
other assets, including bonds and equities. But it could also have more direct effects on
the housing market. By increasing demand for MBS, such a program should reduce the
effective yield on those MBS, which in turn should put downward pressure on mortgage
rates. The aggregate demand effect should be felt not just in new home purchases, but
also in the added purchasing power of existing homeowners who are able to refinance.
Indeed, homeowners who refinance get the equivalent of a permanent tax cut.13
Concerns about central banks making sectoral credit allocation decisions are
understandable in general. But here we are talking about a widely traded instrument in a
sector that appears, now more than ever, to be central to the slow pace of recovery.
Now, I should note that the mortgage market is quite segmented. One relatively
small group of borrowers has extremely good credit and funds for sizable down
13

Of course, the income gained by consumers is lost to the holders of the mortgages that are prepaid as
homeowners refinance. But there are two reasons to believe that aggregate demand would increase. First,
the marginal propensity to consume of the average homeowner is almost surely higher than that of the
average holder of a mortgage-backed security. Second, to the extent that MBS are held by central banks or
foreign investors, the decreased income would not translate into reduced spending.

- 19 payments. That group can readily obtain a mortgage. The other, much larger group lacks
one or both advantages, and it faces much greater hurdles in the mortgage market. So
there is some chance that the principal effect of renewed MBS purchases would be to
allow those in the first group who have already refinanced to do so once again or to buy a
new home at a somewhat lower mortgage rate. These outcomes would be helpful, but the
effectiveness of an MBS purchase program would be amplified, perhaps significantly, if
certain nonmonetary policies were changed.
Proposals for promoting refinancing have been made by many academics,
policymakers, and policy analysts. Any proposals that could sensibly and effectively be
implemented would increase the effect of an MBS purchase program. For example,
action could be taken to bring the benefits of refinancing to underwater borrowers. In
principle, borrowers with mortgages that are guaranteed by government-sponsored
enterprises (GSEs) such as Fannie Mae and that have loan-to-value ratios of up to 125
percent can refinance through the Home Affordable Refinance Program. In practice,
though, numerous obstacles have kept the program from helping many potentially
eligible borrowers. Underwater borrowers whose loans are not guaranteed by GSEs are
essentially unable to refinance at all. Policy changes directed at this last, larger group of
homeowners would have to be carefully designed so as not to transfer credit risk from
private investors to the government, and could well require legislation.
Needless to say, though, an MBS repurchase program will not cure all that ails the
housing market, much less fill the whole aggregate demand shortfall. There is a host of
other problems, including continuing issues in mortgage servicing, uncertainty as to when
house prices will have bottomed out in local markets, ambiguity about the scope of

- 20 putback risk for securitized mortgages, and the substantial part of the underwater
mortgage problem that cannot be solved by refinancing. But I believe that MBS
purchases are worth considering as a monetary policy option precisely because they carry
the promise of addressing the feature of the current aggregate demand shortfall that
differs from typical recessions and recoveries.
Conclusion
Many labor market problems took years to develop, and they will not be
remedied quickly. The employment situation we hope for will require an extended
commitment over many years. As I said earlier, I am not even going to try to do justice
to the longer-term employment policy agenda. It is easy to echo the nearly universal call
for improvements in education, innovation in retraining, and other more effective labor
market policies. It is harder to specify what those policies are, much less how to fund
them. But I do want to emphasize that the challenge is more than determining which
education and training policies are both effective and affordable.
The nation needs a model for economic growth that will generate innovation and
productivity enhancements that will, in turn, generate the kinds of jobs for which we hope
we are educating and training our people. For much of the past decade, the implicit
growth model was too heavily dependent on the assumption of ever-rising home prices.
Needless to say, that model did not work out so well. Elements of the needed model
include a healthy macroeconomic environment and a well-functioning financial system.
But there should also be a premium on measures that expand the growth potential of the
country even as they support near-term economic activity.

- 21 Even the acute problems reflected in today’s grim employment picture cannot be
reversed as quickly as in past recoveries, precisely because the recent recession arose
from a financial crisis that was in turn the result of asset bubbles and high levels of
unsustainable debt. But the fact that these problems cannot be solved quickly does not
mean there is nothing to be done. Without more, the harm to the unemployed and their
families continues, and the risks of longer-term harm increase--both to the unemployed
and to the country as a whole. A shortfall of aggregate demand is the most important
factor behind those dismal statistics. Particularly if we take account of the unusual nature
of the current shortfall in fashioning policy responses, there is much that government
policy--including monetary policy--can still do.