View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Thoughts on Accommodative Monetary Policy, Inflation and
Financial Instability

Charles L. Evans
President and Chief Executive Officer
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Credit Suisse Asian Investment Conference
Hong Kong
March 28, 2014

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CHICAGO
The views expressed today are my own and not necessarily
Those of the Federal Reserve System or the FOMC.

Thoughts on Accommodative Monetary Policy, Inflation and Financial Instability
Charles L. Evans
President and Chief Executive Officer
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Introduction
Thank you, Mr. Naqvi. It is truly a pleasure to be here today at the Credit Suisse Asian
Investment Conference, and I thank the organizers for including me in this impressive
program.
Today, I would like to make three points concerning the U.S. economy and
accommodative monetary policy. First, the U.S. economy continues to improve, and
accommodative monetary policy will remain a strong support for this recovery for quite
some time. Second, although highly accommodative monetary policy can lead to
increasing inflation risks today, inflation in the United States is too low. And this is true
throughout much of the world. Third, while low interest rates could lead to financial
exuberance in principle, monetary policy is not the best tool to mitigate this risk. Instead,
macroprudential policies are more appropriate tools to address the risk of financial
instability.
Before turning to the details of these three points, I need to note that, as always, the
standard Fed disclaimer applies: I will be giving my personal perspective, and that is not
necessarily shared by my colleagues on the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC)
or in the Federal Reserve System.
Recent Monetary Policy Actions
As you all know, in response to the unusual economic circumstances generated by the
financial crisis and the Great Recession, the FOMC lowered our traditional policy tool —
the target federal funds rate — to near-zero levels in December 2008 and has kept it
there since. With the fed funds rate constrained at this lower bound, and economic
conditions requiring additional policy accommodation, the Committee also deployed
nontraditional policy tools to stimulate activity. We embarked upon large-scale
purchases of long-term Treasury securities and agency mortgage-backed securities.
We also used new communications tools to provide forward guidance about how long
short-term interest rates will essentially remain at their lower bound of zero.
While large-scale asset purchases and forward guidance are unconventional tools, their
effect on interest rates and real economic activity is quite conventional. Both tools are
aimed at stimulating economic activity through lower long-term interest rates. Through
arbitrage and portfolio rebalancing, lower rates in one market are transmitted to other
interest rates faced by investors, nonfinancial firms and consumers. Lower rates are
also transmitted across the asset and maturity spectrum. There is significant evidence
that the FOMC’s policies have been helpful in reducing financing costs rates paid by

firms and consumers and, more generally, in supporting aggregate demand in the face
of substantial economic headwinds over the past six years.
It should be noted that economic activity picked up momentum in the second half of
2013. Overall, real gross domestic product (GDP) grew at a bit under a 3-1/2 percent
rate in the second half, up from an average pace of growth of about 2 percent over the
previous three years. Moreover, we’ve seen some more solid consumer spending,
which should provide further impetus to overall growth this year. In the labor market, job
growth has been solid and the unemployment rate is down to 6.7 percent. That is well
below the 8.1 percent rate that prevailed when we instituted the latest round of largescale asset purchases in September 2012.
However, we aren’t out of the woods yet. The harsh weather of this past winter — by
which I mean the North American polar vortex — makes the recent data difficult to
interpret. That said, some of them have been on the soft side. Balance sheet scars from
the financial crisis are still weighing on the economy. Fiscal policy is a restraint on
economic growth. And economic activity abroad is not robust. The good news is that all
of these headwinds appear to be dissipating. But risks remain. And we still have large
resource gaps. For example, the unemployment rate is still well above the 5-1/4 percent
rate I think it should be in the long run. At the same time, inflation is only 1 percent —
well below the FOMC’s longer-run target of 2 percent. Accordingly, monetary policy is
highly accommodative, and needs to remain so for some time.
Given these developments, the FOMC began adjusting the mix of its tools in
December. The Committee, however, is maintaining the overall highly accommodative
stance of policy. The Committee modestly reduced the pace of its monthly asset
purchases from $85 billion to $55 billion in three separate $10 billion steps. In addition,
with the unemployment rate approaching the 6-1/2 percent threshold that was
established in December 2012, the Committee decided it was time to update its forward
guidance on the future path of short-term interest rates. Our policy statement now
emphasizes that when deciding how long short-term rates will remain at their current
level, the Committee will use a wide range of information to assess the realized and
expected progress toward our dual mandate goals of maximum employment and price
stability. The statement also indicates that given the Committee’s current assessment of
these factors, it likely will be appropriate to keep the fed funds rate at its current level for
a considerable period after the asset purchase program ends. Furthermore, even after
the economy lifts off and employment and inflation are near mandate-consistent levels,
economic conditions likely will warrant keeping short-term rates below their typical longrun level for some time.
The various asset purchases the Fed has undertaken since 2008 have expanded our
balance sheet more than fourfold, to over $4 trillion dollars. Moreover, according to the
FOMC’s projections and the latest market expectations, by the time the policy rate
increases, it will have been near zero for about seven years. These are startling facts
and should certainly get your attention! As prudent policymakers, we would be remiss if

3

we failed to carefully assess potential risks that might arise from these unusual and
extraordinary policies.
As the FOMC’s communications indicate, the Committee has fully reviewed the
potential costs of its policies and it reassesses them regularly. I think that the benefits of
our policy choices continue to far outweigh the potential risks. However, we must
repeatedly think long and hard about two risks that are mentioned often — namely, that
our expanded balance sheet and the prolonged period of low rates raise 1) the risk of
higher inflation; and 2) the risk of financial instability. What can go wrong? Do we have
the appropriate infrastructure and tools to adequately assess and manage these risks?
To address these questions, we must evaluate these risks within the context of the
goals of monetary policy and the current state of the economy and financial markets.
Inflation Risks
Let me start with the risk of high inflation. As far back as mid-2009, Fed critics warned
that our near-zero policy rate and trillions of dollars in asset purchases risk generating
very high inflation. On several occasions, to underscore this risk, I have been presented
with a gift of a Zimbabwe 100 trillion dollar note. As someone who is subject to a 20
U.S. dollar limit on gifts, I can assure you it is within the guidelines to accept one of
these notes.
The monetary policy mandates of the Federal Reserve are clear: We must foster
monetary and financial conditions that support maximum employment and price
stability. Since January 2012, the Fed has set an explicit goal for inflation of 2 percent,
as measured by the price index for total personal consumption expenditures, or PCE.
So, how are we doing with respect to this 2 percent target and our Zimbabwean risks?
Despite many earlier predictions of unacceptably high inflation, total PCE inflation has
been hovering around just 1 percent since early 2013. Other inflation measures,
notably, the well-known Consumer Price Index (CPI), are also well below their related
benchmarks.1 Forecasters often look at core inflation, which excludes volatile food and
energy prices, because it is a better predictor of where overall prices are headed than is
total inflation. Our progress toward the inflation target is not noticeably faster by this
metric either. Core PCE inflation was just 1.1 percent over the past year and has been
at this rate since last spring. Most private sector forecasts and survey measures of
inflation expectations have remained well anchored and do not ring any alarms of high
inflation. Expectations embedded in asset prices tell a similar story. Sophisticated
models that extract inflation expectations from the yield curve show that investors’
inflation expectations at the three-year horizon are below 2 percent and will be below 2
percent for several years.
All told, the risk of high inflation seems very low. In fact, I am concerned that inflation
will not pick up quickly enough. As I noted, we have been stuck at 1 percent inflation
1

Because of some differences in product coverage and statistical methodologies, total CPI inflation tends
to average 1/4 to 1/2 percentage points higher than total PCE inflation. Hence, the FOMC’s 2 percent
target on total PCE inflation would translate to a 2.3 percent to 2.5 percent target for total CPI inflation.
4

since early 2013, and there is little indication of a pickup in the recent data. Low inflation
is just as economically costly as high inflation. When we set an inflation target of 2
percent, we need to hit our target without too much delay. Simply put, we need to
average 2 percent inflation over the medium term.
Accordingly, the current 1 percent inflation situation calls for extended policy
accommodation. If the Fed embarked prematurely on more restrictive monetary policy
conditions, these adverse actions would work to reduce inflation to further unacceptably
low levels. That’s going in the wrong direction.2
Financial Stability and Monetary Policy
It is easy and most natural for a Fed policymaker to talk about inflation. Price stability is
one of the explicit goals of monetary policy as mandated by the U.S. Congress.
Financial stability risks are more complicated. How does financial stability dovetail with
the Fed’s dual mandate? There is clearly an interdependent relationship between them.
A strong economy with low inflation provides a key stabilizing force for beneficial credit
intermediation and robust financial market functioning. At the same time, stable and
well-functioning financial markets are essential for achieving maximum employment and
price stability. The global experience since 2008 reinforces this critical interplay
between monetary and financial conditions.
However, beyond these basic principles, what is the appropriate monetary policy stance
for achieving both financial stability and the dual mandate of maximum employment and
price stability?
With inflation running well below our 2 percent longer-run target and the unemployment
rate still well above its normal long-term level, appropriate monetary policy dictates that
low real interest rates should prevail until the economy is further along a sustainable
path to its potential level and inflation is closer to target. Nonetheless, it is common to
hear the argument that these highly accommodative monetary policies might sow the
seeds of financial instability.
The fear is that excessive and persistently low interest rates would lead to excessive
risk-taking by some investors. For instance, some firms, such as life insurance
companies and pension funds, are under pressure to meet a stream of fixed liabilities
incurred when interest rates were higher.3 (And perhaps these liabilities were offered at
somewhat generous terms to begin with.) To meet commitments like these in the
current low interest rate environment, some firms have an incentive to reach for yield by
investing in excessively risky assets. Furthermore, with the costs of borrowing at
historically low levels, other investors might simply decide that this is a good time to
cheaply amplify the risk and return in their portfolios by taking on more leverage.
2

I recently discussed the costs of too-low inflation and the implications of having a 2 percent inflation
target in a January 15 speech; see Evans (2014).
3
I should note that increases in interest rates since last spring have increased discount factors and thus
lowered the present value of pension fund and other fixed nominal liabilities. For instance, see Fitch
Ratings (2013).
5

One could reach the conclusion that historically low and stable interest rates pose a
threat to financial stability. This creates a seeming paradox for policymakers. On the
one hand, the existing large shortfalls in aggregate demand call for highly
accommodative monetary policies and historically low interest rates. On the other hand,
such policies have the potential to raise the likelihood of financial instability in the future.
So, the questions that I’m often asked regarding these matters are as follows: Do the
regulators and the Fed have adequate safeguards in place to mitigate this potential
financial risk? If not, should the FOMC step away from what we thought was the best
monetary policy with respect to our dual mandate? Should we discard our
nonconventional tools and raise the fed funds rate in order to reduce the possibility of
undesirable financial imbalances in the future?
I don’t believe that such monetary policy adjustment is the right approach. I think the
inference that persistently low interest rates pose a danger to financial stability is based
on a narrow view of the economy. This narrow view is unlikely to survive a broader
analysis that takes into account all the interactions between financial markets and real
economic activity.
If more restrictive monetary policies were pursued to generate higher interest rates, they
would likely result in higher unemployment and a sharp decline in asset prices, choking
the moderate recovery. Such an adverse economic outcome is unlikely to set a
favorable foundation for financial stability. Moreover, our short-term interest rate tools
are too blunt to have a significant effect only on those pockets of the financial system
that are most prone to inappropriate risk-taking. At the same time, these blunt tools
could significantly damage other markets, as well as the growth prospects for the
economy as a whole. Therefore, stepping away from otherwise appropriate monetary
policy to address potential financial instability risks would degrade progress toward
maximum employment and price stability. This approach would be a particularly poor
choice when other tools are available, at lower social costs, to address the risk of
financial instability.
Let me be clear. I am not saying that financial stability concerns are not relevant for the
economy or that policymakers should not take decisive action against developments
that threaten financial stability. Rather, I am saying that the macroprudential tools
available to policymakers are better-suited safeguards to addressing financial risks
directly. These macroprudential actions can be dialed up or down given the appropriate
setting of monetary policy tools; so, undesirable macroeconomic outcomes are less
likely than if we were to resort to premature monetary tightening. Indeed, any decision
to instead rely on more-restrictive interest rate policies to achieve financial stability at
the expense of poorer macroeconomic outcomes must pass a cost–benefit test. And
such a test would have to clearly illustrate that the adverse economic outcomes from
more-restrictive interest rate policies would be better and more acceptable to society
than the outcomes that can be achieved by using enhanced supervisory tools alone to
address financial stability risks. I have yet to see this argued convincingly.
6

Macroprudential Tools
Let’s discuss some of these macroprudential tools.
One simple but important tool is enhanced monitoring. Even before the recent financial
crisis, central bankers were well aware of the key role played by stable financial markets
in economic activity. Since the crisis, however, the analysis of financial stability issues
has been greatly expanded and given a more prominent role in the FOMC’s
deliberations. We comb through reams of data looking for evidence of incipient risks to
financial stability.
The Federal Reserve also has revamped its approach to bank supervision substantially
to expand the focus on macrofinancial risks. Traditional bank supervisory tools are
being used more intensively, and new tools have been developed. Bank capital stress
tests are one well-known addition to our supervisory toolkit. Another is the augmentation
of traditional microprudential supervisory work that analyzes individual institutions with
efforts that take a wide-angle view of the banking industry. Supervisors look to identify
common trends across institutions and emerging concentrations of risks that might pose
systemic threats to the financial system. This broad view also allows supervisors to
better identify sound practices among firms and incorporate them into supervisory
reviews and the feedback provided in them.
The Federal Reserve also has greatly expanded its surveillance efforts to financial
markets outside of the traditional banking sector, such as the insurance industry and
financial market utilities. These efforts are not confined to financial institutions per se,
and reach a range of activities that might pose a potential threat to financial stability. For
instance, staff members from the Chicago Fed are actively engaged in assessing the
role of high-frequency computerized trading in securities and derivatives markets and
associated risks that might arise with it.
These are just a few examples of regulatory tools available to monitor and promote
financial stability. And there are a host of other instruments in our toolkit, such as
resolution plans, liquidity requirements and single counterparty credit limits. All are
examples of improvements in supervisory practices aimed at reducing the likelihood of
systemic disruptions and containing the impact should such disruptions occur.
Conclusion
To reiterate, I currently expect that low inflation and still-high unemployment will mean
that the short-term policy rate will remain near zero well into 2015. In this environment,
some have questioned the ability of our supervisory and regulatory tools to adequately
address potential financial instability risks. They argue that a broad tightening of interest
rate policy might be more effective in catching incipient risks that might fall through the
cracks. It is certainly true that higher interest rates would permeate the entire financial
system. But this is just another way of saying that raising interest rates is a blunt tool.
Higher interest rates would reduce risk-taking where it is excessive; but they also would

7

result in a pullback in economic activity in sectors where risk-taking might already be
overly restrained. That’s how a blunt tool works.
If you believe that financial stability can only be achieved through higher interest rates
— interest rates that would do immediate damage to meeting our dual mandate goals at
a time when unemployment is still unacceptably high — then we ought to at least ask
ourselves if the financial system has become too big and too complex.
Think about how problematic the cost-benefit calculus becomes if the only way we can
achieve financial stability is to raise interest rates above the level where the forces of
demand and supply in the real economy put them. The possible benefit of such a
restrictive rate move would be to reduce risks that might be forming in the nooks and
crannies of a highly complex financial system. But the costs would be 1) higher
unemployment; 2) a risk of choking off the economic recovery; 3) even lower inflation
below our objective; and, somewhat paradoxically, 4) the introduction of new financial
risks by reducing asset values and credit quality. Given such cost-benefit trade-offs, I
would have to question whether the financial system has become too complex —
perhaps complex enough to generate negative social value. Rather than degrading our
macroeconomic performance through suboptimal monetary policies, I would have to
consider whether we should contemplate big changes to the financial system — a lot
more rules, substantially higher capital requirements for all institutions and maybe even
fewer financial products.
However, I have a more favorable view of the social value of our financial system and
the efficacy of supervision and regulation. Since the financial crisis, the Federal Reserve
has expanded its macroprudential toolkit and enhanced its microprudential tools. We
have also reoriented our approach to supervision to take full advantage of the Federal
Reserve System’s wide-ranging expertise on macroeconomic and financial
developments and risks.
I believe that these regulatory efforts can effectively minimize the risks of another crisis
and increase the resiliency of the financial system. We can achieve these objectives
without having to resort to wholesale changes to the financial system and without
degrading our monetary policy goals. Maintaining the effectiveness of the financial
system for generating more-robust economic growth continues to be a crucial objective
for public policy. Thank you for your time, and I would be happy to take your questions.
References
Evans, Charles, 2014, “Recurring themes for the New Year,” speech, Corridor
Economic Forecast Luncheon, Coralville, IA, January 15, available at
http://www.chicagofed.org/webpages/publications/speeches/2014/01_15_14_themes_n
ew_year.cfm.
Federal Open Market Committee, 2013, Minutes of the Federal Open Market
Committee, Washington, DC, December 17–18, available at
http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/fomcminutes20131218.htm.
8

Fitch Ratings, 2013, “Fitch: U.S. corporate pension plans underfunded status improves,”
press release, New York, August 15, available at
https://www.fitchratings.com/web/en/dynamic/fitch-home.jsp.

9