View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
12:45 p.m. EDT
June 9, 2014

Corporate Governance and Prudential Regulation

Remarks by
Daniel K. Tarullo
Member
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at
Association of American Law Schools
Midyear Meeting
Washington, D.C.

June 9, 2014

It is a pleasure to be back among law professors here at the Association of American Law
Schools (AALS) Midyear Meeting. Let me begin by applauding the organizers for encouraging
collaboration between corporate and financial law scholars. Indeed, it is striking how much of
the insightful legal scholarship that followed the financial crisis has come from corporate law
scholars. On reflection, this outcome is not really surprising. After all, much corporate law
scholarship revolves around incentive structures, agency costs, and asymmetric information
flows--all matters of great relevance to financial regulation. Furthermore, legislatures and courts
have a long history of debating, and sometimes adopting, special corporate law and governance
rules for financial institutions.
In my remarks this afternoon I will try to further the collaboration between corporate and
financial law scholarship by suggesting how the nature of finance and financial regulation affects
corporate governance and why, in turn, special corporate governance measures are needed as
part of an effective prudential regulatory system. In making the latter argument, I will review
some of the measures, both longstanding and more recent, that illustrate the point and then
suggest some additional steps that might complement existing prudential regulations. Finally, I
will offer some more tentative thoughts on the possible implication of this analysis for corporate
law fiduciary duties. A theme running through these remarks will be the centrality of risk--its
assessment, assumption, and allocation--in understanding the relationship between corporate
governance and financial regulation.
Financial Firms and Corporate Governance
There are at least three significant ways in which the nature of financial activities and
regulation affect the operation of key mechanisms of corporate governance. 1

1

For a basic description of corporate governance mechanisms, see Mark J. Roe (2004), “The Institutions of
Corporate Governance,” in Claude Menard and Mary M. Shirley, eds., Handbook for New Institutional Economics

2

First, it has long been recognized that the unique features of deposit-taking financial
institutions raise the question whether generally applicable corporate law and governance
principles are adequate. Because banks are financial intermediaries that use deposits to provide
much, if not most, of the funding for their lending, an insolvent bank may well be unable to
satisfy all its deposit liabilities. The fear of this possibility lies at the heart of banking runs and
panics. In the days before federal deposit insurance, the impracticality of contractual solutions to
reduce the vulnerability of depositors led to a variant of normally applicable limited liability
rules. Many states enacted so-called double liability rules, whereby shareholders could be liable
for the losses of a failed bank in an amount equal, and in addition, to their investment in the
bank. Presumably, these rules were intended to change the calculus of shareholders as to the
risks they wished their banks to assume and, perhaps, the degree to which they monitored
management.
Following the creation of federal deposit insurance, a series of constraints on normal
corporate prerogatives has been applied to insured institutions, justified in large part by the need
to counteract the resulting moral hazard and to protect the federal deposit insurance fund (DIF).
Bank charters have always differed from general corporate charters insofar as they grant special
privileges and forbid certain activities by the chartered institutions. In addition, special
prudential requirements have always applied to chartered banks. Perhaps the most important of

(The Netherlands: Springer). Useful reviews of corporate governance in financial institutions, reflecting lessons
learned from the financial crisis, include Hamid Mehran and Lindsay Mollineaux (2012), “Corporate Governance of
Financial Institutions,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report No. 539 (New York: Federal Reserve Bank
of New York, February), available at www.newyorkfed.org/research/staff_reports/sr539.pdf; Hamid Mehran, Alan
Morrison, and Joel Shapiro (2011), “Corporate Governance and Banks: What Have We Learned from the Financial
Crisis?” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report No. 502 (New York: Federal Reserve Bank of New York,
June), available at www.newyorkfed.org/research/staff_reports/sr502.pdf; Moonrad Choudhry (2010), “Effective
Bank Corporate Governance: Observations from the Market Crash and Recommendations for Policy,” Journal of
Applied Finance & Banking, vol. 1 (1), pp. 179-211.

3

these today is the imposition of minimum capital requirements on all insured depository
institutions and bank holding companies.
Second, there is a variety of ways in which the attributes of financial markets and
financial regulation affect the capital market discipline assumed in much corporate governance
theory and corporate law. The prior point about the moral hazard associated with insured
deposits implies that--at least in traditional, deposit-reliant banks--the kind of market discipline
associated with the price of funding and creditor monitoring will be attenuated. More generally,
to the degree uninsured depositors or other bank creditors expect that they will be protected by
the government in the event the bank encounters serious difficulties, those same features of
market discipline will again be weakened. This, of course, is the problem of moral hazard
associated with too-big-to-fail perceptions, whereby investors or counterparties are willing to
extend credit at prices that do not fully reflect the risk associated with the bank. 2
The market discipline traditionally associated with the market for corporate control is
also affected by banking regulation and supervision. Mergers and acquisitions involving
banking organizations are subject to review, and possible disapproval, on a broad range of
grounds beyond the antitrust considerations relevant in all industries. These include an
assessment of the adequacy of the financial resources of the firms, the “competence, experience,
and integrity” of the officers and directors, and the impact of the acquisition on systemic risk. 3
Moreover, of course, any firm that acquires a commercial bank must be a bank holding company,
thereby subject to a range of activity restrictions and other regulatory requirements. There are
2

For an argument that shareholders who might otherwise press for breakups of financial conglomerates are
disincentivized from doing so for too-big-to-fail institutions, see Mark J. Roe (2014), “Structural Corporate
Degradation Due to Too-Big-to-Fail Finance,” University of Pennsylvania Law Review, vol. 162, pp. 1419-64
(forthcoming).
3
Bank Holding Company Act of 1956 §3, 12 U.S.C. §1842(c). The Bank Merger Act requires consideration of a
roughly comparable set of factors. Acquisitions are also subject to special scrutiny where an acquiring firm has lessthan-satisfactory supervisory ratings.

4

very good prudential reasons for these constraints upon acquisitions of, and by, banking
organizations. But, by screening out transactions that would result in unacceptable increases in
risk, either to an institution or to the financial system as a whole, these provisions may in some
cases unintentionally limit the salutary disciplining effect on boards and management of the
market for corporate control.
The third way in which the nature of financial activities and regulation affect the
operation of key mechanisms of corporate governance is that the risks associated with financial
intermediaries--especially those that are significantly leveraged and that engage in substantial
maturity transformation--pose a particular challenge for corporate governance. All firms bear
the risk that problems may unexpectedly arise because of, say, product flaws that were unknown
to boards of directors and perhaps even senior management. But in the case of financial
intermediaries, these problems can be incredibly fast-moving, including runs on funding that can
quickly place the very survival of the firm in doubt. These risks have increased during the past
25 years, as many institutions have combined traditional lending activities with capital markets
businesses that rely on other funding models. Accordingly, judgments about risk appetite and
control systems to manage risk must be effectively executed by senior management and overseen
by the board. This imperative, in turn, means that the information and monitoring processes and
systems established for, or available to, boards of financial institutions may need to be more
extensive than those in large, nonfinancial firms.
Financial Regulation and Corporate Governance
In the wake of the financial crisis, the public interest in regulation of banks and other
financial firms is, I think it fair to say, both self-evident and substantial. A full discussion of the

5

rationales for various forms of regulation is beyond the scope of my remarks today. 4 But let me
briefly note that prudential regulation has two distinct motivations--microprudential and
macroprudential.
Microprudential regulation is concerned largely with the safety and soundness of a
financial institution considered individually. It seeks to protect the DIF by combatting what
would otherwise be moral hazard and subsidized funding through capital requirements, activities
restrictions, and other measures. Because microprudential regulations were designed primarily
to minimize losses to the DIF, they have traditionally focused on insured depository institutions
(IDIs); the regulation of owners and affiliates of IDIs is essentially about ensuring that the
activities and risks of those other entities do not threaten the IDIs themselves. Up until the last
several years, microprudential regulation would have come close to covering the entire field of
prudential regulation.
The financial crisis highlighted the need to supplement traditional microprudential
regulation with a macroprudential approach oriented toward the well-being of the financial
system as a whole. Here there are two related objectives, both of which seek to avoid costs that
failure or severe stress would impose on the economy beyond those suffered by shareholders of a
financial firm. One is protecting against systemic risk--for example, the risk that certain
activities or the failure of a firm would result in very large negative externalities, either through a
classic domino effect or through contagion effects producing a financial crisis. Losses in a tail
event are likely to be correlated for large firms deeply engaged in trading and relying on short4

For more complete discussions of the reasons for prudential regulation, see Daniel K. Tarullo (2014), “Rethinking
the Aims of Prudential Regulation,” speech delivered at Bank Structure Conference, Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago, May 8, available at www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/tarullo20140508a.htm; Daniel K. Tarullo
(2014), “A Macroprudential Perspective on Regulating Large Financial Institutions,” in Banque de France,
Financial Stability Review, no. 18, available at www.banquefrance.fr/fileadmin/user_upload/banque_de_france/publications/FSR18_Tarullo.pdf. Consumer and investor
protection, anti-money-laundering efforts, and other nonprudential aims provide additional bases for regulation of
financial institutions.

6

term wholesale funding. This objective, long neglected in financial regulation, is prominently
featured in post-crisis statutory, regulatory, and supervisory reforms. The Dodd-Frank Wall
Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act (Dodd-Frank Act) explicitly establishes financial
stability and the containment of systemic risk as the aim of dozens of new regulatory provisions. 5
Thus, for example, any firm whose failure could pose systemic risk is subject to prudential
regulation, quite apart from its relationship with IDIs.
A second objective of macroprudential regulation is to avoid a harmful contraction of
credit availability in significant regions or sectors of the economy, even if there were little
chance of a financial crisis. This outcome could ensue were banks accounting for a material
portion of credit extension simultaneously to come under solvency or funding pressures that
caused them to pull back from lending. The importance of both macroprudential objectives is
that the regulatory framework should aim to reduce the chances of transmission of systemic risk
by such firms to a greater extent than traditional, microprudential regulation would.
But even stipulating these crucial objectives, why should prudential regulation need to
involve itself with corporate governance? After all, there are many important forms of
regulation applicable to corporations. A regulatory field may establish certain behavioral norms,
require conformity with certain product or byproduct characteristics, or prohibit certain
activities. Corporations are expected to conform to these obligations, many of which are
extensive and detailed. While some regulatory systems require certain procedures within the
regulated entities--particularly as remedial measures following violations--few, if any, create
specific and significant ongoing requirements for corporate decisionmaking or oversight.

5

Some of the more important of these provisions are discussed in Daniel K. Tarullo (2012), “Financial Stability
Regulation,” speech delivered at the Distinguished Jurist Lecture, University of Pennsylvania Law School,
Philadelphia, Pennsylvania, October 10, available at
www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/tarullo20121010a.htm.

7

Corporate and securities law may establish a duty of management and directors to limit
regulatory violations, but the rationale for these duties is to protect shareholders from the
consequences of regulatory violation, not directly to further the public regulatory objective. 6
The answer, I think, lies at least in part with the centrality and nature of risk in the
activities of financial intermediaries. Risk-taking--whether well- or ill-considered--is perhaps
the central activity of all financial intermediaries. Where those intermediaries are significantly
leveraged and engaged in maturity transformation, the risk-taking carries substantial potential
societal consequences beyond the possible losses to investors, counterparties, and employees of
the financial firm. Microprudential and macroprudential regulation each respond to this
divergence between the private and social balances of costs and benefits associated with a given
level of risk-taking by financial intermediaries.
The focus of microprudential regulation is on the distortions to funding costs that may
arise when depositors or capital markets do not require the funds they provide fully to price in
the risks assumed by banks in using those funds, whether because of federal deposit insurance or
expectations of a government safety net. The focus of macroprudential regulation is on the
negative externalities that large financial firms can impose on the rest of the economy. In both
instances, the private assessment by shareholders and their representatives of the risk-reward
tradeoffs of the financial firm’s activities will differ from the public’s assessment of that riskreward tradeoff. That is, while the public has an interest in healthy, profitable banks, and thus
the interests of shareholders and the public overlap, they are not coincident.

6

For a discussion of this duty, particularly as applied to financial institutions, see Eric J. Pan (2010), “The Duty to
Monitor under Delaware Law: From Caremark to Citigroup,” The Conference Board, Director Notes, No. DN-004,
available at www.conference-board.org/retrievefile.cfm?filename=DN-004-10.pdf&type=subsite.

8

At root, then, prudential regulation seeks to influence risk-taking in regulated entities.
But this is difficult to do directly. Conceptually, “risk” is not reducible to a single metric, such
as--for example--the density of particulate matter in the emissions of a power plant. Practically
speaking, a financial institution more or less continually makes risk decisions, the circumstances
of which can vary substantially over time, across asset classes, and even contemporaneously in a
single asset class based on the differing circumstances of borrowers or counterparties.
Prudential rules can limit or prohibit certain bank activities that are thought to be
particularly risky. With respect to activities that are permitted, prudential regulation can
indirectly influence corporate decisions on risk-taking by requiring minimum amounts of capital
to be held by the regulated firms. But, fundamental as they are to contemporary prudential
regulation, capital requirements--particularly static, backward-looking standards--will
necessarily be somewhat imprecisely related to the range of actual risk incident to specific assets
or transactions within the various risk categories established by the capital regime. In fact, the
capital regime may itself invite arbitrage, as firms look to maximize risk-taking within regulatory
risk categories. 7
Thus it is also important for prudential regulation to influence the processes of risktaking within regulated financial firms as a complementary tool to capital requirements and other
substantive measures. This view is reflected in various banking laws, most notably in the DoddFrank Act requirement that all bank holding companies with $10 billion or more in assets have a
risk committee, composed of independent directors and “responsible for the oversight of the

7

Of course, strong capital requirements also build a loss absorption buffer that is useful in dealing with risks gone
bad ex post, even if they cannot entirely contain those risks ex ante.

9

enterprisewide risk management practices” of the firm. 8 This provision in itself requires only
that the bank holding companies have capable and independent risk committees that, by
extension, should be overseeing well-developed risk-management practices and systems of
controls in the firms. It does not specify what the risk appetite of the firm should be. However,
its inclusion in section 165 of the Dodd-Frank Act, which requires an array of additional
prudential measures directed at firms that could pose threats to financial stability, suggests that
the risk-committee mandate has a prudential motivation.
Of course, good risk management is important for shareholders as well. Regulatory
prods for efficient management information systems and well-developed risk-assessment
procedures should generally be welcomed by shareholders. Similarly, regulatory insistence on
capable and independent oversight of risk management is consonant with shareholder interests,
which might be damaged by employees who exercise poor judgment or whose compensation
structures may incentivize them to take risks not desirable for the firm as a whole. To a
considerable extent, then, fostering sound risk-management practices serves the overlapping
interests of both shareholders and regulators.
The possible divergence of interests comes not in the architecture of risk management but
in substantive decisions on risk appetite. How, then, might corporate governance be changed to
incorporate risk considerations consistent with micro- and macroprudential regulatory
objectives? One way would be to broaden the fiduciary duties of boards and management. The
other, which has already been followed to some degree, is to apply regulatory and supervisory
requirements to relevant corporate governance processes. Of course, realization of the first
approach would require either changes in state corporate law or amendments to federal securities
8

Dodd-Frank Act §165(h). This provision further requires that the risk committee include “at least one risk
management expert having experience in identifying, assessing, and managing risk exposures of large, complex
firms.”

10

or financial regulatory statutes. I shall speak briefly to this possibility after describing some
examples of the second approach already in place, along with some possibilities for further
measures.
Aligning Corporate Governance and Financial Regulation
With no claim to comprehensiveness, let me suggest three kinds of regulatory and
supervisory measures that can better align corporate governance of financial firms with
regulatory objectives.
First, regulatory requirements can be directed at changing the incentives of those making
decisions within a financial firm. One good example is incentive compensation for senior
managers and other bank employees with substantial decisionmaking authority. Compensation
arrangements that create high-powered incentives using stock options or other forms of reward
dominantly based on equity have their origins in efforts better to align management and
shareholder interests. Otherwise, managers who stand to suffer reputational or job loss as their
firm declines or fails may have a more conservative risk appetite than diversified shareholders,
who value the upside of risk-taking and whose limited liability makes them relatively less
concerned with catastrophic downside possibilities. As has been observed by numerous
commentators, 9 however, where these kinds of incentive compensation arrangements have
succeeded in better aligning the interests of shareholders and employees, they intensify the
conflict between shareholder and regulatory interests. 10 Ironically, regulatory objectives match

9

See, for example, Lucian Bebchuk and Holger Spamann (2010), “Regulating Bankers’ Pay,” Georgetown Law
Journal, vol. 98 (2), pp. 247-87; and Kenneth R. French, M. N. Baily, J. Y. Campbell, J. H. Cochrane, D. W.
Diamond, D. Duffie, A. K. Kashyap, F. S. Mishkin, R. G. Rajan, D. S. Scharfstein, R. J. Shiller, H. S. Shin, M. J.
Slaughter, J. C. Stein, and R. M. Stulz (2010), The Squam Lake Report: Fixing the Financial System (Princeton:
Princeton University Press).
10
Indeed, if the incentives are powerful enough, they may give employees a greater risk appetite than even
diversified shareholders are presumed to have.

11

up better with the old-style managers for whom the preservation of the firm is considerably more
important than for shareholders.
Various suggestions for change have been made. Some have proposed making incentive
compensation packages more closely reflect the composition of the liability side of a banking
organization’s balance sheet by including returns on debt, as well as equity, instruments in the
calculation of compensation. 11 Others have proposed the much simpler approach of making a
significant part of incentive compensation deferred and subject to clawback and forfeiture, with
the employee’s ultimate right to the compensation dependent on the firm not having become
insolvent, received government assistance, or experienced a similar triggering event. While
developing the details of an effective mechanism that also allows for motivating employees to
advance shareholder interests will take some work, some measure along these lines is key to
adjusting incentives so as to promote prudential objectives across the many risk decisions made
within the firm.
Incentive realignment can also be achieved by fostering more of the capital market
discipline that has, as explained earlier, been limited. One example is a byproduct of measures
to increase the total loss absorbency of systemically important financial firms by requiring
minimum amounts of debt that could be converted to equity upon a firm’s insolvency. As you
may know, the Federal Reserve Board intends to issue a proposed rulemaking that would
implement such a requirement at the largest financial firms. While the principal motivation of
such a requirement is to help ensure that even a very large financial firm can be resolved in an
orderly fashion without the injection of public capital, identifying debt instruments as convertible

11

See Bebchuk and Spamann, “Regulating Bankers’ Pay.” Depending on how closely one would want to tie
compensation to the prices of bonds, for example, there may be difficulties owing to the potential at times for
interest rate risk fluctuations to overwhelm credit risk fluctuations in the price of debt instruments. Interest rate risk
fluctuations would not reflect the performance or risk associated with a specific firm.

12

to equity in a context where resolution is a credible option should make the price of those
instruments especially sensitive to the relative risk of failure of those firms. Requiring
systemically important financial firms to issue a meaningful amount of long-term debt would
indirectly influence corporate governance by introducing at-risk debt holders as a constituency
whose concerns management must monitor and address.
A second kind of measure to align corporate governance at financial firms more closely
to regulatory objectives is a substantive requirement or constraint upon decisions made within
the firm. As a practical matter, it would be hard to develop a rule setting a comprehensive risk
appetite consonant with regulatory objectives. However, there are regulatory requirements that
can serve as partial surrogates for such a rule. A good example, already in place, is a feature of
the Federal Reserve’s program of stress testing and capital planning. A firm may not make
capital distributions (whether in the form of dividends or capital repurchases) that would, when
added to losses under hypothesized adverse scenarios as projected in our annual supervisory
stress test, reduce the firm’s capital below certain minimum levels.
When we adopted this rule several years ago, we were criticized by some for encroaching
on the prerogative of boards of directors of financial firms to decide on capital distribution
policies, in accordance with general corporate governance practice. This criticism has always
seemed to me misplaced. After all, banking regulators are not only permitted, but obliged, to set
minimum capital requirements at banking organizations and other systemically important
financial firms. Limiting capital distributions is, conceptually, no different from requiring a firm
to build capital in the first place. 12 A regulation designed to maintain minimum capital levels in
large banking organizations in a projected period of stress is consistent with the macroprudential

12

Indeed, insured depository institutions are prohibited by statute from making any capital distribution that would
render the firm undercapitalized. 12 U.S.C. §1831o(d)(1).

13

objectives discussed earlier. Indeed, these requirements counteract the practices seen at some
banks in the run-up to the financial crisis, whereby boards of directors continued to return capital
to shareholders even as conditions deteriorated severely. 13 Tying capital levels to corporate
governance decisions about capital distributions simply recognizes that capital levels and capital
distributions are two sides of the same coin.
A third kind of measure seeks to affect the institutions and processes of corporate
governance, rather than directly to change incentive structures or regulate decisions. Many
possible actions of this sort would really be efforts to improve the risk-assessment and riskmanagement capacities of management and boards, rather than to focus specifically on the
divergence between shareholder and regulatory interests with respect to risk appetite. An
effective system of controls is important both to shareholders and to regulators. Thus, for
instance, the considerable and continuing emphasis we have placed on firms developing and
maintaining effective management information systems makes risk assessment work better for
shareholders, even as it facilitates supervisory oversight.
With respect to the institutional features of board oversight of risk management, there is
also substantial overlap in the interests of shareholders and regulators. For example, both
shareholders and supervisors should expect a board to include members with the expertise,
experience, and time commitment that are appropriate to risk management of the kinds of
activities in which the financial firm engages. Of particular interest are three board positions-the nonexecutive chair or lead director, the head of the risk committee, and the head of the audit
committee. More generally, shareholders and supervisors must have confidence that globally
active institutions with hundreds of thousands of employees have audit and risk committees with
13

Beverly Hirtle (2014), “Bank Holding Company Dividends and Repurchases during the Financial Crisis,”
Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report No. 666 (New York: Federal Reserve Bank of New York,
March), available at www.newyorkfed.org/research/staff_reports/sr666.html.

14

the practical ability to provide effective oversight of risk decisions. 14 I might note in passing that
regular discussion between board members and supervisors can also serve the interests of
shareholders, since supervisors may have an informed perspective on the firm’s operations that
enables boards better to fulfill their strategic and risk-oversight functions.
Supervisors should also expect a well-conceived process for board review of major firm
decisions, which will nearly always carry some implications for risk management and risk
appetite. In practical terms, such a process would connect decisions on strategy, risk-appetite
setting, and capital planning. Neither we nor shareholders should be comfortable with a process
in which strategic decisions are made in one silo, risk-appetite setting in another, and capital
planning in yet a third, with the convergence of these efforts coming together only when it is too
late for each to affect the other, or for the board to be able to exercise effective oversight. These
major decisions need to be made in an integrated manner.
While regulators should have clear expectations for boards, we need to make sure that we
are creating expectations that lead to boards spending more time overseeing the risk-management
and control functions I have emphasized this afternoon. There are many important regulatory
requirements applicable to large financial firms. Boards must of course be aware of those
requirements and must help ensure that good corporate compliance systems are in place. But it
has perhaps become a little too reflexive a reaction on the part of regulators to jump from the
observation that a regulation is important to the conclusion that the board must certify
compliance through its own processes. We should probably be somewhat more selective in
14

There have also been proposals that boards of large financial firms have a small staff, independent of
management, who can help the board sift through the often voluminous materials delivered by management to foster
informed inquiries of management and decisions on risk appetite. For example, a proposal for a “dedicated
secretariat” was offered by a parliamentary committee in the United Kingdom. See U.K. House of Commons
Treasury Committee (2009), Banking Crisis: Reforming Corporate Governance and Pay in the City, (London:
House of Commons, May), available at
www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/cm200809/cmselect/cmtreasy/519/519.pdf.

15

creating the regulatory checklist for board compliance and regular consideration. One example,
drawn from Federal Reserve practice, is the recent supervisory guidance requiring that every
notice of a “Matter Requiring Attention” (MRA) issued by supervisors must be reviewed, and
compliance signed off, by the board of directors. 15 There are some MRAs that clearly should
come to the board’s attention, but the failure to discriminate among them is almost surely
distracting from strategic and risk-related analyses and oversight by boards.
One might ask how the strengthening of systems of controls and risk-appetite decision
processes can promote achievement of regulatory interests beyond those shared with the owners
of firms. One answer is that it clearly improves the supervisory line-of-sight into the safety and
soundness of financial firms. The more timely and accurate the information that can be
aggregated by supervisors, the more responsive our supervisory and financial stability oversight
can be. A well-developed set of risk and control functions also allows an effective point of entry
for pursuing certain regulatory objectives. To date, the best example of this potential is our
annual supervisory stress tests and Comprehensive Capital Analysis and Review (CCAR) to
which I have already referred.
As a substantive matter, the CCAR requirements limit capital distributions of large
financial institutions based upon a forward-looking assessment of the losses that would be
suffered under hypothetical adverse economic scenarios, so that capital will be built and
maintained at levels high enough for the firms to remain viable financial intermediaries even
under such stressed conditions. In addition to the microprudential improvement that comes from

15

An MRA is a supervisory finding that the Federal Reserve communicates to the firm and requires
remediation. For more information, see Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Division of Banking
Supervision and Regulation (2013), “Supervisory Considerations for the Communication of Supervisory Findings,”
Supervision and Regulation Letter SR 13-13 (June 17), www.federalreserve.gov/bankinforeg/srletters/sr1313.htm.

16

substituting a dynamic for a static capital calculation, there is an important macroprudential
motivation, reflected in the design of scenarios and the required levels of post-stress capital.
The efficacy of the CCAR process is substantially enhanced as the information systems
and internal risk-management capacities of the firm improve. Beyond this important, but
discrete regulatory measure, well-developed processes for determining risk appetite give
supervisors better insight into risks specific to the activities and strategic decisions of each firm.
As a result, supervisors should be better able to identify points at which a firm’s risk-taking may
diverge from that which is consistent with microprudential and macroprudential objectives.
This, in turn, should permit more timely supervisory or regulatory responses.
Regulatory Objectives and Fiduciary Duties
The regulatory focus on risk in corporate governance will produce additional examples of
each of the three kinds of measures I have just described. For instance, the Office of the
Comptroller of the Currency has recently proposed guidance for risk governance at large national
banks. 16 Still, particularly with an audience half composed of corporate law professors, it is
natural to ask whether corporate law tools might usefully supplement regulatory measures.
Specifically, the question arises as to whether the fiduciary duties of the boards of regulated
financial firms should be modified to reflect what I have characterized as regulatory objectives.
Doing so might make the boards of financial firms responsive to the broader interests implicated
by their risk-taking decisions even where regulatory and supervisory measures had not
anticipated or addressed a particular issue. And, of course, the courts would thereby be available
as another route for managing the divergence between private and social interests in risk-taking.

16

U.S. Department of the Treasury, Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (2014), Guidelines Establishing
Heightened Standards for Certain Large Insured National Banks, Insured Federal Savings Associations, and Insured
Federal Branches; Integration of Regulations, 79 Fed. Reg. 4282 (January 27).

17

As I noted at the outset, there is a long history of actual or considered measures to alter
the duties or liabilities of those with decisionmaking authority in the corporate governance of
banks. A more contemporary variant on these ideas was offered a little over a decade ago by Jon
Macey and Maureen O’Hara, who proposed expanded fiduciary duties for directors of insured
banks, including giving bank creditors the right to sue for violations of these duties. 17 In a
provocative recent paper, John Armour and Jeff Gordon suggest that the duties of directors of
systemically important financial institutions should be modified precisely because diversified
shareholders have a strong interest in avoiding risk decisions by these institutions that increase
systemic risk. 18 Their analysis implies that the customary tension between regulatory and
diversified shareholders’ interests may be considerably mitigated in the case of systemically
important firms whose failure could result in financial turbulence and consequent economic loss
for the entire economy.
A consideration of the merits of these or other such proposals is beyond the scope of my
remarks today. Obviously, any such changes in corporate law are beyond the authority of the
Federal Reserve. I mention them in the hope and anticipation that corporate law scholars will
continue to evaluate such ideas, since whatever one’s eventual conclusions on their desirability,
the analytic process is sure to yield further insights into the key question of how best to respond
to the points of divergence between shareholder and regulatory interests in risk-taking by large
financial firms.

17

Jonathan R. Macey and Maureen O’Hara (2003), “The Corporate Governance of Banks,” Federal Reserve Bank of
New York, Economic Policy Review, vol. 9 (April), pp. 91-107.
18
John Armour and Jeffrey N. Gordon (2013), “Systemic Harms and Shareholder Value,” European Corporate
Governance Institute Working Paper No. 222 (Brussels: ECGI, August), available at
http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2307959.

18

Conclusion
In the wake of the financial crisis, the changes in finance, in financial regulation, and in
the relationship among government agencies that carry out prudential regulation have created
any number of opportunities for financial law scholars to collaborate with their colleagues in
other disciplines--from administrative law to constitutional law to bankruptcy law. This
collaboration is perhaps natural, since major shocks to the economy, and thus the country, have
in the past occasioned legal changes whose implications reached far beyond the original area of
reform. As I hope you can tell from my remarks today, I have already found the interaction
between corporate and financial law scholarship to have been helpful in thinking through the
policies that will shape a safer financial system. I look forward to the fruits of the collaborations
encouraged by the event sponsored today.

19