View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
10:15 a.m. EDT
October 21, 2016

Pedagogy and Scholarship in a Post-Crisis World

Remarks by
Daniel K. Tarullo
Member
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at
Conference on the New Pedagogy of Financial Regulation
Columbia Law School
New York, New York

October 21, 2016

Let me begin with the most prosaic of observations: The events of 2007-09 will be
remembered not as a banking crisis, but as a financial crisis. Neither the origins nor the
transmission of stress were limited to the traditional banking system of commercial banks and
thrifts. While Wachovia and Washington Mutual failed, and other large depository institutions
survived only because of government support, the more spectacular failures were those of
nonbank financial firms--including American International Group (AIG), Bear Stearns, Lehman
Brothers, and the government-sponsored enterprises Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. Repurchase
agreement (repo) and commercial paper markets depended on government liquidity to continue
operating, as did money market funds.
It is thus unsurprising that, in approaching regulatory reform after the crisis, both the
official sector and academics have focused more on the financial system as a whole. The shift is
apparent in the very diction of post-crisis regulatory initiatives. The Dodd-Frank Wall Street
Reform and Consumer Protection Act (Dodd-Frank Act) refers dozens of times to “financial
stability” and “systemic risk.” A special regulatory structure has been developed for “G-SIBs”-that is, banks of global systemic importance--and a new category of designated systemically
important nonbank financial companies has been created. This shift is also reflected in the titles
and intellectual approaches of the two books that were discussed at this conference earlier this
morning--that is, financial regulation. The authors of both books have eschewed the traditional
concentration on banking or securities law alone, and have even moved beyond the more
innovative pre-crisis casebooks that focused on the differential regulation of various forms of
financial institutions. 1

1

Howell E. Jackson and Edward J. Symons, Jr. (1999), Regulation of Financial Institutions (St. Paul, MN: West
Group).

1

This broader category of “financial regulation” as the relevant delineation of an academic
subject area seems right to me. For one thing, different forms of financial intermediation are--if
not equally attractive for the preferences of specific investors and users of capital--at least
significantly overlapping in the roles they can play. Beginning in the 1970s these overlaps
multiplied, as the traditional separation of lending and capital market activities--which had been
reinforced by the Glass-Steagall Act--began to break down under the weight of macroeconomic
turbulence, technological and business innovation, and competition. In the 30 years that
followed, these activities were progressively integrated further, both within bank holding
companies and beyond, ultimately producing the explosive growth of money market,
securitization, and derivative instruments.
More fundamentally, the broader category of “financial regulation” reflects the
importance of a macroprudential, or systemic, perspective on the financial system. This means
taking account of the relationships among the circumstances and activities of significant financial
actors through such channels as funding dependencies and correlated assets. The financial crisis
has made what was formerly a minority view--the need to incorporate systemic considerations
into the regulatory regime--into something approaching a consensus.
But this shift of perspective--whether in pedagogy or in policy--raises as many questions
as it answers. My remarks this morning will detail some of the questions that have recurred in
regulatory deliberations in recent years, which I believe to be salient for policy, scholarship, and
pedagogy. Then, more briefly, I will make a few observations about teaching and scholarship
from the broadened perspective of financial regulation. I should note at the outset that, in the
interest of time, I will confine myself to the prudential aspects of financial regulation.

2

Thinking Through a More Integrated Approach to Financial Regulation
It is only moderately reductionist to say that, from the New Deal through the crisis, the
nature and scope of regulation was determined by the categorization of financial actors. If an
entity was classified as a bank or a broker-dealer or an investment company, it was subject to a
regulatory regime fashioned to deal with the risks associated with that form of intermediation or,
perhaps more precisely, the risks that were perceived to be so associated. Such an approach
always provided for some interesting legal discussions, since forms of intermediation that served
similar purposes and carried broadly similar risks might be subject to quite different regulatory
constraints.
But when, as noted earlier, nonbank forms of intermediation began to threaten traditional
bank intermediation and when, in what was at least partly an effort to maintain the franchise
value of commercial banks, strictures on bank activities and affiliations were significantly
relaxed, the foundation of the New Deal regime was substantially eroded. With the notable
exception of an increased emphasis on capital, which itself was decidedly microprudential in
focus, the prudential regime was not shored up or extended to other kinds of intermediaries,
much less replaced--a signal failure that contributed to the severity of the crisis. This may be a
good point at which to note in passing that the pre-crisis failures were not limited to the
underappreciation of systemic or macroprudential risks. Even from a purely microprudential
perspective, for example, the Basel II changes to the capital requirements for large banks were
ill-conceived. 2
A natural reaction to this legacy might be to shift from a regime based predominantly on
the form of an intermediary to one built predominantly on its functions. As a practical matter,

2

See Daniel K. Tarullo (2008), Banking on Basel: The Future of International Financial Regulation (Washington,
DC: Peter G. Peterson Institute for International Economics), pp. 178-82.

3

though, much post-crisis regulatory reform has been directed at strengthening the traditional
form-based foundation, though perhaps to a somewhat greater degree in the United States than in
some other financially important jurisdictions. And, at a conceptual level, some features of
particular forms of intermediaries--such as being an insured depository institution rather than a
money market fund--remain rightly important for regulatory purposes. So we will probably
continue to build on a form-based regulatory regime, though the potential range of
complementary function-based measures could be quite extensive. And, at the very least,
analyses based on function rather than form can be valuable heuristic exercises for identifying
inconsistencies and lacunae in the financial regulatory system.
A first set of questions follows from just such an identification of gaps in the regulatory
system, which are arguably most troubling when they relate to systemic considerations--that is,
when a financial intermediary or activity may contribute to risk in the financial system because
of the related positions or activities of others. Two critical gaps highlighted by the crisis were
the inadequate prudential regulation of the most systemically important financial institutions
(SIFIs) and the sometimes nonexistent prudential regulation of the many activities now
denominated as “shadow banking.”
The SIFI issue has received the most public attention, often in the context of too-big-tofail concerns. It was at the center of some of the most notable provisions of the Dodd-Frank Act,
many of which follow from the important principle enunciated in section 165 that prudential
regulation should become increasingly stringent for institutions of greater systemic importance.
Precisely because a satisfactory treatment of this topic would require at least one lengthy speech
on its own, it seems reasonably clear that teaching and scholarship should highlight the SIFI

4

problem, appraise the regulatory approach toward such institutions since the crisis, and consider
alternatives.
An appraisal of whether more or, as some would have it, fewer measures are needed
under the approach taken in the Dodd-Frank Act and related regulatory actions will, I admit, be a
little challenging. Some measures--including stress testing, capital requirements, and resolution
planning--are still in train, and others may be forthcoming as a result of the research program the
Federal Reserve is launching to consider the potential for additional explicitly macroprudential
features in capital and liquidity stress testing. 3 Still, I think it is feasible to teach and assess the
general approach of using multiple regulatory tools that impose requirements that force
systemically important firms to internalize the costs their distress or failure would impose on the
financial system, and then leaving the regulated firms to make decisions as to how to alter their
size and activities in order to make themselves most profitable within the stricter regulatory
constraints. This approach can be usefully compared to structural or other approaches to the SIFI
issue, such as caps on overall size or reimposition of the Glass-Steagall separation of commercial
and investment banking.
In addressing this topic, I have found it useful to try to specify as clearly as possible the
adverse systemic consequences that may be feared by public authorities confronting the possible
failure of a systemically important institution. This exercise helps identify the regulatory
measures that would be most effective in promoting the resiliency and orderly resolvability of
such institutions. On virtually any short list of concerns would be reliance on short-term
wholesale funding sources, which may dry up quickly under stressed conditions. A firm with

3

See Daniel K. Tarullo (2016), “Next Steps in the Evolution of Stress Testing,” speech delivered at the Yale
University School of Management Leaders Forum, New Haven, CT, September 26.

5

inadequate sources of liquidity may then be forced into responses with systemic implications,
such as fire sales of assets and termination of credit extensions to their own counterparties.
The other major vulnerability revealed by the financial crisis was systemic risk that may
be created through so-called shadow banking activities--that is, credit intermediation outside the
prudentially regulated banking system. Here is where the integration of traditional lending and
capital markets is most clearly in evidence, albeit in quite different ways. In truth, many shadow
banking channels passed through prudentially regulated institutions, as with the notorious
structured investment vehicles and asset-backed commercial paper conduits. Changes in
accounting and in bank capital and liquidity requirements have done a great deal to guard against
a recurrence of such patterns in the future, though continued monitoring will be needed to
prevent the development of other forms of support that elude these regulatory measures.
Of greater interest for financial regulation going forward will be the constantly changing,
and largely unrelated, set of intermediation activities pursued by very different types of financial
market actors. While the extent of shadow banking has significantly diminished since the crisis,
there is good reason to believe that it will grow in the future. Indeed, the very rigor of new
regulations applicable to firms within the prudential perimeter may well incentivize more
innovation outside that perimeter. It will be essential to disaggregate all the activities that might
be characterized as shadow banking in order to regulate those that pose risks to the financial
system while not unduly burdening forms of credit extension that may more or less benignly help
meet the savings and investment needs of households and businesses. This task is perhaps
summed up by the fact that activities which in one context are called “shadow banking” are in
other contexts called “market-based financing.”

6

One might fairly characterize the current regulatory approach to shadow banking as one
that examines, in turn, significant forms of credit intermediation outside the banking system and
determines whether some type of prudential regulation is needed. In the terms I introduced a
moment ago, regulators look at a particular form, such as money market funds. If no significant
risks to financial stability are identified, or if some regulation to counteract those risks is
implemented, the form of intermediation may then be thought of as relatively safe (at least from
a systemic perspective) market-based finance. The virtue of this approach is that it allows for a
very tailored regulatory response. But, as you can imagine, this approach necessarily involves a
good bit of active oversight on an ongoing basis, both of measures previously taken and of new
channels of nonbank intermediation as they arise.
An alternative approach would be to define shadow banking in broadly applicable terms,
with specified regulatory consequences that ensue more or less automatically, regardless of
whether the entity conducting the shadow banking is otherwise subject to prudential regulation.
To date, the attempts I have seen along these lines look likely to entail substantial overinclusion,
substantial underinclusion, or regulatory consequences that are inappropriately uniform. And, in
the United States and other jurisdictions, it is not clear that authority exists to take this approach,
either by an individual regulatory agency or even collectively. But, as with hypothesizing a
functionally-based regulatory system more generally, hypothesizing a broadly applicable
regulatory definition can usefully inform the direction of the current regulatory approach of
activity-by-activity scrutiny.
Of course, while the current approach allows for an ad hoc consideration of the
particulars of each activity, it still requires at least a general filter for identifying sources of
systemic risk. My own sense is that the greatest risks to financial stability lie in activities with

7

vulnerability to funding runs and asset fire sales. These may be associated either with some of
the same kinds of short-term funding found in systemically important banking organizations or
in the potential for rapid and substantial investor redemptions of their holdings in certain
investment funds. Where substantial leverage--either nominal or synthetic--is also present, the
risks are only greater. Efforts to calibrate these, and possibly other, risks will remain an
important feature of shadow banking regulation, along with refining ways in which such risks
may be mitigated.
Before turning to another, though related, set of questions, let me digress a bit to note
another implication of a regime in which regulation is developed with a view to risks to the
financial system as a whole. The motivation both for more stringent regulation of systemically
important firms and for regulation of shadow banking arises in large part from the potential
contribution of each to systemwide contagion. A complementary motivation for some
macroprudential measures is the importance of maintaining effective financial intermediation
even during a period of severe recession or financial stress. But this reasoning should, I think,
move us toward less regulatory stringency for some parts of the financial system, as well as
greater stringency in other parts. For example, as banking regulation is strengthened to take
account of the progressively more systemic significance of larger or more complicated
institutions, there is a good argument for a less demanding regime for smaller institutions whose
contribution to systemic contagion would almost surely be somewhere between modest and
inconsequential. This observation raises the issue, which I have discussed previously, as to
whether even within a particular form-based area of financial regulation we should be moving
toward quite different regimes. 4

4

See, e.g., Daniel K. Tarullo (2014), “Rethinking the Aims of Prudential Regulation,” speech delivered at the
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Bank Structure Conference, Chicago, IL, May 8.

8

The next set of questions raised by a systemwide perspective on financial regulation can
be described much more briefly. It pertains to the appropriate target once a need for regulation
has been established. The selection among, and mix of targets for, systemically-motivated
regulation will be an important determinant of the character of financial regulation in the years
ahead.
The relevant choices here are frequently identified in binary terms--that is, the regulation
may be directed either at financial institutions or financial activities. This leads to confusion
because, for example, what has been described as an “activities-based” approach to dealing with
the potential risks posed by certain asset management activities actually involves regulation of
the firms involved in those activities, such as through liquidity and risk management
requirements. I suspect this confusion has arisen because, in the minds of some, “institutionbased” regulation has become close to synonymous with banking regulation. Thus those
opposed to, say, capital requirements for a particular kind of intermediary will advocate for
activities-based regulation.
My own sense is that it is useful to distinguish three possible targets of regulation-specific financial institutions, financial business models, and financial transactions. Most
financial regulation, historically and contemporaneously, falls within what I would describe as
business model regulation. So, for example, any entity engaged in the “business of banking” is
subject to the panoply of requirements found in Title 12 of the U.S. Code. Similarly, the
requirements imposed on money market funds by the Securities and Exchange Commission
(SEC), and being considered for application to asset management activities, are also targeted at a
business model, even though the kind of regulation is quite different from that applicable to
insured depository institutions.

9

In contrast, my taxonomy would categorize regulation as targeted at a specific institution
when it applies because of the particular characteristics of that institution, not simply because of
its business model (or models). Thus, the designation of a nonbanking firm as systemically
important by the Financial Stability Oversight Council (FSOC) under the authority of the DoddFrank Act is made because the size, portfolios, activities, and other characteristics of the specific
firm are found on an individualized basis to meet the statutory standard of nonbank systemic
importance. Similarly, the determination of the capital surcharge applicable to SIFIs is made on
the basis of the particular “systemic footprint” of the firm.
Finally, a transaction-based requirement is one that would be binding on anyone involved
in such a transaction (with perhaps some de minimis exceptions), regardless of their status as a
particular kind of financial intermediary. An example would be the minimum margining
requirements on securities financing transactions that have been agreed to at the Financial
Stability Board (FSB), which the Federal Reserve will be proposing through a rulemaking next
year.
Of course, a particular firm may be a target under two, or possibly all three, approaches.
But it is important to identify clearly why a regulation is deemed necessary and, accordingly,
how it should be targeted. In the framework I have set forth, for example, institution-specific
measures may be thought of as those needed to protect financial stability even though a firm is
already subject to business model regulation. And a transaction-based measure may be thought
of as one needed to protect financial stability regardless of whether all entities that might engage
in such a transaction need to be regulated because of the risks associated with their business
models.

10

My third set of questions pertains to the scope and allocation of government authority for
financial regulation. With some relatively modest exceptions, authority in the New Deal regime
was determined based on the distinct regulatory aims established for different kinds of financial
intermediaries, the oversight of which was assigned to different agencies. The allocation
basically followed the Glass-Steagall Act’s separation of commercial and investment banking.
But, over time, both markets and regulatory change complicated this fairly simple picture:
markets complicated this as both banks and broker-dealers invented new ways of doing business
that allowed each to take on risks previously reserved for the other, and regulatory changes saw
shifts in the relationship of the Federal Reserve’s authority as holding company regulator and
that of the SEC or Commodity Futures Trading Commission as primary regulator of important
nonbank holding company subsidiaries.
The additional regulatory authorities and mandates in the Dodd-Frank Act have created a
quite different landscape from the pre-crisis regulatory terrain. Many of these authorities and
mandates are explicitly tied to financial stability goals--a sharp departure from pre-crisis
circumstances. Many must be exercised jointly by two or more agencies--in rulemakings,
implementation, or both. And, of course, the Dodd-Frank Act created the FSOC--an unusual
entity in U.S. administrative law.
Appreciating this new configuration of authorities is important as a positive matter for
understanding how regulation will be shaped over time and identifying possible remaining gaps
in regulatory authority. It is also important as a normative matter in considering whether the
allocation of authorities proves optimal over time. Here one would want to look at factors of
efficacy, expertise, and excessive concentrations of authority, among others. In this regard, I

11

would suggest that a comparison of the reconfigured financial regulatory system in the United
Kingdom serves as an instructive counterpoint to the U.S. system.
Some Thoughts on Post-Crisis Scholarship Topics and Pedagogy
Scholarship
Insofar as I have succeeded in identifying questions that will be central to the further
development and refinement of a regulatory system that takes account of the financial system as
a whole, all of what I have already said should be fertile ground for legal and economic
scholarship. However, not every important topic for research fits neatly into one of these crosscutting issues, so let me mention some policy issues that may especially benefit from academic
work.
First is the issue of measures and standards for evaluating systemic risk. Numerous
financial economists have done very useful work in creating metrics for the systemic importance
of financial institutions--a literature that has already informed regulatory efforts to designate and
categorize such institutions and, as it develops further, will surely continue to do so. 5 But there
are also specific legal standards, such as the financial stability factor now mandated in the review
of proposed bank and holding company mergers, that could also benefit from academic work. 6
Second is the set of issues associated with corporate governance in a prudentially
regulated institution. John Armour, Lucien Bebchuk, Jeff Gordon, Jon Macey, and others have
already tackled some of these issues--such as incentive compensation arrangements, the

5

Tobias Adrian and Markus K. Brunnermeier (2016), “CoVaR,” American Economic Review, vol. 106 (July), pp.
1705-41; Fernando Duarte and Thomas M. Eisenback (2013; revised 2015), “Fire-Sale Spillovers and Systemic
Risk,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report, no. 645; and Christian T. Brownlees and Robert F. Engle
(2016), “SRISK: A Conditional Capital Shortfall Measure of Systemic Risk,” available at
https://ssrn.com/abstract=1611229 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1611229.
6
Daniel K. Tarullo (2012), “Financial Stability Regulation,” speech given at the University of Pennsylvania School
of Law Distinguished Jurist Lecture, Philadelphia, PA, October 10.

12

appropriate duties for boards of directors in such institutions, and the appropriate scope of
supervisory expectations for boards. 7 These issues remain worthy of discussion. The preceding
questions and others, such as the advisability of a requirement for a non-executive chair of the
board, have only grown in significance since I spoke to this topic a couple of years ago. 8
Third is the subject of overseeing the regulators, which includes such matters as the
advisability of publicly releasing some or all supervisory ratings and informal enforcement
actions. You may recall that our decision in 2009 to release the results of our stress test--a
practice that we have continued in subsequent years--was quite controversial, but has proven to
be enormously helpful both for giving investors in the firms and the public a better sense for how
the Federal Reserve is conducting its capital regulation policies.
Fourth is the rather broad topic of the implications of technological innovation for
financial services regulation and, indeed, for the competitive position of insured depository
institutions. Many innovations now promising dramatic change in the way that credit is
extended will probably end up having considerably less impact. But some could prove
significant. I suspect that innovations in payments systems are quite likely to have far-reaching
effects, including the growth of what might be termed the “shadow payment system” at the retail
level. Here, by the way, I am departing a bit from my self-limitation to prudential issues, since
consumer protection issues around alternative payments systems may be quite significant.

7

See, e.g., John Armour and Jeffrey Gordon (2014), “Systemic Harms and Shareholder Value,” Journal of Legal
Analysis, vol. 6, no. 1 (Spring), pp. 35-85; Lucian A. Bebchuk and Holger Spamann (2010), “Regulating Bankers’
Pay,” Georgetown Law Journal, vol. 98, no. 2, pp. 247-87; Jonathan Macey and Maureen O’Hara (2016), “Bank
Corporate Governance: A Proposal for the Post-Crisis World,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Economic
Policy Review, vol. 22, no. 1 (August), pp. 85-105.
8
Daniel K. Tarullo (2014), “Corporate Governance and Prudential Regulation,” speech given at the Association of
American Law Schools 2014 Midyear Meeting, Washington, DC, June 9.

13

Fifth is the organization of the international system for financial regulation. The issues
here are in some sense familiar from pre-crisis days: To what degree can host countries
responsibly rely on home jurisdiction consolidated regulation and supervision of large and
internationally active financial institutions? How should international cooperative efforts to set
minimum prudential standards be brought together with domestic legal processes for financial
regulation? These familiar questions have taken on new significance in light of the post-crisis
emphasis on the financial system as a whole, including the varieties of shadow banking. So too
the differing circumstances and legal systems of notable financial jurisdictions, which raise anew
the question of how much international harmonization is ultimately desirable. The creation of
the FSB, and greater emphasis on international standards in the International Organization of
Securities Commissions and the International Association of Insurance Supervisors have
substantially changed the relevant international organization chart from the days when only the
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision produced such standards.
Pedagogy
Having not taught financial regulation since the interesting months of the fall 2008
semester, I am probably at a comparative disadvantage to most of this audience in reflecting on
the new pedagogy of financial regulation. However, that will not stop me from making a couple
of comments--though only a couple--on the core topic of this conference.
First, I would urge everyone teaching in this area to place much more emphasis on the
liability side of the balance sheets of financial institutions. Traditional banking law casebooks
gave some treatment to deposits and deposit insurance, which provided a good point in a course
to engage students on the subject of moral hazard. But the whole concept of runnable liabilities-whether uninsured deposits, repo, commercial paper, or other forms--was left largely untouched,

14

even for commercial banks, much less for broker-dealers like Lehman Brothers or insurance
holding companies like AIG. And, of course, in the pre-crisis period there was no quantitative
liquidity regulation to include in a casebook.
Yet the financial crisis was, at least in its more virulent periods, as much a funding crisis
as it was a solvency crisis. Indeed, the very fact that it may be difficult to distinguish clearly
between the two is indicative of the primacy of funding to the crisis. Particularly in the context
of systemic risk, funding and liquidity issues accordingly deserve something close to the
attention devoted to capital if students are to understand the origins of the crisis, the regulatory
response, and the challenges of regulation going forward. A focus on liabilities will help
students understand why, for example, the Federal Reserve plans on setting capital standards
differently for traditional insurance companies (that is, not the pre-crisis AIG) than for bank
holding companies and their affiliates. An emphasis on runnable funding will help them see why
systemic concerns extend beyond SIFIs as such. It also provides a good occasion for introducing
students to the role of a lender of last resort, now perhaps more of a contested concept than had
previously been assumed.
I have considerably less conviction regarding my second comment, but I offer it anyway,
perhaps to contribute to the pedagogical discussions that will be bred by this conference. Let me
preface the observation by noting that were I to teach financial regulation again, the course
would have to differ markedly from that fall 2008 version. Still, I wonder whether students will
acquire a strong enough foundation for understanding how a financial regulatory system works
in a course that is taught essentially as a survey of financial regulatory issues, without some point
of reference to which they can return as they proceed through the course (or, more probably, as
they cram for the exam). I was always struck by how much of a conceptual anchor for a banking

15

law course was provided by the famous Corrigan/Aspinwall debate on whether banks were
“special.” 9 One could note, for example, that Aspinwall’s observation that banks were becoming
less special might have suggested that other forms of intermediaries should be more regulated,
rather than the implication that banks should be less regulated. Indeed, my rereading of the
companion pieces suggests that despite--or maybe because of--the fact that the debate is now
more than 30 years old, it might profitably introduce a course that ventures well beyond
traditional banking regulation, by its invitation to consider why we regulate in the first place.
Conclusion
I began teaching in this area just as the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act was culminating three
decades of bank deregulation. At the time, I suggested to students that the regulation of banking
organizations was in an unstable equilibrium. While I initially meant the adjective mostly to
refer to doctrine, it became progressively more applicable to the financial system itself. The
implementation of the regulatory aims established after the crisis, along with the inevitable
refinements of what has already been done, will continue to play out for some time. The upshot,
I think, is both an unusually important time to be researching and writing in this area and an
unusually challenging time to be teaching it. This conference has been an excellent occasion for
helping to shape both a research agenda and a new pedagogy.

9

See E. Gerald Corrigan (1982), “Are Banks Special?” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Annual Report,
available at www.minneapolisfed.org/publications/annual-reports/are-banks-special; and Richard Aspinwall (1983),
“On the ‘Specialness’ of Banking,” Issues in Banking Regulation, vol. 7 (Autumn), pp. 16-22.

16