View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

SPEECH

Progress toward Financial Integration and Financial Stability
October 20, 2013
Christine M. Cumming, First Vice President
Remarks at the SEACEN 30th Anniversary Conference, Kuala Lumpur, Malaysia
As prepared for delivery

It is a privilege to be here today at this conference celebrating the 30th anniversary of SEACEN. Thank you to the SEACEN Centre
for inviting me to participate, and congratulations to the Centre on the launch of the new SEACEN Financial Stability Journal.
We are at a good moment to consider financial integration, its benefits and costs, its prospects, and its challenges. We have gained
a few years’ distance and some perspective on the causes and consequences of the global financial crisis that began in the United
States and Europe. We have seen for more than a decade sustained growth in many regions of the world, especially Asia, above
that in the advanced economies, with important implications for the distribution of global income, wealth and financial activity.
In addition, the global financial crisis and the accompanying Great Recession in the advanced economies have produced a long list
of challenges for central banks and supervisors: reform of the regulatory framework for global, systemically important financial
institutions, strengthening of the financial infrastructure, and significant new efforts to monitor financial stability and proactively
address vulnerabilities and threats. Central banks within the advanced economies are conducting unconventional monetary policy
to combat the continuing sluggishness in their economies. All central banks are seeking to understand the channels of
transmission of these new approaches to monetary policy and the zero-bound interest rate environment. The transmission
channel to emerging market financial markets is important to study, both because of the market turbulence we’ve seen this year
and the potential effects on emerging market economies and overall global growth.
In my remarks today, I will focus on the prospects for continued financial integration and then three challenges associated with
stabilizing a financial system in which financial integration is substantial and advancing. As always, I will be expressing my own
views and not those of the Federal Reserve System or the Federal Reserve Bank of New York.
Increasing Financial Integration
Modern financial integration really began in earnest with the resumption of international trade and financial activity in the 1960s.
It is now 40 years since the postwar fixed-rate exchange-rate regime gave way to a more flexible, floating regime. Significant
financial deregulation soon followed in the advanced economies, where such features as interest rate ceilings and credit controls
were not uncommon in the 1970s. Several waves of liberalization reduced long-standing post-war restrictions on capital flows.
Much of this liberalization took place because strong market forces made fixed exchange rates and the old controls on domestic
financial activity and international capital flows increasingly ineffective and expensive to maintain. At the same time, market and
technology forces also reshaped large parts of the financial sector, eventually producing the very large global financial institutions
we have today.
Without question, global financial integration has advanced substantially over the last 30 years. The measurement of financial
integration, however, is difficult.
Financial integration is often measured by the size of cross-border financial flows. Those flows over the past decade provide a very
mixed message about progress in international financial integration. But interpreting flows during that period is complicated by
our realization in hindsight of just how much the run up to the financial crisis distorted real and financial activity over this period.
The tremendous expansion of U.S. housing finance, its amplification through the repackaging of risk exposures for global
distribution, and the large rise in household and financial leverage created a volume of finance that was unsustainable. Quite
possibly, that financial climate played some role in fostering strong capital flows to the emerging market economies. After the
financial crisis, the unwinding of those exposures and the continuing impact of the recession depressed financial activity,
including with it, capital flows. Moreover, the challenging macroeconomic impacts in the advanced economies and the resulting
policy responses to them have no doubt contributed to volatility in those capital flows.
Yet capital flows are simply our proxy for the hard-to-observe features of financial integration. The benchmark for full financial
integration is pricing of global financial assets that enables an efficient allocation of global resources. Two characteristics we
might look for as signs of that pricing mechanism. One is the completeness of markets, including, for example, capital markets for
business and government and markets for household credit. A second is greater convergence in the distribution of risk-adjusted
interest rates and financial prices in national markets around financial prices in international markets. Such convergence may
require strengthening the risk profile of financial institutions and financial activity in local markets as well as eliminating barriers

and business practices that create a “wedge” between international and national financial prices.
So rather than look at the slowdown of capital flows since the financial crisis as a sign that financial integration is decreasing and
may be difficult to restart, we could look closely at developments outside the advanced economies and come to a very different
conclusion—that financial integration is continuing now and will persist in the future. I see three ongoing drivers of integration.
First, the composition of global GDP has changed markedly in the last decade—the share of the advanced economies has fallen
from roughly 80 percent to just over 60 percent today; and that of the rest of the world has doubled, with the rise in share most
pronounced in Asia. The rise in incomes and standards of living around the world creates new consumer and business credit
demand. Since investment, economic activity and finance gravitate to where incomes are growing, this redistribution of global
income increases the impetus to financial integration.
Second, the continuing shift away from policy instruments that fix prices and quantities, such as interest rate ceilings, credit
controls and capital flow restrictions, is another force behind continuing financial integration. As national or regional
policymakers turn toward the use of open market operations and regulatory capital requirements, they are using instruments that
seek to influence, but not determine market prices and the cost of capital. This shift in policy instruments promotes the
interaction of national policies to occur in the price domain, rather than the quantity domain.
Finally, we have the continuing efforts around the world to strengthen the regulatory framework and financial infrastructure.
Through forums such as the SEACEN Centre, the Asia-Pacific region has been working to strengthen prudential supervision and
explore greater regional integration, including the development of regional capital markets. Those efforts are likely to contribute
to the greater completeness and alignment of financial marketplaces that is a hallmark of financial integration. To the extent that
Asian and other emerging countries continue to develop their domestic banking and capital markets, financial infrastructure and
regulatory and supervisory regimes, the potential for further financial integration is good.
The benefits of financial integration are hard to disentangle from the benefits of economic integration—such as international trade
and real investment. The benefits of global integration overall, however, are clear: standards of living and life expectancies have
increased dramatically, poverty rates have dropped sharply in the countries of highly integrated countries, such as many in Asia.
After several decades of stagnation, the gap between income levels between the advanced economies and the emerging countries,
while still large, has narrowed, in emerging Asia especially dramatically.
But the rise in incomes and standards of living has not resolved all issues. The global financial system is still vulnerable to
frequent and sometimes severe crises. Progress is being made on the international agenda to mitigate those risks, but much work
is still to be done. And the level of real and financial wealth has grown staggeringly. With it, the size of the financial sector in the
advanced economies has grown dramatically, as have levels of compensation in the financial industry. That growth has raised
questions about the efficiency and the fairness of our financial mechanisms.
The post-crisis reforms are designed to address the issue of vulnerabilities and tools of crisis management, but may also have
impacts on the size and structure of the financial sector. Let me turn to areas of post-crisis reform, beginning with globally
systemically important financial institutions, the so-called G-SIFIs.
Global Financial Institutions
The activities of global systemically important financial institutions or G-SIFIs have been a major driver of financial integration.
The recent financial crisis illustrates dramatically that problems at large, systemically important firms can have impacts on
markets and the real economy not only where they are domiciled, but across the globe. This spillover has long been a concern of
financial authorities in host countries.
The regulatory and financial stability agenda being advanced by the Financial Stability Board and the Basel Committee on Banking
Supervision is intended both to reduce the probability that such firms could fail and to mitigate the costs of their failure, should it
occur. Measures to raise both the quantity and quality of capital at the G-SIFIs, such as Basel III and enhanced prudential
standards, are aimed at reducing the probability of failure. The work on recovery and resolution planning, as set out in the Key
Attributes for Effective Resolution Regimes, a new global standard published in 2011, aims at mitigating the cost of failure by
developing the institutional arrangements and concrete plans to place a failing G-SIFI into resolution. These initiatives at the
global level have been mirrored at the national level in many countries.
I’d draw special attention to stress testing in its role in reducing the probability of failure and resolution planning in reducing
failure’s social cost, because both represent an important shift of focus for the supervisory community. Both processes focus
attention on the far adverse tail of the probability distribution of outcomes for a firm. Technology, financial modeling, and risk
management theory and practice have greatly expanded and enhanced the supervisors’ ability to address those severe adverse
outcomes.
As a result, supervisors and resolution authorities are having conversations with firms that were simply unimaginable prior to the
crisis. For example, the U.S. requirement for firms to produce a “living will” or resolution plan under the U.S. Bankruptcy Code is
forcing firms to confront the sources of their long-tail risk and the consequences to the firm of adverse outcomes in a manner

never discussed before.
I mention the breaking of these barriers because it is relevant to another set of conversations that have proven difficult: the
conversation between home and host supervisors. Host jurisdictions for over 20 years have sought greater information about the
parent organization as they supervise local subsidiaries and branches of global financial firms. The information need is felt most
acutely, of course, when the global firm is in distress.
Resolution planning is developed in relatively small groups of authorities in the jurisdictions in which a G-SIFI’s largest operations
are located. Currently, work is underway under FSB auspices to find a way to communicate with other host supervisors where the
local operations are systemically important in that nation.
Just as the dialogues within firms and between firms and their supervisors have had to break through old barriers, the dialogue
between home and host supervisors will also need to break new ground. The preconditions for that dialogue are ensuring that
safeguards to ensure the confidentiality of information are in place. Information about a troubled firm will need to be
communicated with economy, given the time pressures and scope of communication needed in a crisis.
We do not know yet how the reform agenda will affect the international activities of G-SIFIs, although we can see some early
indications. Higher capital requirements and more stringent prudential standards are causing some firms to re-examine their
correspondent and business relationships and make new cost-benefit assessments. The greater focus on stress testing and
resolution planning may lead to more discussion of firm structure, including the number of subsidiaries, the alignment of the
corporate structure with the firm’s business activities, the management of intragroup exposures, the use of parent guarantees, and
the correlation of the firm’s capital and liquidity structure with the firm’s business and legal entity structure.
In my personal view, discussion will no doubt lead to action, in the best scenario, by G-SIFIs themselves. In my personal view,
these issues reflect areas where the true costs of managing a large, complex, internationally active firm have not yet been fully
internalized by the firms. Said differently, the cost of international financial activity has probably been too low, and as it rises,
some readjustment of those activities will be inevitable.
This touches on one area of global financial firm recovery where more progress will need to be made. I like to benchmark
progress toward financial institution recovery against the program that U.S. regulators used in the domestic banking crisis of the
early 1990s. Because the problems at that time were simpler, the remediation program imposed by supervisors was easy to
understand and it was effective. The program had three principal actions: a troubled bank had to raise additional capital and
strengthen its liquidity; it needed to fully identify its problem assets and exposures, isolate them and place them in workout; and it
needed to develop a new business plan.
The international community of supervisors has done a great deal to address the need for more and better quality capital through
new capital standards. The identification and workout of troubled assets has made significant progress, which we can observe in
the recovery of markets for some troubled assets. But global financial firms are still working on the new business plan. From the
financial press, it’s clear that many large financial companies are rethinking their strategies, often along the lines of increasing the
focus on nonfinancial businesses and households and reducing the focus on expanding capital markets businesses. But I believe
we are more at the beginning than toward the end of that reconsideration.
Complexity
Let me turn to complexity. The development of international and domestic capital markets has been one of the dramatic
developments of the last 30 years. A combination of new instruments, new national markets, and the development of a range of
complex securitization and derivatives structures has made the financial system substantially more complex. The global financial
crisis underscored the difficulty of monitoring and containing mounting financial stress in the global system and the specific
dangers that lie in very complex products with opaque risk characteristics.
Complexity is a fact of modern life—look at the global supply management chain or the integration of activities guided today by
“smart” technology. Cost, however, can grow geometrically with complexity, and may be one reason why the share of the financial
sector in GDP has grown so much. For central banks and supervisors, complexity makes it difficult to identify emerging problems,
understand the potential for one adverse development to trigger others, and close gaps in regulatory coverage that encourage
regulatory arbitrage.
Whatever the costs of complexity are under normal operating conditions, those costs escalate sharply under conditions of distress.
Indeed, in the early stages of the recent crisis, many financial market participants had to scramble to understand the nature of
their exposures down to the details, including details about the clearing and settlement of transactions.
Complexity therefore needs to be managed and reduced meaningfully whenever we have the opportunity. I would point to four
ways that we in the official community can reduce complexity.
First is the development of international standards in forums such as the Financial Stability Board and the Basel Committee on
Banking Supervision and the application of those standards in all our jurisdictions. Consistency in our approach to supervision

and regulation across jurisdictions can make the regulatory environment more seamless and less subject to arbitrage.
The expansion of the Financial Stability Board and other standard setting bodies to include the G-20 countries means that more
voices are heard as these standards are developed. Regional organizations such as the SEACEN Centre, as well as the FSB’s
regional consultative meetings, provide a forum for discussion of policy matters with a much wider set of countries.
Second is the move to regional financial markets. A regional financial market has obvious benefits in scale and liquidity. It can
harmonize market practices across many jurisdictions and consolidate financial infrastructure, thereby simplifying the financial
system.
Third is greater standardization of financial products. The global financial crisis highlighted weaknesses in infrastructure and risk
management because of the lack of standardization in the global derivatives markets. Highly customized complex transactions
produced large losses in part because their inherent risks were poorly understood; conventional risk management and
infrastructure systems could not capture and flag all of the risk dimensions.
The Financial Stability Board and in the U.S., the Dodd-Frank Act, as well as earlier international supervisory efforts led by the
Federal Reserve Bank of New York, have pushed forward centralized clearing of derivatives. The move to trade repositories and
clearinghouses may also lead toward more transactions through exchanges or electronic trading platforms, where products are
generally standardized.
Fourth is seeking greater transparency into firms and markets. International standards and standardization of financial products
create some of that transparency. But much more is needed. Requiring a financial institution to explain to the public the nature of
its risks and their management is a strong discipline on both risk-taking and complexity.
Financial Stability
Let me end with a few words on financial stability. How adeptly financial institutions and financial supervisors manage the risks
associated with complexity and large, globally connected institutions will have important implications for financial stability.
However, the experience of the financial crisis has drawn attention to the need to identify threats to financial stability and address
them promptly and to create the institutional arrangements that ensure that need is met. The result has been an effort to
strengthen the focus on financial stability as a mandate and provide the necessary powers to address it in national statutes.
The policy discussion now describes three realms of relevant policy: macroeconomic, such as monetary policy; microprudential,
such as financial institution supervision; and macroprudential. At least two issues figure prominently in discussion of these
realms: who is responsible for financial stability and which policies and policy tools should be considered macroprudential?
I’d like to offer an analogy that might be helpful. A major financial loss in a financial institution almost always reflects the
breakdown of multiple sets of controls. The supervisory program the supervisor would have liked to have had in place before the
loss would involve asking the firm to take multiple corrective actions to have prevented the breakdown.
I would posit that instances of financial instability result similarly from the coincidence of several failures or breakdowns requiring
policy intervention. Financial instability events are by definition systemic; their scope and size cause them to impact real and
financial activity across multiple sectors. The financial crisis that began with the U.S. boom in residential mortgage financing grew
to be so destructive because of increased leverage in the household and financial sectors and a series of poor and risky practices in
the marketing, mortgage underwriting and securitization of housing loans.
This view has two implications. It means that coordination is essential to financial stability and it also means that several
measures will likely be necessary to address emerging financial instability. Thus, the full range of macroeconomic, regulatory and
market conduct policies need to be available to deal with the emergence of instability. Coordination involves quickly laying out the
sources of stress and the transmission paths of that stress as clearly as possible and then calibrating a response across the
complete policy toolkit available.
Such an approach may lead to a concern that conflicts could arise among the goals of macroeconomic, macroprudential, and
microprudential objectives. In many cases, the overarching goal of stability will create alignment because the stabilization goals
of monetary policy and financial supervision are prerequisites for financial stability. But where conflict exists or targeting is
needed, coordination and a sufficiently large toolkit allow the authorities to craft a response to a systemic threat that minimizes
any short-term conflicts among goals.
The focus on coordination also forces us to ask what structures and mechanisms create strong incentives for coordination and
address conflicts within the group of policymakers. In some countries, much of the coordination of policy tools could be led and
overseen by the central bank—for example, one that serves as both monetary authority and a primary microprudential supervisor.
In a country like the United States, with our numerous regulators, the coordination mechanism Congress has put in place is the
Financial Stability Oversight Council, known as FSOC, chaired by the Secretary of the Treasury.
What guarantees that the ten or so agencies at the U.S. Financial Stability Oversight Council, table will coordinate? The
requirement to publish an annual assessment of financial stability risks, that is, shared concerns, is one such incentive. A second

is the escalation processes built into the FSOC process, should the members disagree. A recent example of disagreement arose
when the U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) did not approve a proposal asking for comment on possible avenues to
reduce the risk of runs on money market mutual funds, a source of concern highlighted in FSOC’s financial stability report. Many
FSOC members thought it important to move forward with reform in this important area. The FSOC process offers a range of
options, exerting peer pressure to formal actions that could involve imposing new requirements. With further deliberation, the
SEC put out a new proposal for comment.
Finally, I believe we need in the official sector a bias toward action and a willingness to take risk in confronting emerging financial
instability. It will almost always be uncertain whether an emerging problem will become systemic. Any supervisory actions taken
will have an immediate impact, curtailing someone’s profitable opportunity; moreover, the results of an action might not be
discernible for some time. Yet we need to overcome the inclination to wait, especially in light of the rapid rate of deterioration of
financial firms and markets we observed in the financial crisis. To respond timely and with sufficient force, policymakers need to
be agile; observing the impact of their actions, they need to able to adjust their program to improve its impact. Given the need for
agility, we may also need much more flexibility in our policy instruments and processes.
To sum up, I’ve highlighted three challenges we need to address to continue to foster international financial integration and reap
its benefits:
• We need to complete the reform agenda dealing with large financial institutions.
• We need to manage and contain complexity
• We need to coordinate more fully on meeting threats to financial instability.
We have plenty of work ahead.
Thank you for attention today.
Posted February 20, 2014