View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
12:15 p.m. EST
November 9, 2011

The Evolution of Capital Regulation

Remarks by
Daniel K. Tarullo
Member
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
to the
Clearing House Business Meeting and Conference

New York, N.Y.
November 9, 2011


A little over three years ago, Lehman Brothers ignited the dry tinder of a badly
overleveraged financial system that was too dependent on continuous, significant increases in
housing prices and too opaque for supervisors, investors, analysts, and often participants
themselves to understand. As one would expect of a truly systemic crisis, there were many
contributing factors--the prevailing statutory framework for financial regulation, supervisory
practices, and the risk-management practices of financial actors. And, as one would thus expect,
the reform agenda has itself also been multi-dimensional.
For all the regulatory changes that are in place, in process, or under consideration,
however, I believe that capital regulation remains the single most important element of
prudential financial regulation. Let me immediately elaborate upon that statement in two ways.
First, capital regulation itself must be multi-dimensional and rigorous in each of its components.
Second, while strong capital regulation is necessary for a sound financial system, it is not, on its
own, sufficient. In my remarks this afternoon, I will concentrate on the first of these points and
discuss how capital regulation reform is evolving in the wake of the crisis.
Evolution and Shortcomings of Capital Regulation
Although they had long used bank capital ratios as a supervisory instrument, U.S. bank
regulators did not impose explicit minimum capital requirements until the 1980s. The proximate
reason for this change was regulatory concern over the decline in capital ratios of the largest
banks--a concern reinforced by Congress, as it saw some of those large banks facing enormous
losses on their loans to foreign sovereigns. Within a few years this U.S. regulatory innovation
was effectively internationalized by the original Basel Accord.
At the same time, regulators came to regard capital requirements as a supple prudential
tool. As activity and affiliation restrictions were loosened in the United States, capital

-2

requirements seemed a promising way to protect the public's interest in the stability of financial
institutions that had access to the Federal Reserve's discount window and Federal Deposit
Insurance Corporation insurance. Capital requirements promised to provide a buffer against
bank losses from any activities in which the bank or its affiliates might engage, a consideration
of equal or greater relevance in countries with universal banking models. Some support also
developed for the proposition that minimum capital levels could, by maintaining a material
equity value for the bank, serve as a disincentive for excessive risk-taking by management and
shareholders.
In the ensuing quarter century, banking regulators around the world focused considerable
attention toward elaborating capital requirements to reflect more precisely the particular risks
faced by a financial institution. Capital requirements had, to a considerable extent, become the
dominant prudential regulatory tool.
The financial crisis showed that this concentrated, almost all-consuming regulatory focus
on refining bank capital requirements in Basel II had come at the expense of attention to other
risks in the financial system. In particular, banking regulators failed to appreciate fully the
implications of the growth--in size, leverage, and maturity transformation levels--of the shadow
banking system for the balance sheets of commercial banks and for overall financial stability.
The crisis showed that liquidity problems can be an independent source of severe stress, perhaps
even for firms that might otherwise have remained solvent.
But it was also evident that the specifics of pre-crisis capital regulation fell far short of
what this prudential instrument can achieve. The Basel I and Basel II capital requirements relied
almost exclusively on capital ratios that were essentially snapshots of balance sheets and thus all
too often a lagging indicator of a bank's condition. Declines in asset values--particularly of non-



-3

traded assets--were often not reflected in capital calculations for some time. Though already
well-known before the crisis, this phenomenon was particularly problematic as asset values
declined rapidly, causing both markets and supervisors alike to regard regulatory capital ratios as
providing only limited information about a firm's current financial condition.
In addition, minimum capital levels had simply been set too low, in general and with
respect to particular assets. One of the most obvious examples was the capital requirement for
asset-backed securities in the trading books of banks. The requirement was based on returns
over a 10-day holding period, used a one-year observation period that had been characterized by
unusually low price volatility, and did not adequately account for the credit risks inherent in
these traded instruments.
Furthermore, at least some of the instruments that qualified as "Tier 1 capital" for
regulatory purposes were not reliable buffers against losses, at least not on a going concern basis.
It is instructive that during the height of the crisis, counterparties and other market actors looked
almost exclusively to the amount of tangible common equity held by financial institutions in
evaluating the creditworthiness and overall stability of those institutions. They essentially
ignored the Tier 1 and total risk-based capital ratios in regulatory requirements. In the fall of
2008, there was widespread doubt in markets that the common equity of some of our largest
institutions was sufficient to withstand the losses that those firms appeared to be facing. This
doubt made investors and counterparties increasingly reluctant to deal with those firms,
contributing to the severe liquidity strains that characterized financial markets at the time.
Finally, the crisis validated the concerns expressed by some academics and by policy
staff at the Bank for International Settlements that the effectiveness of capital regulation was
limited by its exclusively microprudential focus. Capital requirements had been set with



-4

reference solely to the balance sheet of a specific firm. The risk weights assigned to the firm's
assets were calculated with reference to ordinary times, whether through a supervisory
determination or a combination of supervisory formulas and a firm's own modeling. This
microprudential focus did not take into account the potential impact of a shock to the value of
widely-held assets--whether exogenous, caused by the distress sales of such assets by a large
firm suffering particularly severe problems, or, as in the financial crisis, a lethal interaction
between these two factors.
The limits of the microprudential approach were particularly evident with respect to very
large, interconnected firms. There would be very substantial negative externalities associated
with the disorderly failure of any such firm, distinct from the costs incurred by the firm and its
stakeholders. The failure of one large firm, especially in a period of stress, significantly
increases the chances that other financial firms will fail, for two reasons. First, direct
counterparty impacts can lead to a classic domino effect. Second, because losses in a tail event
are much more likely to be correlated for firms deeply engaged in trading, structured products,
and other capital market instruments, all such firms are vulnerable to accelerating losses as
troubled firms sell their assets into a declining market.
Reform of Capital Regulation in the Post-Crisis Period
It is obvious that the post-crisis regulatory system will not be as dependent on capital
requirements as the pre-crisis regime. Dodd-Frank itself is testimony to this fact, as are a
number of changes already made by the bank regulatory agencies. There is now increased
emphasis on market discipline, liquidity regulation, activities restrictions, and more effective
supervision, in addition to capital requirements. Reforms for money market funds and the
triparty repo market, as well as more general attention to wholesale funding models for financial



-5

intermediation, are still needed. But the crisis reinforces the point that robust capital
requirements should continue to be a central component of the financial regulatory system. The
U.S. banking agencies made reform of the capital regime a high priority.
In response to the shortcomings of the pre-crisis capital regulatory regime, there have
been three complementary threads of reform. First is improvement of the traditional, individualfirm approach to capital regulation. This strand mostly originates in the work of the Basel
Committee. Basel 2.5 revised and strengthened the market risk requirements of Basel II. Basel
III upgraded the quality and increased the quantity of minimum capital requirements, created a
capital conservation buffer, and introduced an international leverage ratio requirement.
Second is the introduction of a macroprudential component of capital regulation.
Although Basel III does contain a few features responsive to macroprudential concerns, it
remains principally microprudential. This second thread is linked both to the requirement in
section 165 of the Dodd-Frank Act for enhanced risk-based capital standards for large bank
holding companies and to the Basel Committee's effort to develop a framework for the
assessment of a capital surcharge based on the global systemic importance of the largest, most
interconnected banking organizations.
Third is establishment of regular stress testing and capital planning. These
complementary supervisory tools serve two related functions. First, they make capital regulation
more forward-looking by subtracting losses in asset values and earnings estimated to be
sustained in an adverse macroeconomic scenario, in order to determine whether firms would
have enough capital to remain viable financial intermediaries. Second, they contribute to the
macroprudential dimension of capital regulation by examining simultaneously the risks of all
large financial institutions in the face of the adverse scenario. This reform thread is sourced in



-6

the Dodd-Frank requirement for stress testing at large banks, but more generally in the Federal
Reserve's establishment of a formal annual capital planning requirement for these firms.
The development and implementation of these three threads of capital reform are at
different stages, so it may be useful to review where each stands. As to the first--improving the
traditional, individual-firm approach to capital regulation--Basel 2.5 and Basel III are important
steps forward, both internationally and domestically. In addition, the so-called “Collins
amendment” in Dodd-Frank requires that banking organizations maintain capital at levels no
lower than those set by “generally applicable” requirements, which include a standardized
approach to risk-weighting. In practice, the Collins amendment provides a safeguard against
declines in minimum capital requirements in a capital regime based on internal modeling.
The Basel Committee completed work on Basel 2.5 and Basel III in 2009 and 2010,
respectively. Implementation of these two frameworks into national legislation or regulations is
underway in the jurisdictions represented on the committee.1
Two issues concerning implementation in the United States bear mentioning. First, while
U.S. bank regulatory agencies have published a proposed regulation for the new market risk
capital requirements, we did not include the trading book securitization and resecuritization
portions of Basel 2.5, which are supposed to take effect in 2011. The complication here, and
with part of Basel III implementation, lies in the use of agency credit ratings. Dodd-Frank
requires the removal of agency credit ratings from all regulations throughout the government.
Thus, the banking agencies have had to develop substitutes for agency ratings in each of the
quite different contexts in which they are used within the capital standards. This has not been the
easiest of tasks, but I believe we are now close to convergence on the approaches we will take in


Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2011), Progress Report on Basel III Implementation (Bank for
International Settlements: Basel, Switzerland, October), www.bis.org/publ/bcbs203.pdf.
1



-7

fashioning these substitutes. We should soon be able to draft a proposed regulation for the rest
of Basel 2.5. Work on the Basel III rule has had to compete for staff time with all the other
rulemakings currently underway at the banking agencies, but I would expect a proposed
regulation in the first quarter of 2012.
The second issue pertains to the six-year transition period for Basel III, which by its
terms phases in the requirements for both the improved quality and increased quantity of capital
in somewhat backloaded stages beginning in January 2013. Questions have arisen as to
supervisory expectations for capital levels during this rather lengthy period. Specifically, there
has been some uncertainty as to whether supervisors intend to “pull forward” the various
transition points outlined in Basel III. While the Federal Reserve intends to ensure that firms are
on a steady path to full Basel III compliance, we do not intend to require firms to raise external
capital or to reduce their risk-weighted assets in order to meet any new requirement earlier than
at the time specified in the Basel III transition schedule. However, because this issue is
complicated somewhat both by certain expectations stated in Basel III and by the relationship of
Basel III implementation to the Federal Reserve’s requirement for annual capital planning by
certain large bank holding companies, it may be useful to provide some further details on our
expectations.
In the first place, the Federal Reserve will require bank holding companies that are
subject to our proposed capital plan rule (generally companies with $50 billion or more in total
assets) to take affirmative steps to improve capital ratios, such as external capital raises, when
those steps would be needed to meet each Basel III transition target on time.
Next, it is important to note a statement made by the Governors and Heads of Supervision
(GHOS)--the oversight body of the Basel Committee--in announcing agreement on Basel III in



-8

September 2010. The GHOS said that banks should “maintain prudent earnings retention
policies” so as to meet both the new minimum equity standard and the conservation buffer “as
soon as reasonably possible.”2 In the spirit of that statement, we will expect large bank holding
companies that have not yet met the fully phased-in Basel III requirements (including any
expected capital surcharge for globally systemically important banks) to improve their capital
ratios steadily during the transition period through prudent earnings retention policies, even if
they already meet any applicable intermediate targets. In practical terms, we will monitor their
progress through the annual capital planning exercise, about which I shall have more to say a bit
later in these remarks. We will be comfortable with proposed capital distributions only when we
are convinced they are consistent with a bank holding company readily and without difficulty
meeting the new capital requirements as they come into effect.
Turning now to the second thread of capital regulation reform, the introduction of a
capital requirement keyed to the systemic importance of financial firms, I am sure you are all
aware that last Friday the Basel Committee released its framework for calibrating capital
surcharges for banks of global systemic importance. This initiative is consistent with the Federal
Reserve’s obligation under section 165 of the Dodd-Frank Act to impose more stringent capital
standards on systemically important financial institutions, including the requirement that these
additional standards be graduated based on the systemic importance of the bank. Both the DoddFrank provision and the Basel framework are informed by the fact that the failure of a
systemically important firm would have substantially greater negative consequences on the
financial system than the failure of other firms, even quite sizeable ones. Yet obviously such a
firm has no incentive to take account of these negative externalities. An ancillary rationale is

2

See Bank for International Settlements (2010), “Group of Governors and Heads of Supervision Announces Higher
Global Minimum Capital Standards,” press release, September 12, www.bis.org/press/p100912.htm.



-9

that additional capital requirements could help offset any funding advantage derived from the
perceived status of such institutions as too-big-to-fail.
The surcharge attempts to reduce the chances of a global systemically important bank’s
(G-SIB’s) failure so as to bring the expected impact of the failure of such a firm--that is, the
expected damage to the system upon its failure discounted by the possibility that it will, in fact,
fail--more in line with that of other sizeable firms. Moreover, the metrics for determining G-SIB
status are heavily weighted toward the kind of interconnectedness features that pose
macroprudential risks. The framework includes a range of surcharges in the 1.0–2.5 percent
range for what will likely be a global group of about 30 banks, to be phased in as an expansion of
the Basel III capital conservation buffer from 2016 to 2019.
For illustrative purposes, the Basel Committee used 2009 data to generate a list of banks
that were of global systemic importance and, based on the criteria developed from that data, a
hypothetical set of “buckets” associated with the different surcharge rates. It is important to
note, however, that this list, which was published last week, will not be used to determine any
bank’s surcharge. The list of banks to be covered and the surcharge buckets into which they will
be placed when the surcharge begins to take effect in 2016 will be based upon data collected in
2014. This is as it should be, since the inclusion and ordering of the firms should be based upon
the characteristics of the banks as they have evolved closer to the effective date. Some banks
have changed their profiles materially in the past couple of years, and the prospect of capital
surcharges may be an incentive for others to do so as well. In this regard, I should also note that
the bucket allocation of each G-SIB will be recomputed in each year after 2016.
The use of more up-to-date data means that banks will not know for some time exactly
which buckets they will occupy when the surcharge first phases in. However, the potential



- 10 

uncertainty associated with this approach should be substantially reduced by the plan to publish
an updated list of the covered financial institutions each November, along with an indication of
the bucket to which each firm would have been allocated based on data from the preceding year.
The Basel Committee will release by the latter part of 2014 additional information relevant to the
surcharges that will be applied beginning in 2016 -- the thresholds for each surcharge “bucket”
and the denominator reflecting the universe of global banking institutions against which each GSIB will be measured. To further advance the goals of transparency and predictability, we will
continue to work within the Basel Committee to ensure that the indicators used to determine the
systemic-risk ranking of a firm are clear and based upon publicly available information sources.
If additional information is needed by firms to allow for effective capital planning, the Basel
Committee should be prepared to develop and release additional guidance.
Dodd-Frank requires the Federal Reserve to impose more stringent capital requirements
on all bank holding companies with assets of $50 billion or more, not just the U.S. firms that are
on the list of G-SIBs and will thus have capital surcharges. No decision has yet been made as to
whether the more stringent capital requirement to be applied to firms other than those on the
eventual list of G-SIBs will be in the form of a surcharge. However, analysis of the systemic
footprints of other U.S. bank holding companies suggests that even if surcharges were to apply,
their amounts would be quite modest, at least based on current characteristics of the other bank
holding companies.
The third thread of reform in capital regulation is the establishment of regular stress
testing and capital planning. Unlike the first two threads, there is no international framework
that parallels our domestic changes, though stress testing is receiving increased attention in a
number of other jurisdictions. These reforms build on the stress test we performed at the height



- 11 

of the financial crisis in early 2009, which used an adverse macroeconomic scenario and
estimates of firm revenues and potential losses on a portfolio-specific basis to calculate the
amount of capital that each firm would need to remain a viable financial intermediary even were
the adverse scenario to materialize. The test was thus both forward-looking and horizontal,
meaning that the 19 largest U.S. bank holding companies were assessed in a simultaneous,
consistent fashion.
Dodd-Frank creates two kinds of stress testing requirements. First, it mandates that the
Federal Reserve Board conduct annual stress tests on all bank holding companies with $50
billion or more in assets to determine whether they have the capital needed to absorb losses in
baseline, adverse, and severely adverse economic conditions. Second, it requires both these
companies and certain other regulated financial firms with between $10 billion and $50 billion in
assets to conduct internal stress tests. The Board must both publish a summary of results of the
supervisory stress tests and issue regulations requiring firms to publish a summary of the
company-run stress tests.
Those who participated in the 2009 exercise, both at the banks and at regulatory agencies,
know that the resource demands associated with it were considerable. Yet the value of that effort
was also considerable, a fact that doubtless informed the Congressional decision to make the
practice mandatory. The exercise itself forces supervisors to focus on the nature and extent of
potential sources of loss for the largest bank holding companies as a group. The disclosure of
stress test results allows investors and other counterparties to better understand the profiles of
each institution. And, I believe, the demands of supervisors for well-specified data and
projections from firms has improved risk management at these institutions.



- 12 

We will be implementing the specific stress testing requirements of Dodd-Frank over the
next year. However, in the interim we are using a modified form of stress testing as part of the
annual capital planning process we have established for large bank holding companies. This
process goes well beyond a stress testing exercise. It requires firms to project their capital needs
and plans on a firm-specific basis, as well as with reference to more standardized stress
scenarios. It also allows us to review the safety and soundness of the firm's capital position,
including any plans it has for distributions of capital. As you will recall, in the absence of such a
capital review, some companies engaged in ill-advised, inappropriate capital distributions in the
period immediately preceding the financial crisis, leaving them less able to absorb the losses that
ensued.
We conducted a capital plan review early this year for the 19 firms that had been
involved in the 2009 stress test. In just a few weeks, we will begin the 2012 review. This
process integrates stress testing and decisions about capital adequacy and possible capital
distributions. It also gives supervisors insight into the risk measurement and risk management
capabilities of the firms. We are close to issuing a final regulation that will contain the basic
structure for this annual exercise.
The rule would extend this formal capital planning to all bank holding companies with
$50 billion or more in assets. The comments received on the proposed regulation issued in June
have been useful in crafting the final rule. I expect that the final rule would, among other things,
respond to the concern of some firms that the timing of the first capital planning process did not
provide for appropriate capital distributions in the first quarter of the succeeding calendar year.
Clarifications of some other issues that arose in the 2011 capital review will be addressed in the
documentation for the 2012 exercise--such as describing with more specificity what constitutes



- 13 

the kind of material change in the risks faced by a firm, such that a supplemental capital plan
would be needed during the course of the year.
It is important to note that the capital planning process, including the stress testing
component, provides supervisors with the opportunity to determine whether banking
organizations need to maintain capital ratios above the minimum levels specified in the various
Basel frameworks as implemented into U.S. law. Institution-specific capital measures of this
sort are explicitly contemplated in the Basel arrangements, in U.S. legislation, and in the
regulations of U.S. banking agencies. During the financial crisis, we used our safety-andsoundness authority to require banks to hold sufficient capital to weather the impact of the crisis
and the serious recession that followed. Similarly, our annual capital plan review is a forwardlooking exercise that, in estimating losses and reduced revenues that would follow an adverse
economic scenario, may result in requiring banks to maintain more capital than would a static,
backward-looking snapshot of minimum capital levels.
Conclusion
On a number of previous occasions, I have noted that, for all the disagreement over the
right set of financial reform measures, on one point there is near unanimity: No one wants
another TARP program. Not those who thought TARP was the best of a bad set of options in the
fall of 2008. Certainly not those who opposed it. Not the American people, many of whom saw
the injection of billions of dollars of government capital into financial firms as more a bail-out of
large banks than an imperative to stabilize the financial system. And not even, I suspect, most of
the large financial firms that received the government capital.
Each of what I have characterized as the three threads of capital regulation reform is still
in development. Domestically, there are notice-and-comment rulemakings still to be done in



- 14 

each area. Internationally, the Basel Committee will continue work on the indicators used in its
capital surcharge methodology and, of course, has yet to finalize the list of systemically
important banks and the assignment of those banks to the various surcharge buckets. In both
arenas it is important to move as quickly as feasible to complete all this work, so as to provide
more clarity to banks, markets, and the public on the details of capital requirements, while still
ensuring that the final regulations and requirements are well-crafted.
But if details are still lacking, the direction of these reforms is now clear. When fully
implemented, these reform strands together will increase significantly the safety and soundness
of the financial system and make much less likely the need for some future TARP. At a time
when there is considerable disagreement over the best direction for many aspects of financial
regulation, that result is one I suspect commands broad support among policymakers, policy
analysts, and the public.