View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

AGRICULTURE IN A DEVELOPING ECONOMY
By Chester C. Davis, President
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
Before the Town Hall Workshop
February 19, 1945 - New York
To come right to grips with the topic, the problems of agriculture
will not be solved in the postwar period, or at any other time, either.
We are going to keep on living with them as dynamic human issues. No one
set of laws or policies can possibly put them at rest. When military and
lend-lease uses for food and fiber come to an end and when relief shipments
cease, we will have a farm

plant geared to produce a great deal more than

we normally consume at home. New mechanical devices will be coming into use
to make one man1 s labor on the farm far more productive than it ever was
before. Our price structure will make normal export trade, that is, trade
without subsidy, impossible in most important commodities.

Increasing

mechanical .and technological efficiency will team up with the normal high
rural birthrate to free workers from the farm who, as Mr. Schultz pointed
out, must be absorbed by expanding non-agricultural employment.

A review of our agricultural history since the turn of the century
points up two basic conditions that in the past have been necessary for
agricultural prosperity.

First, a high

domestic demand has been provided

by expanding industrial employment. Second, there have been substantial
exports.

The fact that raw material exports from the United States are going

to be increasingly difficult in the future throws even more eznphasis on the
first point.

But a high domestic demand for agricultural products does not exist
within"agriculture itself.

In other words, the problem of agriculture cannot

be treated separately as if agriculture were in a vacuum.
many cases lie completely outside the business of farming.



Their solutions in

- 2 As a basic prerequisite to high agricultural income, it is necessary
to have an expanding industry. All of my life I have preached the vAiolesome
effect v/hich a prosperous farm population has on factory employment and wages,
I want to emphasize the corollary to this - the effect which high wages and
sustained industrial production have on farm income. The fact that our
employable population is now working regularly - most of it at good wages has been the principal factor in building up a high and mainly profitable
demand for the products of the farmer.

The variation in farm income, as Mr. Schultz showed, is caused primarily
by price changes. Vfiien farm prices rise, farm income rises just about as
fast; and, conversely, when farm prices fall, farm income falls in about the
same degree. Recognition of this condition has resulted in agriculture's
policy of attempting to stabilize farm prices, and if this could be accomplished successfully, the farmer fools with some justification that most of his
difficulties would disappear.

The ttrouble is that price stability is impossible unless there is
stability in the supply and demand relationship*

As long as agriculture

continues to supply about the same volume of goods each year, changes in
demand for those goods will result in changes in price.

YJhen we try to get

around this by fixing floor prices by law, we encounter the "surplus" problem what to do with the excess above what the market will take at the floor prices*
The Government buys it up, either directly or through loans, and then starts
worrying about how to hold it or dump it.

In the long run there are two ways to stability in farm prices%
Either we must control the supply so as to maintain stable prices, or we
must maintain a high level of demand.
reasons#



The latter way appeals to me for two

First, a high level of demand means high consumption as well as

- 3
stable prices and so promotes a more prosperous agriculture.

Second, it is

difficult to control the short-run supply of agricultural goods to the extent
necessary to maintain stable prices.

It is a tough enough job to make the

long-run adjustment to permanent demand changes.

I think we face a continuing naed for far-reaching adjustments in
agriculture as long into the future as anyone can see.

These adjustments

will not be easy, and in some areas like the cotton belt they are likely to
be drastic, even revolutionary.

But these adjustments will be easier to

make if the farm business operates in an economy of high industrial production
with a high level of employment at as high a wage level as is supported and
justified by the volume of production. Only a high level of national income,
of consumer purchasing power, can make a good market at good prices for our
meat and milk, our vegetables and fruit.

I have no cure-all to suggest for farmers or government, but if I
could be granted one wish on behalf of a prosperous agriculture, it would
be that the rest of the population might learn the way to full employment
and high volume production.

Most of the farmersT troubles would tend to

shrink and disappear if non-agricultural industry would only follow the same
program of full production that agriculture has always followed.

I should like to consider the question of exports for a moment.
Under lend-lease shipments alone we are currently sending abroad 2-h times
the value of the agricultural products exported prior to the war.

In other

words, a substantial part of the demand that has lifted farm prices and farm
income to their present level comes from abroad.

I do not believe that

agricultural exports after the war will play as large a part as they have
during the war period.

There will be some demand for relief and rehabilita-

tion purposes, but it is not likely to last for long.



- 4 I agree that if in postwar years we could export more agricultural
commodities than wo did during the 1930fs it would be a great prop for a
prosperous agriculture.

But international trade is going to be closely con??

trolled after the war and if our domestic price for export

crops continues

above world levels I do not believe other nations will permit us to subsidize
exports in increasing volume in competition with countries that are primarily
raw material producers.

In the long run, agriculture's hope for a con-

siderable share in world markets depends on having costs of production low
enough to permit it to meet world prices.

Y/e are facing difficult political and economic problems with farm
price guarantees. For two years beginning with the January 1 following the
date on which the president or Congress declares the hostilities in the
present war have terminated, direct government price supports have been
guaranteed for most of the 166 farm commodities produced commercially in
this country, a large number of which have been guaranteed support through loan
and purchase programs at 90 or 92~ij per cent of the parity price.
Existing guarantees pledge support at specified percentages of the
parity price. It is going to be a job of some magnitude to maintain those
guarantees.

I believe in the use of moderate price supports to cushion

the shock of readjustment from war demands, but I am afraid of the consequences of the tendency to shove the supports up and up to higher levels,
and I am afraid of what a system of rigid, legislated prices will do to
the farmers themselves if they are extended into the indefinite future.
There is a lot more to it than just setting a price or a parity formula
by law. Let me try bo illustrate some of the difficulties.




- 5With perishable and semi-perishnble crops like livestock and dairy
products, fruits and vegetables, it is necessary that prices permit the
markets to clear the supplies that are delivered.

There are practical

limits to the quantities which public or private agencies can store while
they look around for new outlets. If for any reason consumer purchasing
power falls off sharply while the prices of theso commodities are held where
they were when consumer purchasing power was high, then the quantities bought
and consumed will drop. Farmers will find they are producing and delivering
more than the market will take at the old price, no matter v/hat the law says.

Perhaps the problem can be scon more clearly in the case of cotton.
If Congress could pass a law or the Department of Agriculture could issue a
regulation fixing tho price of cotton, for example, at 13 or 20 cents a
pound, and then have the cotton crop move into consumption at that price, we
wouldn't have much of a cotton problem.

It might work, at that, if the

demand for cotton could be met only by the American staple and nothing
else, and if over the years the demand always equalled the supply. But
the peacetime world c m buy cotton in other markets than ours, and the
domestic mills can use synthetic fibers. It is time to stop, look and
listen; we do not want to wake up some day to find we have priced ourselves
out of the market*

Farmers have fought for a quarter of a century to get the concept
of purchasing power parity recognized in the law.

They do not want to see

it dropped unless some workable and satisfactory standard is offered in its
stead, even though they may recognize defects in the old 1909-1914 formula.
I believe it is possible to devise a more practical farm price standard




- 6 than the present parity formula, and I an confident that a better way to
meet the government1 s postwar obligation to the farmer can be found than
to try to fix market prices by a rigid formula.

I raise the question whether

the country as a whole4 including the farmers, would not be better off by
permitting the price flexibility necessary to move our farm production
into use by the consumer, and finding another way to protect or stabilize
farm income. For example, Mr. Schultz has suggested that instead of fixed
support prices, the government arrange to make supplemental payments to
farmers in case there is industrial depression that cuts down the amount
of money available in consumer hands to pay for farm products. There are
many other suggestions, all worthy of study.

Some of you may ask, quite properly, why should any government
payments at all be made to the farmers. The immediate practical reason
is that the government has pledged these price guarantees by law to encourage
the production needed for war.

I am concerned with how they can best bo

carried out.
There isn!t much time to look at other important phases of postwar
agricultural policy, but I do want to point out that farmers* wartime
savings can be converted into permanent gains if after the war they go to
equip farms for more efficient production* and to establish real soil
conservation practices.

Vfo are depleting our soil and plant-food mineral reserves at a
rapid rate, and without the soil and those minerals in the right supply we
cannot have healthy plants or healthy people. The farms are giving up to
the cities in the process of land mining which is what most farming is, a
mineral wealth which the farmer does not figure in his costs* He is



- 7depleting his reserves year by year,, but he can't charge it against his
taxes.

That is one good reason why we on the pavements owe it to our farmer

neighbor to take more than just a passive interest in the protection and
restoration of the land.

That is a big postwar job.

Just one concluding word:

The big question that confronts the

farmers is the same question that li^s ahead for the whole economy. Can
we, in peacetime, use our magnificent plant and labor force in reasonably
full production?

Agriculture is one member of one body.

It cannot be

healthy if the rest of the body is sick. The rest of the body cannot long
thrive if agriculture is ailing. "Vfo are all in one boat with rough weather
and a long pull ahead.

Only one spirit can bring us through - the spirit

of good-humored and tolerant cooperation, with industry and agriculture and
labor and government pulling together.




oooOOOooo